Skip to main content
Log in

Why does production function take the Cobb–Douglas form?

Direct observation of production function using empirical data

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We directly observed a Cobb–Douglas symmetric plane using the index of surface openness, which is used in geography, and successfully identified it. Based on this observation, we measured the capital shares (capital elasticity) and labor shares (labor elasticity) and compared them with the results of multiple regression analysis used in economics. We confirmed consistent agreement in seven countries: Japan, Germany, France, Spain, Italy, the UK, and the Netherlands. Thus, we show that the Cobb–Douglas production function can be clearly captured in empirical data as a geometric entity with a quasi-inverse symmetry of variables. Based on the above discussion, we theoretically clarified why the Cobb–Douglas production function is better fitted to empirical data in economics, because it uniquely derives the fact that its variable follows a power-law distribution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aoki M, Yoshikawa H (2007) Reconstructing macroeconomics - a perspecrive from statistical physics and conbinatiorial stochastic processes. Cambridge University Press, Cambrige

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Iyetomi H, Ikeda Y, Souma W, Fujiwara Y (2008) Econophysics. Kyoritsu Shuppan CO., LTD, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Yoshikawa H, Iyetomi H, Fujiwara Y (2009) Labour productivity superstatistics. Prog Theor Phys Suppl No 179:80–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Fujiwara Y, Ikeda Y, Iyetomi H, Souma W (2009) Superstatistics of labour productivity in manufacturing and nonmanufacturing sectors. Econ Open Access Open Assess E J 3:2009–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Yoshikawa H, Iyetomi H, Fujiwara Y (2010) Productivity dispersion: facts, theory, and implications. J Econ Interact Coord 5:27–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Iyetomi H, Yoshikawa H (2015) Equilibrium distribution of labor productivity. J Econ Interact Coord 10:57–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama H, Fujiwara Y, Ikeda Y, Iyetomi H, Souma W, Yoshikawa H (2017) Macro-econophysics: new studies on economic networks and synchronization (physics of society: econophysics and sociophysics). Cambridge University Press, Cambrige

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ, Chenery HB, Minhas BS, Solow RM (1961) Capital-labor substitution and economic efficiency. Rev Econ Stat 43:225–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bureau van Dijk (2020) http://www.bvdinfo.com/Home.aspx/

  • Christensen LR, Jorgenson DW, Lau LJ (1973) Transcendental logarithmic production function. Rev Econ Stat 55:28–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clauset A, Shalizi CR, Newman MEJ (2009) Power-law distributions in empirical data. SIAM Rev 51:661–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cobb CW, Douglass PH (1928) A theory of production. Am Econ Rev 18:139–165

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Grazzi M, Marrengo L, Settepanella S (2016) Production theory: accounting for firm heterogeneity and technical change. J Ind Econ 64(4):875–907

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara Y, Souma W, Aoyama H, Kaizoji T, Aoki M (2003) Growth and fluctuations of personal income. Phys A 321:598–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara Y, Guilmi CD, Aoyama H, Gallegati M, Souma W (2004) Do Pareto–Zipf and Gibrat laws hold true? An analysis with European firms. Phys A 335:197–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat R (1932) Les Inégalités Économiques. Sirey, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Hildenbrnad W (1981) Short-run production functions based on microdata. Econometrica 49(5):1095–1125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker HS (1955) The Pareto distribution and the cobb-douglas production function in activity analysis. Rev Econ Stud 23:27–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa A (2006) Annual change of Pareto index dynamically deduced from the law of detailed quasi-balance. Phys A 371:525–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa A (2009) Quasistatically varying log-normal distribution in the middle scale region of Japanese land prices. Prog Theor Phys Suppl 179:103–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa A, Fujimoto S, Watanabe T, Mizuno T (2013) The emergence of different tail exponents in the distributions of firm size variables. Phys A 392:2104–2113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa A, Fujimoto S, Mizuno T, Watanabe T (2014) Analytical derivation of power laws in firm size variables from Gibrat’s law and quasi-inversion symmetry: a geomorphological approach. J Phys Soc Jpn 83:034802

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyetomi H (2012) Labor productivity distributions with negative tempreature. Prog Theor Phys Suppl No 194:135–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mizuno T, Ishikawa A, Fujimoto S, Watanabe T (2012) Power laws in firm productivity. Prog Theor Phys Suppl 194:122–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ (2005) Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf’s law. Contemp Phys 46:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto V (1897) Cours d’Économie Politique. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Prima ODA, Echigo A, Yokoyama R, Yoshida T (2006) Supervised landform classification of Northeast Honshu from DEM-derived thematic maps. Geomorphology 78:373–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Souma W (2007) Networks of firms and the ridge in the production space. In: Chatterjee A, Chakrabarti BK (eds) Econophysics of markets and business networks. Springer Italia, Milan, pp 149–158

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Souma W, Ikeda Y, Iyetomi H, Fujiwara Y (2009) Distribution of labour productivity in Japan over the period 1996–2006. Econ Open Access Open Assess E J 3:2009–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Bureau (2020) Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. https://www.stat.go.jp/english/index.html

  • Sutton J (1997) Gibrat’s legacy. J Econ Lit 35:40–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Yokoyama R, Sirasawa M, Kikuchi Y (1999) Representation of topographical fearures by openness. J Jpn Soc Photogramm Remote Sens 38:26–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Yokoyama R, Sirasawa M, Pike R (2002) Visualizing topography by openness: a new application of image processing to digital elevation models. Photogramm Eng Remote Sens 68:257–265

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Dr. Tsutomu Watanabe with whom much of this work was discussed. This study was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 17K01277, 16H05904, 18H05217, ROIS NII Open Collaborative Research, Research Organization of Information and Systems 2019-FS01, the Obayashi Foundation, and The Okawa Foundation for Information and Telecommunications.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Atushi Ishikawa.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interest regarding the publication of this article.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants performed by any of the authors.

Informed consent

Informed consent was obtained from all individual participants included in the study.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Here, we show that under the inverse symmetry (4), according to Fujiwara et al. (2003, 2004), the power laws of \(x _ 1\) and \(x _ 2\) with the same Pareto index are derived from Gibrat’s law (5). Using growth rate \(R=x_2/x_1\), (4) is rewritten by variables \(x_1, R\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{12}(x_{1},R)=R^{-1}~P_{12}(R x_{1}, R^{-1}). \end{aligned}$$
(33)

Using conditional PDF \(Q (R | x_1) = P_{12} (x_1, R) / P (x_1)\) and Gibrat’s law (5), this can be reduced:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P(x_1)}{P(R x_{1})} = \frac{1}{R} \frac{Q(R^{-1}|R x_{1})}{Q(R|x_1)} = \frac{1}{R} \frac{Q(R^{-1})}{Q(R)}. \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Since the system has inverse symmetry, Gibrat’s law (5) is also established under the inverse transformation of \(x_1 \leftrightarrow R x_1 ~ (= x_ {2})\). The right side of Eq. (34) is only a function of R, and so, we signify it by G(R) and expand Eq. (34) by \(R = 1 + \epsilon ~(\epsilon \ll 1)\) in \(\epsilon\). The zeroth order term of \(\epsilon\) is trivial, and the first-order term yields the following differential equation:

$$\begin{aligned} G'(1) P(x_1) + x_1 \frac{d}{dx_1} P(x_1) = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Here, \(G '(\cdot )\) means the R differentiation of \(G (\cdot )\). No more useful information can be obtained from the second-order and higher order terms of \(\epsilon\). The solution to this equation is uniquely given:

$$\begin{aligned} P(x_1) \propto {x_1}^{- G'(1)}. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

This solution satisfies Eq. (34) even if R is not near \(R = 1\), when \(Q (R) = R ^ {-G '(1) -1} ~Q (R)\) holds (this is called a reflection law). Reflection law has been confirmed with various actual data (Fujiwara et al. 2004). Finally, if we set \(G '(1) = \mu + 1\), Eq. (36) matches the power laws (1), (2), and (3) described by variables at 1 year \(x_1\). Since this system has symmetry \(x_1 \leftrightarrow x_ {2}\), the power laws holds for the same Pareto index \(\mu\) even at time 2.

Appendix 2

Here, we show that according to Ishikawa (2006, 2009), Mizuno et al. (2012), and Ishikawa et al. (2013, 2014), under the quasi-inverse symmetry (6), the power laws of \(x _ 1\) and \(x _ 2\) with different Pareto indices are derived from Gibrat’s law (5). Using extended growth rate \(R = x_{T+1}/{a {x_T}^{\theta }}\), (6) is rewritten by variables \(x_1, R\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{12}(x_{1},R)=R^{1/{\theta }-2}~P_{12}(R^{1/\theta } x_1, R^{-1}). \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Equation (37) is reduced to Eq. (33) at \(\theta = 1\). Using the conditional PDF \(Q (R | x_T)\) and Gibrat’s law (5), this is reduced to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P(x_1)}{P(R^{1/\theta } x_{1})} = R^{1/{\theta }-2} \frac{Q(R^{-1}|R^{1/\theta } x_{1})}{Q(R|x_1)} = R^{1/{\theta }-2} \frac{Q(R^{-1})}{Q(R)}. \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Here, we assume that Gibrat’s law (5) holds under a transformation: \(x_1 \leftrightarrow R^{1/\theta } x_1 ~(=(x_{2}/a)^{1/\theta })\). This is valid in a system that has quasi-inverse symmetry. Since the last term in Eq. (38) is only a function of R, we signify it by \(G _ {\theta } (R)\) and expand Eq. (38) to R near 1 as \(R = 1 + \epsilon ~(\epsilon \ll 1)\). The zeroth order of \(\epsilon\) is trivial, and the first-order term yields the following differential equation:

$$\begin{aligned} {G_{\theta }}'(1) P(x_1) + \frac{x_1}{\theta } \frac{{\text {d}}}{{\text {d}}x_1} P(x_1) = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Here, \({G_{\theta }}'(\cdot )\) denotes the R differentiation of \(G_{\theta }(\cdot )\). No more useful information can be obtained from the second-order and higher order terms of \(\epsilon\). The solution to this equation is uniquely given:

$$\begin{aligned} P(x_1) \propto {x_1}^{- \theta {G_{\theta }}'(1)}. \end{aligned}$$
(40)

Similar to Appendix 1, this solution satisfies Eq. (38) even if R is not near \(R = 1\), when \(Q(R) = R^{-{G_{\theta }}'(1)-1}~Q(R)\) holds.

Next, in quasi-static system \((x_1, x_ {2})\), we identify distribution \(P (x_ {2})\). Actually, we should write \(P_ {x_1} (x_1)\), \(P_ {x_ {2}} (x_ {2})\); however, because function forms are complicated, they are collectively written as P. From Eq. (40) and \(P(x_1) dx_1 = P(x_{2}) dx_{2}\), \(P (x_ {2})\) can be expressed:

$$\begin{aligned} P(x_{2}) = P(x_1) \frac{{\text {d}} x_1}{{\text {d}} x_{2}} \propto {x_{2}}^{- {G_{\theta }}'(1) + 1/\theta - 1}. \end{aligned}$$
(41)

Here, we signify Pareto indices at year 1, 2 by \(\mu _{1}\), \(\mu _{2}\) and represent \(P(x_1)\), \(P(x_{2})\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} P(x_1) \propto {x_1}^{- \mu _1 - 1} ,\quad P(x_{2}) \propto {x_{2}}^{- \mu _{2} - 1}. \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Comparing Eqs. (40) and (41) to Eq. (42), we obtain \(\theta {G_{\theta }}'(1) = \mu _1 + 1\), \({G_{\theta }}'(1) - 1/\theta + 1 = \mu _{2} + 1\) and conclude the relation among \(\mu _1\), \(\mu _{2}\), and \(\theta\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \theta = \frac{\mu _{1}}{\mu _{2}}. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ishikawa, A., Fujimoto, S. & Mizuno, T. Why does production function take the Cobb–Douglas form?. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 18, 79–102 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00180-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-020-00180-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation