Skip to main content

Plea Bargaining: Negotiated Justice

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Paradox of Punishment
  • 536 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces another player in the criminal process, the prosecutor, who is instrumental in the determination of actual criminal punishments through the practice of plea bargaining. Under plea bargaining, which is a literal negotiation between prosecutors and defendants over criminal sentences, prosecutors exercise considerable discretion regarding both what charge to bring and what sentence to offer. The vast majority of criminal convictions in the United States are achieved in this way. The chapter reviews economic theories of this practice and emphasizes the trade-off between the resulting savings in trial costs and the risk of wrongful conviction. It concludes by examining how plea bargaining affects the goals of deterrence and corrective justice.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    404 U.S. 257 (1971).

  2. 2.

    397 U.S. 742 (1970).

  3. 3.

    Technically, the distribution for guilty defendants is shifted rightward compared to that for innocent defendants in the sense of first-order stochastic dominance.

  4. 4.

    For example, Blackstone famously said that “it is better that ten guilty persons escape, than that one innocent suffer.” This view echoes that of the biblical story of Sodom and Gomorrah in which Abraham, after much back and forth, elicits a promise from the Lord that he will not destroy the city of Sodom for the sake of as few as ten righteous people (Genesis 18: 22–33).

  5. 5.

    As noted earlier, Posner (2003, p. 620) puts the range for “beyond reasonable doubt” at between 75% and 95% certainty. In the case of In Re Winship (397 U.S. 358 (1970), the Supreme Court held that the beyond-a-reasonable-doubt standard was required in criminal trials under the due process clause of the Constitution.

  6. 6.

    Hylton and Khanna (2009) offer a somewhat different theory for these safeguards, as will be noted below.

  7. 7.

    See generally the survey of the law-and-economics literature on plea bargaining by Gazal-Ayal and Riza (2009), and the discussion of prosecutorial objectives in Garoupa (2012).

  8. 8.

    We will abstract here from the existence of a sentencing range and simply assume that, for the crime in question, a convicted defendant must receive a sentence of s.

  9. 9.

    This is the condition for the upper bound in (5.1) to be at least as large as the lower bound.

  10. 10.

    This includes crimes not listed in Table 5.1.

  11. 11.

    This is the outcome that would arise from ordinary Nash bargaining.

  12. 12.

    This is the explanation offered by Landes (1971). Also see Cooter and Rubinfeld (1989).

  13. 13.

    See, for example, Bebchuk (1984), who first explained trials in this way.

  14. 14.

    Formally, the conditional expected value of ε among defendants who go to trial (i.e., those for whom ε ≥ ε0) is increasing in b.

  15. 15.

    Baker and Mezzetti (2001) show that in this case, the only type of equilibrium that exists involves some guilty defendants and all innocent ones opting for trial. Thus, some type 2 errors are possible.

  16. 16.

    There is, however, evidence that this situation is changing. See Adelstein (2017, pp. 231–233) and Gazal-Ayal and Riza (2009).

  17. 17.

    We will argue in Chap. 8 that some people obey the law irrespective of the consequences simply because it is the “right” thing to do.

References

  • Adelstein, Richard. 1998. Plea Bargaining: A Comparative Approach. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Law and Economics, ed. P. Newman. New York: Stockton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. The Exchange Order: Property and Liability as an Exchange System. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Adelstein, Richard, and Thomas J. Miceli. 2001. Toward a Comparative Economics of Plea Bargaining. European Journal of Law and Economics 11: 47–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, Scott, and Claudio Mezzetti. 2001. Prosecutorial Resources, Plea Bargaining, and the Decision to Go to Trial. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 17: 149–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, Lucian. 1984. Litigation and Settlement Under Imperfect Information. RAND Journal of Economics 15: 404–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjerk, David. 2005. Making the Crime Fit the Penalty: The Role of Prosecutorial Discretion Under Mandatory Minimum Sentencing. Journal of Law and Economics 48: 591–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2007. Guilt Shall Not Escape or Innocence Suffer? The Limits of Plea Bargaining When Defendant Guilt Is Uncertain. American Law and Economics Review 9: 305–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, Robert, and Daniel Rubinfeld. 1989. An Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution. Journal of Economic Literature 27: 1067–1097.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubber, Markus. 1997. American Plea Bargains, German Lay Judges, and the Crisis of Criminal Procedure. Stanford Law Review 49: 547–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterbrook, Frank. 1983. Criminal Procedure as a Market System. The Journal of Legal Studies 12: 289–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, Lawrence. 2004. Law in America: A Short History. New York: The Modern Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froeb, Luke. 1993. The Adverse Selection of Cases for Trial. International Review of Law and Economics 13: 317–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garoupa, Nuno. 2012. The Economics of Prosecutors. In Research Handbook on the Economics of Criminal Law, ed. Alon Harel and Keith Hylton. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gazal-Ayal, Oren, and Limor Riza. 2009. Plea-Bargaining and Prosecution. In Criminal Law and Economics, ed. N. Garoupa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Gene, and Michael Katz. 1983. Plea Bargaining and Social Welfare. American Economic Review 73: 749–757.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huff, C. Ronald, Ayre Rattner, and Edward Sagarin. 1996. Convicted But Innocent: Wrongful Conviction and Public Policy. Thousand Oaks: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hylton, Keith, and Vikramaditya Khanna. 2009. Political Economy of Criminal Procedure. In Criminal Law and Economics, ed. N. Garoupa. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, Louis. 2011. On the Optimal Burden of Proof. Journal of Political Economy 119: 1102–1140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, Leo. 1996. Ill-Gotten Gains: Evasion, Blackmail, Fraud, and Kindred Puzzles of the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, William. 1971. An Economic Analysis of the Courts. Journal of Law and Economics 14: 61–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langbein, John. 1979. Land Without Plea Bargaining: How the Germans Do It. Michigan Law Review 78: 204–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, Thomas. 1990. Optimal Prosecution of Defendants Whose Guilt Is Uncertain. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6: 189–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1996. Plea Bargaining and Deterrence: An Institutional Approach. European Journal of Law and Economics 3: 249–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. The Economic Approach to Law. 3rd ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Png, I. 1986. Optimal Subsidies and Damages in the Presence of Legal Error. International Review of Law and Economics 6: 101–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, Richard. 2003. Economic Analysis of Law. 6th ed. New York: Aspen Law and Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum, Jennifer. 1988. Plea Bargaining and Prosecutorial Discretion. American Economic Review 78: 713–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulhofer, Stephen. 1988. Criminal Justice Discretion as a Regulatory System. The Journal of Legal Studies 17: 43–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas J. Miceli .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Miceli, T.J. (2019). Plea Bargaining: Negotiated Justice. In: The Paradox of Punishment. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-31695-2_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-31695-2_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-31694-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-31695-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics