Skip to main content
Log in

Efficiency measurement when producers control pollutants: a non-parametric approach

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper treats efficiency measurement when some outputs are undesirable and producers control pollutants by end-of-pipe or change-in-process abatement. A data envelopment analysis framework that compares producers with similar pollution control efforts is proposed. First, my approach avoids arbitrary disposability assumptions for undesirable outputs. Second, the model is used to evaluate the interplay between pollution control activities and technical efficiency. I compare my approach to the traditional neo-classical production model that does not incorporate undesirable outputs among outputs, and to Färe et al.’s (Rev Econ Stat 71:90–98, 1989, J Econom 126:469–492, 2005) well-known model that incorporates bads. I evaluate the common assumption in the literature on polluting technologies, that inputs are allocatable to pollution control, and apply U.S. electricity data to illustrate my main point: Although my empirical model specifications are in line with the literature on polluting technologies, they rely on inputs that play an insignificant role in controlling nitrogen oxides (NOx) emissions. Consequentially, there are no reasons to expect the efficiency scores of the traditional model to differ from the efficiency scores of the other two models that account for resources employed to pollution control. Statistical tests show that my model, which explicitly takes pollution control efforts into account, produces efficiency scores that are not statistically different from the traditional model’s scores for all model specifications, while Färe et al.’s model produces significantly different results for some model specifications. I conclude that the popular production models that incorporate undesirable outputs may not be applicable to all cases involving polluting production and that more emphasis on appropriate empirical specifications is needed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This approach has become popular in research that integrate the materials balance condition in microeconomic production analysis; see e.g. Coelli et al. (2007) and Lauwers (2009).

  2. End-of-pipe abatement involves production processes that transform uncontrolled byproducts into different byproducts that are of less threat to the environment. One of the issues with end-of-pipe abatement is that it causes additional byproducts, since the abatement process itself is also subordinate to the laws of physics. This issue will not be treated further in the current article; see Pethig (2006) for a discussion.

  3. Recently, some authors have applied Network DEA (Färe and Grosskopf, 2000) to model pollution control activities explicitly (Färe et al. 2013; Hampf, 2013). These studies determine which inputs are allocatable to the production of desirable outputs and pollution control.

  4. The weak disposability model does however not rule out regions of the outputs sets where undesirable outputs can be reduced while simultaneously increasing desirable outputs.

  5. One referee pointed out that the issue of negative shadow prices can also be resolved by assuming that pollutants are freely disposable inputs (or costly disposable outputs). This approach to modeling undesirable outputs is explored by Hailu and Veeman (2001), but has been criticized by Färe and Grosskopf (2003) for being inconsistent with physical laws.

  6. The power plants face regulation on both nitrogen and sulfur emissions. The regulations on sulfur emissions involve emissions trading, while the regulations on nitrogen to a larger extent are based on emission standards. In Rødseth (2011), emissions trading and pollution control are viewed as substitutes that may both be applied to increase the production of desirable outputs without violating legal emission constraints. Since the current paper is concerned with resources allocated to pollution control I choose to focus on nitrogen control, to avoid considerations between pollution control and emissions trading.

  7. The original dataset is collected for the period 2002–2009 and has been updated for 2002–2005. It uses a modified selection criterion, namely that the plants must satisfy Welch and Barnum’s criterion in 2002 and have nonzero consumption of coal and gas in the following years. Consequentially, some of the plants in the sample may violate Welch and Barnum’s criterion in 2005. Historical information does, however, show that the plants in the sample have gas capacities that allow them to satisfy the selection criterion.

  8. The efficiency scores must be multiplied with 100 in order to show percentage change.

  9. Although they are not discussed in this section, the estimated efficiency scores for plants with missing labor data are printed in italics in Table 2.

  10. For comparison, I also execute the tests for all 54 power plants for the model specifications with labor. In this case, no test rejects the null hypotheses for the pollution control model, but the KSM, WILC and MED tests reject the null hypotheses at the 10 percent level for the weak disposability model.

References

  • Ball E, Färe R, Grosskopf S, Zaim O (2005) Accounting for externalities in the measurement of productivity growth: the Malmquist cost productivity measure. Struct Change Econ Dynam 16:374–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbera AJ, McConnell VD (1990) The impact of environmental regulations on industry productivity: direct and indirect effects. J Environ Econ Manag 18:50–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumgärtner S, Arons JS (2003) Necessity and inefficiency in the generation of waste. J Ind Ecol 7:113–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgärtner S, Dyckhoff H, Faber M, Proops J, Schiller J (2001) The concept of joint production and ecological economics. Ecol Econ 36:365–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brännlund R, Lundgren T (2009) Environmental policy without costs? A review of the Porter hypothesis. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 3:75–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Brännlund R, Färe R, Grosskopf S (1995) Environmental regulation and profitability: an application to Swedish pulp and paper mills. Environ Resour Econ 6:23–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung YH, Färe R, Grosskopf S (1997) Productivity and undesirable outputs: a directional distance function approach. J Environ Manag 51:229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli T, Lauwers L, Van Huylenbroeck G (2007) Environmental efficiency measurement and the materials balance condition. J Prod Anal 28:3–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2000) Network DEA. Socio Econ Plan Sci 34:35–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2003) Nonparametric productivity analysis with undesirable outputs: comment. Am J Agric Econ 85:1070–1074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK, Pasurka CA (1989) Multilateral productivity comparisons when some outputs are undesirable: a nonparametric approach. Rev Econ Stat 71:90–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Pasurka CA (2001) Accounting for air pollution emissions in measures of state manufacturing productivity growth. J Regional Sci 41:381–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Noh D-W, Weber WL (2005) Characteristics of a polluting technology: theory and practice. J Econom 126:469–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Weber WL (2006) Shadow prices and pollution costs in U.S. agriculture. Ecol Econ 56:89–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Pasurka CA (2007a) Environmental production functions and environmental directional distance functions. Energy 32:1055–1066

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Pasurka CA (2007b) Pollution abatement activities and traditional productivity. Ecol Econ 62:673–682

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Pasurka CA (2013) Joint production of good and bad outputs with a network application. In: Shogren JF (ed) Encyclopedia of energy, natural resources and environmental economics. Elsevier, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR (2009) Good modelling of bad outputs: pollution and multiple-output production. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 3:1–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Hailu A, Veeman TS (2001) Non-parametric productivity analysis with undesirable outputs: an application to the Canadian pulp and paper industry. Am J Agric Econ 83:605–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hampf B (2013) Separating environmental efficiency into production and abatement efficiency: a nonparametric model with application to US power plants. J Prod Anal. doi:10.1007/s11123-013-0357-8

  • Jaffe AB, Peterson SR, Portney PR, Stavins RN (1995) Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: what does the evidence tell us? J Econ Lit 33:132–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuosmanen T (2005) Weak disposability in nonparametric production analysis with undesirable outputs. Am J Agric Econ 87:1077–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuosmanen T (2009) Data envelopment analysis with missing data. J Oper Res Soc 60:1767–1774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lauwers L (2009) Justifying the incorporation of the materials balance principle into frontier-based eco-efficiency models. Ecol Econ 68:1605–1614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Y, Sumaila UR (2010) Estimating pollution abatement costs of salmon aquaculture: a joint production approach. Land Econ 86:569–584

    Google Scholar 

  • Murty S (2010) Externalities and fundamental nonconvexities: a reconciliation of approaches to general equilibrium externality modeling and implications for decentralization. J Econ Theory 145:331–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murty S, Robert Russell R, Levkoff SB (2012) On modeling pollution-generating technologies. J Environ Econ Manag 64:117–135

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C, Rao DSP, Battese G (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empir Econ 34:231–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmer K, Oates WE, Portney PR (1995) Tightening environmental standards: the benefit-cost or the no-cost paradigm? J Econ Perspect 9:119–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasurka CA (2006) Decomposing electric power plant emissions within a joint production framework. Energy Econ 28:26–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pethig R (2006) Non-linear production, abatement, pollution and materials balance reconsidered. J Environ Econ Manag 51:185–204

    Google Scholar 

  • Picazo-Tadeo AJ, Prior D (2009) Environmental externalities and efficiency measurement. J Environ Manag 90:3332–3339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter M, Van Der Linde C (1995) Toward a new conception of the environment–competitiveness relationship. J Econ Perspect 9:97–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray SC (1988) Data envelopment analysis, nondiscretionary inputs and efficiency: an alternative interpretation. Socio Econ Plan Sci 22:167–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reig-Martínez E, Picazo-Tadeo AJ, Hernández-Sancho F (2001) The calculation of shadow prices for industrial wastes using distance functions: an analysis for Spanish ceramic pavements firms. Int J Prod Econ 69:277–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rødseth KL (2011) Treatment of undesirable outputs in production analysis: desirable modeling strategies and applications. Thesis, Institute for Economics and Resource Management. Norwegian University of Life Sciences, Ås

  • Rødseth KL (2013) Capturing the least costly way of reducing pollution: a shadow price approach. Ecol Econ 92:16–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggiero J (1996) On the measurement of technical efficiency in the public sector. Eur J Oper Res 90:553–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadbegian RJ, Gray WB (2005) Pollution abatement expenditures and plant-level productivity: a production function approach. Ecol Econ 54:196–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW, Färe R (1974) The law of diminishing returns. Z Nationalokonomie 34:69–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simar L, Wilson PW (2007) Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econom 136:31–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welch E, Barnum D (2009) Joint environmental and cost efficiency analysis of electricity generation. Ecol Econ 68:2336–2343

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author thanks two anonymous referees for their helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth Løvold Rødseth.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rødseth, K.L. Efficiency measurement when producers control pollutants: a non-parametric approach. J Prod Anal 42, 211–223 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0382-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0382-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation