Skip to main content
Log in

Programmatic choices and the demand for theatre: the case of Flemish theatres

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Theatre experts generally agree that the Flemish theatre has flourished artistically over the period 1980–2000. Attendance, on the other hand, has declined significantly. Following Lancaster’s characteristics approach, we identify several output characteristics of individual theatre productions. Using a panel of 59 Flemish theatres, we examine the impact on demand of both these output characteristics and of traditional determinants such as own price, income and the price of substitutes. Differences in the relevant geographical market for touring and non-touring theatres are considered. We find that the nature of the artistic output affects demand. Theatregoers prefer large productions (in terms of cast size), plays by Dutch-speaking playwrights and revivals of old productions. Own price and consumer income have the expected negative and positive effects on attendance. Observed trends toward a decreasing proportion of new plays, an increasing presence of plays by Dutch-speaking playwrights, and increasing consumer income had a stimulating effect on attendance. These trends have been offset, however, by trends toward smaller cast sizes and higher ticket prices as well as by unobserved factors captured by time dummies. The net result has been a considerable drop in attendance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Such an approach, in a way, assumes perfect foresight on the part of the theatre managers. As Krebs and Pommerehne (1995) admit, it is always possible for a ‘lowbrow’ piece to be unsuccessful and for a ‘highbrow’ piece to be successful with the lay audience.

  2. The quality and critic ratings variables were not tested empirically (Kelejian & Lawrence, 1980).

  3. Repertoire diversity measures—such as conformity/conventionality indices, or the number of different productions in a season—have been used in studies examining the determinants of repertoire diversity. Special focus is given to the relationship between diversity and public funding (Austen-Smith, 1980; DiMaggio & Stenberg, 1985; O’Hagan & Neligan, 2005; Pierce, 2000). It would be interesting to use such measures in demand analysis. However, the use of the conformity index in the context of the Flemish theatre is difficult because of the small scale of the sector and the large heterogeneity of the chosen plays and playwrights. For example, out of the 193 theatre productions in 2000, 122 productions involved playwrights whose work was only performed in 1 production. There was only one playwright (Thomas Bernhard) for whom (a maximum number of) five productions were staged.

  4. The latter reflect two distinct effects on demand. First, expert opinions may be seen as an appreciation of the set of unobserved (by the empirical analyst) characteristics of a play. Second, these opinions may—given a set of characteristics—exert an effect on demand. Since a theatre performance is an experience good, consumers have the difficult task to assess the quality of a production prior to seeing the actual performance. Thus, they can rely on expert judgement to make their consumption decision.

  5. Structural subsidies are distributed to ensure the long-run operation of a theatre company; this in contrast to project subsidies that are distributed to support individual productions during a particular theatre season.

  6. In practice (minor) regional differences in the language persist between Flanders and the Netherlands. The actual situation is comparable with the differences between British and American English.

  7. The distinction between touring and non-touring theatre companies is based on a categorization of subsidized theatres by the Flemish Community.

  8. Data on theatre productions come from the ‘Vlaamse Theaterjaarboeken’ (Flemish Theatre Year Books) in the editions 1980–1981 to 1996–1997/1997–1998 and the online database (http://www.vti.be) from the Vlaams Theater Instituut (Flemish Theatre Institute). The detailed description of the theatre productions is taken to reflect which characteristics are relevant from the viewpoint of the theatre sector itself. Therefore, our own choice of output characteristics (z 1 to z 5) is based on the information provided by these data sources.

  9. Data on theatre attendance, box office revenues and the number of visitors come from the Flemish Ministry of Culture. Data on per capita income, number of inhabitants and cinema ticket prices come from the Nationaal Instituut voor Statistiek (NIS).

  10. As we already noted in Sect. 3, some theatres start as touring companies but end up having their own playhouse later on.

  11. The average price of cinema tickets was calculated by dividing box office income by the number of cinema visitors. Our data on movie theatres show that they are only located in large municipalities and not in their neighbouring municipalities. Hence, the use of the spatial weighting matrix to calculate the average price of cinema tickets was not relevant.

  12. It is standard practice for the fixed effects model (FEM) to be compared with the random effects model (REM). The REM involves rewriting the error term ɛ i,t as u i  + e i,t where u i is now the random disturbance characterizing the i-th observation (constant over time) and e it a remainder component which is assumed to be uncorrelated over time. To choose between the REM and the FEM, the Hausman test statistic (Hausman, 1978) tests whether the FE and RE estimators are significantly different. The Hausman test checks the more efficient REM against the less efficient but always consistent FEM. Large values of the Hausman statistic imply a larger variance of the RE estimator relative to the FE estimator and a greater efficiency of the FE estimator. Thus a rejection of the null hypothesis confirms the preference for the FE estimator to the RE alternative. For the random effects model to be preferred to the fixed effects model the Hausman test must not be rejected (Verbeek, 2004).

  13. To analyse subperiods, we split the sample into a 1980–1990 sample and a 1991–2000 sample. Concentrating on the significant coefficients in Table 1, we find that coefficients in the split samples have the same sign. Still, in terms of significance there is a difference. The effects found in Table 1 appear to derive mainly from the 1991–2000 period (in this subperiod, all significant variables in Table 1 except the share of Dutch-language plays are significant at 5%).

  14. The differences in results for the different specifications of the spatial weight matrix W i are small. For example, the consumer income variable is always positively significant with t-values of 2.14 (defining the relevant market as the municipality in which a given theatre is located), 2.76 (considering the municipality where the theatre is located as well as its geographical neighbours) and 2.51 (when also considering the neighbours’ neighbours), respectively. The population variable is insignificant in all three cases with t-values of .05, .31 and .03, respectively. Finally, R² values are 83.91%, 83.99% and 83.94% for the three specifications, respectively. On the basis of these results, the second specification is preferred.

  15. The positive relationship between cast size and attendance might indicate that theatre companies performing in playhouses with a larger capacity have the ability to stage large-scale productions as well as to attract larger audiences. However, we assume that average capacity remains the same over the studied period and is captured by theatre-specific fixed effects.

References

  • Abbé-Decarroux, F. (1994). The perception of quality and the demand of services: Empirical application to the performing arts. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 99–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1980). On the impact of revenue subsidies on repertory theatre policy. Journal of Cultural Economics, 4, 9–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W., & Baumol, H. (1985). On the cost disease and its true policy implications for the arts. In R. Towse (Ed.), Baumol’s cost disease. The arts and other victims (pp. 213–224). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75, 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonato, L., Gagliardi, F., & Gorelli, S. (1990). The demand for live performing arts in Italy. Journal of Cultural Economics, 14, 41–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brouwers, T. (1998). De Vlaamse gezelschappen, Terug naar af? In Vlaams Theaterjaarboek 1996–97/1997–98 (pp. 15–21). Brussel: Vlaams Theater Instituut.

  • Caves, R. (2000). Creative industries: Contracts between art and commerce. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corning, J., & Levy, A. (2002). Demand for live theater with market segmentation and seasonality. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26, 217–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P., & Stenberg, K. (1985). Why do some theatres innovate more than others? An empirical analysis. Poetics, 14, 107–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. (1987). Non-profit organisations in the production, distribution of culture In W. W. Powell (Ed.), The non-profit organisation. A research handbook (pp. 195–220). New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R., & Ritenour, S. (1999). An exploration of the Beckerian theory of time costs: Symphony concert demand. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 58, 887–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felton, M. V. (1992). On the assumed inelasticity of demand for the performing arts. Journal of Cultural Economics, 16, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gapinski, J. (1984). The economics of performing Shakespeare. American Economic Review, 74, 458–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gapinski, J. (1986). The lively arts as substitutes for the lively arts. American Economic Review, 76, 20–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greckel F. R., & Felton M. V. (1987). Price and income elasticities of demand: A case study of Louisville, In N. Grant, W. Hendon, & V. Owen (Eds.), Economic efficiency and the performing arts (pp. 62–73). Akron: Association for Cultural Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H. (1981). Non-profit enterprise in the performing arts. Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 341–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251–1271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heilbrun, J., & Gray, C. M. (2001). The economics of art and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, S., & Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Interdependent decision-making in non-profit industries: A simultaneous equation analysis of English provincial theatre. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5, 149–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian H., & Lawrence, W. J. (1980). Estimating the demand for Broadway theatres: A preliminary inquiry, In W. Hendon, J. Shanahan, & A. MacDonald (Eds.), Economic policy for the arts (pp. 333–346). Cambridge: Abt Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krebs, S., & Pommerehne, W. (1995). Politico-economic interactions of German public performing arts institutions. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19, 17–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. (1971). Consumer demand: A new approach. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laermans, R. (2003). Oeuvreloos maar niet werkeloos. Kleine cultuursociologie van de Vlaamse podiumkunst anno 2003. In M. Uytterhoeven (Ed.), Pigment. Tendensen in het Vlaamse podiumlandschap (pp. 51–53). Brussel: Ludion Gent / Vlaams Theater Instituut.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montias, J. M. (1983). Public support for the performing arts in Europe and the United States, reprinted in DiMaggio, P. (1986). Nonprofit enterprise in the Arts. Studies in mission and constraint (pp. 287–319). New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Moore, T. G. (1966). The demand for Broadway theatre tickets. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48, 79–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Hagan, J. (1998). The state and the arts: An analysis of key economic policy issues in Europe and the United States. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Hagan, J., & Neligan, A. (2005). State subsidies and repertoire conventionality in the non-profit English theatre sector: An econometric analysis. Journal of Cultural Economics, 29, 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, J. L. (2000). Programmatic risk-taking by American opera companies. Journal of Cultural Economics, 24, 45–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli, F. (2003). Reaction or interaction? Spatial process identification in multi-tiered government structures. Journal of Urban Economics, 53, 29–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1990). Perception of quality in demand for the theatre. Journal of Cultural Economics, 14, 65–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1994) The production and consumption of the arts: A view of cultural economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Touchstone, S. (1980). The effects of contributions on price and attendance in the lively arts. Journal of Cultural Economics, 4, 33–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urrutiaguer, D. (2002). Quality judgements and demand for French public theatre. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22, 185–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Dries, L. (1996a). Première van Mistero Buffo in de Munt. Ontgrenzing van het Vlaams-Nederlands theatergebied. In R. L. Erenstein (Ed.), Een theatergeschiedenis der Nederlanden. Tien eeuwen drama en theater in Nederland en Vlaanderen. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

  • Van den Dries, L. (1996b). Jan Fabre regisseert Het is theater zoals te verwachten en te voorzien was. De internationale doorbraak van het Vlaamse theater. In R. L. Erenstein (Ed.), Een theatergeschiedenis der Nederlanden. Tien eeuwen drama en theater in Nederland en Vlaanderen. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

  • Verbeek, M. (2004). A guide to modern econometrics. Chichester: John Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werck, K., Grinwis, M., & Heyndels, B. (2004). Baumol’s suppressed cost disease and programmatic choices by Flemish subsidized theatres, Paper presented at the 13th Conference of the Association for Cultural Economics, International. Chicago, 2–5 June.

  • Withers, G. (1977). Demand for performing arts services. In K. A. Tucker (Ed.), Economics of the Australian service sector (pp. 385–413). London: Croom Helm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Withers, G. (1980). Unbalanced growth and the demand for the performing arts: An econometric analysis. Southern Economic Journal, 46, 735–742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank two anonymous referees as well as Mona Grinwis and John Ashworth for their helpful and incisive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kristien Werck.

Appendix

Appendix

Table A1 List of variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Werck, K., Heyndels, B. Programmatic choices and the demand for theatre: the case of Flemish theatres. J Cult Econ 31, 25–41 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-006-9026-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-006-9026-3

Keywords

Navigation