Skip to main content
Log in

A corporation’s culture as an impetus for spinoffs and a driving force of industry evolution

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We offer a theory of spinoffs that explains some salient aspects of these important market entrants. In infant industries, a great share of new market opportunities is depleted by firms that spinoff from incumbents. A model emphasizing the relation between incumbents’ evolving corporate cultures and the generation of spinoffs explains this regularity in industry evolution. By doing so, we capture different patterns in firm development that finally will help explain the evolutionary paths that industries may follow. We show that organizations reach a critical size that entails the collapse of a cooperative culture and triggers the exodus of personnel founding own firms. Thereby, organizations with a cooperative culture active in a dynamic business environment provide ideal training grounds for potential founders. Moreover, we argue that cooperative firm cultures and processes of “entrepreneurial imprinting” are important sources of spinoffs’ superior capabilities concerning their later market performance. We relate our findings to empirical evidence on developmental patterns in industries, such as genealogies and performance of spinoffs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this context, “entrepreneurial imprinting” (EI) has to be distinguished from “organizational imprinting” (OI). EP refers to the individual learning history of the potential entrepreneur and spinoff founder. In contrast, OI is a concept initially developed by Stinchcombe (1965) that argues that environmental conditions at the time of firm entry shape organizational structures. This process of imprinting leads to long lasting internal structures. The imprinting process is, therefore, a main driver of firm related inertia. As imprinted structures in firms are irreversible, they are subsequently subject to market selection processes (also Kimberly 1975; Hannan and Freeman 1977; Boeker 1989). EI, on the other hand, is affecting the individual entrepreneur and is, therefore, a matter of individual learning. Social learning processes at the level of the organization are not touched by EI. Hence, EI is compatible with a dynamic approach to corporate cultures, an issue that is at the heart of the analysis in this article.

  2. A critical share of innovations has been made by firms of modest size (e.g., Christensen 1993).

  3. A cultural variant is defined as an idea, skill, belief, attitude, or value that is acquired by social learning and that influences an individual’s behavior.

  4. Accordingly, nA P reflects the weight of fellow employees, whereby A E + nA P = 1.

  5. The corresponding author will provide exact analytical solutions upon request.

  6. The exact critical cognitive size at which cooperation collapses depends on several aspects external to our model: e.g., the maturity of the group, the personalities of its members, the details of a firm’s norms, or general cultural influences. The deleterious effects on collective outcomes of increasing group size may partly be overridden when collective identity is high (Brewer and Kramer 1986; Wagner 1995; Akerlof and Kranton 2005). In any case, we argue that it should be possible to determine a certain range of group sizes wherein these effects become eminent.

  7. Firms of an intermediate size are especially vulnerable to failure, an observation for which there is empirical and theoretical evidence (e.g., Hannan and Freeman 1977; Boone et al. 2004).

  8. Garvin (1983) argues that employees start their own firms after becoming frustrated with their employers. The drop in cooperativeness resulting from firm growth is such a source of frustration.

  9. In the case shown here, we assumed this range to lie between 0.5 ≤ p ≤ 0.8.

  10. We assume teams of five employees to leave the parent organizations. Furthermore, we allow a spinoff to happen if the parent firm’s size exceeds this spinoff size fivefold.

  11. In a dynamic business environment, these spinoffs enjoy competitive advantages from their high levels of cooperation. However, in a stable environment, this relative advantage diminishes because opportunistic agents start to contribute to firm profits and an increasing share of the business opportunity is exploited by incumbent firms.

  12. McKendrick et al. (2009) provide empirical evidence that spinoffs can have a positive impact on parent firms. The effect mentioned here may be one of those fostering the parent’s development.

  13. There is a human disposition to identify with larger, symbolically marked groups and their norms and institutions. Such groups still depend, however, upon the moral dispositions that help stabilize cooperation in local band-scaled groups as their constituents (Richerson and Boyd 2005).

  14. Deteriorating culture is then the final impetus for going for the perceived business opportunity.

  15. The likelihood is high that these identified business opportunities lie in the industry the parent firm is active in. This fact explains a great part of the self-selection of spinoff founders into the same industry.

  16. Firms more advanced along the industry life cycle have lower spinoff rates also for other reasons: e.g., valuable knowledge becomes more embodied in physical capital making it less accessible to employees (Garvin 1983; Klepper and Sleeper 2005).

References

  • Agarwal R, Echambadi R, Franco AM, Sarkar M (2004) Knowledge transfer through inheritance: spin-out generation, development, and survival. Acad Manag J 47:501–522

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2005) Identity and the economics of organizations. J Econ Perspect 19:9–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Albanese R, van Fleet DD (1985) Rational behavior in groups: the free-riding tendency. Acad Manag Rev 10:244–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Samuelson L (2006) Building rational cooperation. J Econ Theory 127:117–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Aronson E, Wilson TD, Akert RM (2002) Social psychology. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1974) The limits of organization. W.W. Norton & Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch DB, Mahmood T (1994) Firm selection and industry evolution: the post-entry performance of new firms. J Evol Econ 4:243–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney JB (1986) Organizational culture: can it be a source of sustained competitive advantage?Acad Manag Rev 11:656–665

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhardt D, Hughson E, Kutsoati E (2006) The evolution of managerial expertise: how corporate culture can run amok. Am Econ Rev 96:195–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeker W (1989) The development and institutionalization of subunit power in organizations. Adm Sci Q 34:388–410

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton GE, Ockenfels A (2000) ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. Am Econ Rev 90:166–193

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone C, Carroll GR, van Witteloostuijn A (2004) Size, differentiation and the performance of Dutch daily newspapers. Ind Corp Chang 13:117–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1980) Sociobiology, culture and economic theory. J Econ Behav Organ 1:97–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (2002) Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. J Theor Biol 215:287–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer MB, Kramer RM (1986) Choice behavior in social dilemmas: effects of social identity, group size, and decision framing. J Pers Soc Psychol 50:543–549

    Google Scholar 

  • Brittain JW, Freeman J (1986) Entrepreneurship in the semiconductor industry. Mimeo

  • Buenstorf G (2009) Opportunity spin-offs and necessity spin-offs. Int J Entrep Ventur 1:22–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Buenstorf G, Klepper S (2009) Heritage and agglomeration: the Akron Tyre cluster revisited. Econ J 119:705–733

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral LM, Wang Z (2009) Spin-Offs: theory and evidence from the early U.S. automobile industry. The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City RWP 08–15:1–29

  • Card D, Mas A, Rothstein J (2008) Tipping and the dynamics of segregation. Q J Econ 123:177–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli-Sforza LL, Feldman MW (1981) Cultural transmission and evolution: a quantitative approach. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterji AK (2009) Spawned with a silver spoon? Entrepreneurial performance and innovation in the medical device industry. Strateg Manag J 30:185–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen CM (1993) The rigid disk drive industry: a history of commercial and technological turbulence. Bus Hist Rev 67:531–588

    Google Scholar 

  • Churchill NC, Lewis VL (1983) The five stages of small business growth. Harv Bus Rev 61:30–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini RB, Goldstein NJ (2004) Social influence: compliance and conformity. Annu Rev Psychol 55:591–621

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter R, Eisenberg MA (2001) Fairness, character, and efficiency in firms. Bus Hist Rev 149:1717–1733

    Google Scholar 

  • Cordes C, Richerson PJ, McElreath R, Strimling P (2008) A naturalistic approach to the theory of the firm: the role of cooperation and cultural evolution. J Econ Behav Organ 68:125–139

    Google Scholar 

  • Cordes C, Richerson PJ, Schwesinger G (2010) How corporate cultures coevolve with the business environment: the case of firm growth crises and industry evolution. J Econ Behav Organ 76:465–480

    Google Scholar 

  • Cordes C, Richerson PJ, McElreath R, Strimling P (2011) How does opportunistic behavior influence firm size? An evolutionary approach to organizational behavior. J Inst Econ 7:1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Crémer J (1993) Corporate culture and shared knowledge. Ind Corp Chang 2:351–386

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl MS, Reichstein T (2007) Are you experienced? Prior experience and the survival of new organizations. Ind Innovat 14:497–511

    Google Scholar 

  • Deal TE, Kennedy AA (1982) Corporate cultures: the rites and rituals of corporate life. Addison-Wesley, Reading

    Google Scholar 

  • Deckop R, Mangel R, Cirka CC (1999) Getting more than you pay for: organizational citizenship behavior and pay-for-performance plans. Acad Manag J 42:420–428

    Google Scholar 

  • Elfenbein DW, Hamilton BH, Zenger TR (2010) The small firm effect and the entrepreneurial spawning of scientists and engineers. Manag Sci 56:659–681

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis S, Drori I, Shapira Z (2008) Genealogy as evolutionary dynamics. Working Paper, pp 1–51

  • Enzle ME, Anderson SC (1993) Surveillant intentions and intrinsic motivation. J Pers Soc Psychol 64:257–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Eriksson T, Kuhn JM (2006) Firm spin-offs in Denmark, 1981–200—patterns of entry and exit. Int J Ind Organ 24:1021–1040

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90:980–994

    Google Scholar 

  • Forsyth DR (2006) Group dynamics. Thomson Wadsworth, Belmont

    Google Scholar 

  • Franco AM, Filson D (2006) Spin-outs: knowledge diffusion through employee mobility. RAND J Econ 37:841–860

    Google Scholar 

  • Garvin DA (1983) Spin-offs and the new firm formation process. Calif Manag Rev 25:3–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal S, Moran P (1996) Bad for practice: a critique of the transaction cost theory. Acad Manag Rev 21:13–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Gittell JH (2000) Organizing work to support relational co-ordination. Int J Hum Resour Manag 11:517–539

    Google Scholar 

  • Gladwell M (2000) The tipping point. Little, Brown and Company, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Gooding RZ, Wagner JA III (1985) A meta-analytic review of the relationship between size and performance: the productivity and efficiency of organizations and their subunits. Adm Sci Q 30:462–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner LE (1998) Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harv Bus Rev 76:55–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B (1974) Helping behavior and group size: some exploratory stochastic models. Behav Sci 19:219–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, van Damme E (1998) Information, strategic behavior, and fairness in ultimatum bargaining: an experimental study. J Math Psychol 42:227–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan MT, Freeman J (1977) The population ecology of organizations. Am J Sociol 82:929–964

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington JE Jr (1999) Rigidity of social systems. J Polit Econ 107:40–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J (2001) Cultural transmission and the diffusion of innovations: adoption dynamics indicate that biased cultural transmission is the predominant force in behavioral change. Am Anthropol 103:992–1013

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J (2004) Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. J Econ Behav Organ 53:3–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R (2002) On modeling cognition and culture. J Cogn Cult 2:87–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Gil-White FJ (2001) The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav 22:165–196

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H, McElreath R (2001) In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Am Econ Rev 91:73–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin BE (2001) Economics and corporate culture. In: Cooper CL, Cartwright S, Earley CP (eds) The international handbook of organizational culture and climate. Wiley, Chichester, pp 217–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgins MC (2005) Career imprints: creating leaders across an industry. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B, MacDonald GM (1994) The life cycle of a competitive industry. J Polit Econ 102:322–347

    Google Scholar 

  • Kameda T, Diasuke N (2002) Cost-benefit analysis of social/cultural learning in a nonstationary uncertain environment: an evolutionary simulation and an experiment with human subjects. Evol Hum Behav 23:373–393

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz D (1964) The motivational basis of organizational behavior. Behav Sci 9:131–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenney M, von Burg U (1999) Technology, entrepreneurship and path dependence: industrial clustering in Silicon Valley and route 128. Ind Corp Chang 8:67–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr NL (1989) Illusions of efficacy: the effects of group size on perceived efficacy in social dilemmas. J Exp Soc Psychol 25:287–313

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimberly JR (1975) Environmental constraints and organizational structure: a comparative analysis of rehabilitation organizations. Adm Sci Q 20:1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (1996) Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life cycle. Am Econ Rev 86:562–583

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (2002) The capabilities of New firms and the evolution of the US automobile industry. Ind Corp Chang 11:645–666

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (2009) Spinoffs: a review and synthesis. Eur Manag Rev 6:159–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (2010) The origin and growth of industry clusters: the making of Silicon Valley and Detroit. J Urban Econ 67:15–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Sleeper SB (2005) Entry by spinoffs. Manag Sci 51:1291–1306

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S, Thompson P (2010) Disagreements and intra-industry spinoffs. Int J Ind Organ 28:526–538

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosfeld M, von Siemens FA (2011) Competition, cooperation, and corporate culture. RAND J Econ 42:23–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotter JP, Heskett JL (1992) Corporate culture and performance. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Labov W (2001) Principles of linguistic change: social factors. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Langlois RN (1998) Personal capitalism as charismatic authority: the organizational economics of a Weberian concept. Ind Corp Chang 7:195–213

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine JM, Moreland RL (1990) Progress in small group research. Annu Rev Psychol 41:585–634

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine JM, Moreland RL (1998) Small groups. In: Gilbert DT, Fiske ST, Lindzey G (eds) The handbook of social psychology. McGraw-Hill, Boston, pp 415–469

    Google Scholar 

  • March JG (1991) Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organ Sci 2:71–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Markham SE, Dansereau F Jr, Alutto JA (1982) Group size and absenteeism rates: a longitudinal analysis. Acad Manag J 25:921–9271

    Google Scholar 

  • Marlowe FW (2005) Hunter-gatherers and human evolution. Evol Anthropol 14:54–67

    Google Scholar 

  • McKendrick DG, Wade JB, Jaffee J (2009) A good riddance? Spin-offs and the technological performance of parent firms. Organ Sci 20:979–992

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgram S (1974) Obedience to authority: an experimental view. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore G, Davis K (2004) Learning the Silicon Valley way. In: Bresnahan TF, Gambardella A (eds) Building high-tech clusters: Silicon Valley and beyond. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 7–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhaya K (2003) Jury size and the free rider problem. J Law Econ Organ 19:24–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Norenzayan A, Heine SJ (2005) Psychological universals: what are they and how can we know? Psychol Bull 131:763–784

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1994) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2009) A general framework for analyzing the sustainability of social-ecological systems. Science 325:419–422

    Google Scholar 

  • Pakes A, Nitzan S (1983) Optimum contracts for research personnel, research employment, and the establishment of Rival enterprises. J Labor Econ 1:345–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Pratten CF (1971) Economies of scale in manufacturing industry. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Richerson PJ, Boyd R (2005) Not by genes alone: how culture transformed human evolution. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Rob R, Zemsky P (2002) Social capital, corporate culture, and incentive intensity. RAND J Econ 33:243–257

    Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Kaplan HS (2003) The evolution of human life expectancy and intelligence in hunter-gatherer economies. Am Econ Rev 93:150–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers EM (1983) Diffusion of innovations. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin PH (1982) Evolved ethics and efficient ethics. J Econ Behav Organ 3:161–174

    Google Scholar 

  • Schein EH (1992) Organizational culture and leadership. Jossey-Bass Publishers, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling TC (1972) The process of residential segregation: neighborhood tipping. In: Pascal AH (ed) Racial discrimination in economic life. Lexington Books, Lexington, pp 157–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1939) Business cycles. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen JB (2007) Bureaucracy and entrepreneurship: workplace effects on entrepreneurial entry. Adm Sci Q 52:387–412

    Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen JB, Phillips DJ (2011) Competence and commitment: employer size and entrepreneurial endurance. Ind Corp Chang 20:1277–1304

    Google Scholar 

  • Spoor JR, Kelly JR (2004) The evolutionary significance of affect in groups: communication and group bonding. Group Process Intergroup Relat 7:398–412

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe AL (1965) Social structure and organizations. In: March JG (ed) Handbook of organizations. Rand-McNally, pp 142–193

  • Stuart TE, Sorenson O (2003) Liquidity events and the geographic distribution of entrepreneurial activity. Adm Sci Q 48:175–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ, Pisano G, Shuen A (1997) Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strateg Manag J 18:509–533

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson JD (1967) Organizations in action. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Tichy NM (1983) Managing strategic change: technical, political and cultural dynamics. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • van den Bergh JCJM, Gowdy JM (2009) A group selection perspective on economic behavior, institutions, and organizations. J Econ Behav Organ 72:1–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Van den Steen E (2010) On the origin of shared beliefs (and corporate culture). RAND J Econ 41:617–648

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner JA III (1995) Studies of individualism-collectivism: effects on cooperation in groups. Acad Manag J 38:152–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenting R (2008) Spinoff dynamics and the spatial formation of the fashion design industry, 1858–2005. J Econ Geogr 8:593–614

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (2002) The theory of the firm as governance structure: from choice to contract. J Econ Perspect 16:171–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (1998) Imagination and leadership—the neglected dimension of an evolutionary theory of the firm. J Econ Behav Organ 35:161–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2000) Changing cognitive frames—changing organizational forms: an entrepreneurial theory of organizational development. Ind Corp Chang 9:733–755

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2007) Firms as realizations of entrepreneurial visions. J Manag Stud 44:1125–1140

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are indebted to Guido Buenstorf from the University of Kassel for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Cordes.

Appendices

Appendix A

The general form of logistic models is the following:

$$n^{\prime} =n+xn\left( 1-\frac{\sum\limits_{i} {n_{i} } }{K} \right),$$
(11)

where the growth rate of n is denoted by x. We can derive this growth rate form n′ given by Eq. 1 in the text:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} x&=&\frac{n^{\prime} -n}{n}=\frac{1}{n}\left({pn\left({1+r_{c} }\right)+n( {1-p} )\left({1+r_{o}( n )} \right)-n}\right), \notag \\ &=&p({1+r_{c} })+({1-p})\left({1+r_{o}(n)}\right)-1. \end{array}$$
(12)

which gives the growth rate used in Eq. 3.

Appendix B

In order to account for the effects of new personnel joining the firm and the necessary “renewal” of the socialization of existing employees, who are then considered as if they were personnel just joining the firm, we suppose that in each time step a cohort of n employees “retires” and is replaced by n new employees who are socialized by all n old employees, plus the entrepreneur. In addition, we assume that all new employees show neutral behavior when they join the firm. Moreover, these new firm members encounter other employees at random. With the help of the cultural transmission table below (Table 1), we specify the probability that a particular set of role models with different weights makes an individual acquire the behavioral variant c or o, given a changing group size.

Table 1 The probability of agents acquiring behavior c or o given a particular set of models (Entrepreneur/Leader, Peers) that have different total weights (A E , A P

The variable p measures the frequency of the c type in an infinite meta population of firms of size n. That is, for illustrative simplicity we are here modeling only the deterministic effect of evolutionary processes. In any given firm, stochastic effects will be important. However, in an infinite population of firms with particular characteristics, p will perfectly describe the average frequency of the cooperative behavior and ( 1 − p) the opportunistic behavior. Therefore, the average pairing probability of role models in the transmission table will have A E + pnA P probability of transmitting c to each new member of a cohort and probability ( 1 − p)nA p of transmitting the behavioral variant o. Thus, in an infinite population of firms of size n, the partial recursion for the socialization phase with the frequency of c after transmission, p′, given that is was p before transmission, is expressed by Eq. 6 in the text.

Appendix C

We assume employees to choose an individual at random from the total number of a firm’s employees. Due to the direct bias μ co alone, which captures the attractiveness of opportunistic behavior, agents are probabilistically more likely to adopt behavior o (0 ≤ μ co ≤ 1) when they encounter it or to stick to it if they already behave opportunistically and meet a cooperative colleague. In addition, the conformist component, 2 p′ − 1, which depends on the frequency of behavior c in the firm, modifies the adoption probabilities as described in the text. Then, the probabilities of switching are given by Table 2.

Table 2 The probability of employees acquiring c or o given the behavior encountered

Using the probabilities of each possible pairing of “Self” and “Other”, we can calculate the frequency of behavior c after this kind of transmission process by multiplying the former by the different probabilities of switching to behavior c. We get the following recursion:

$$p^{\prime\prime} = {p^{\prime}}^{2} [1] + 2p^{\prime} (1 - p^{\prime}) \left[ \frac{1}{2} \left\{ 1 + (\eta (2p^{\prime} - 1) - (1- \eta) \mu_{co}) \right\} \right] + (1 - p^{\prime})^{2} [0]\,.$$
(13)

Simplifying gives (7) in the text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cordes, C., Richerson, P.J. & Schwesinger, G. A corporation’s culture as an impetus for spinoffs and a driving force of industry evolution. J Evol Econ 24, 689–712 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0335-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0335-3

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation