Skip to main content

Determinants of the Investment Rate in the Economy and Their Relevance in Entry Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Market Entry and Competition Law in Latin America

Part of the book series: Munich Studies on Innovation and Competition ((MSIC,volume 14))

  • 146 Accesses

Abstract

The issue of economic growth has been the focus of great attention in the economics literature for a long period of time. Based on the model developed by Solow, neoclassical growth theory predicts differences in growth rates based on, among other factors, a country’s propensity to invest. Levine and Renelt find empirical support for this prediction. As a result, there have been numerous works that seek to identify the determinants of investment rates. From the myriad of variables that have been studied, there have been efforts to identify the ones that are more robustly associated with economic performance. This literature has a special value for antitrust law and economics because the factors that influence a firm’s decision to invest are directly related to the decision of entering a market. Not taking them into account can lead to error costs in enforcement interventions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Solow (1956).

  2. 2.

    Mankiw et al. (1992), pp. 422–425.

  3. 3.

    Levine and Renelt (1992), p. 947.

  4. 4.

    See, for example: Sala-i-Martin et al. (2004), Levine and Renelt (1992), and Barro (1991).

  5. 5.

    For an overview of common country characteristics relevant for competition law in different sub-regions in Sub-Saharan Africa, see Fox and Bakhoum (2019).

  6. 6.

    It should also be pointed out that in most of the cases portrayed in Chap. 8 concerned national and sub-national markets. Many of the cases where in infrastructure industries such as telecommunications services and water provision, which tend to circumscribed to investments within national borders.

  7. 7.

    Sala-i-Martin et al. (2004), p. 824; and Levine and Renelt (1992), p. 950.

  8. 8.

    Ibid.

  9. 9.

    See Gerber (2010) and De Leon (2009).

  10. 10.

    Mauro (1995), p. 685.

  11. 11.

    Ibid.

  12. 12.

    Coase (1960).

  13. 13.

    North (1989), p. 1319.

  14. 14.

    Dixit and Pindyck (1994).

  15. 15.

    See, for example: Barro (1991), Levine and Renelt (1992), Mauro (1995), Knack and Keefer (1995), Brunetti and Weder (1998), and Henisz (2000).

  16. 16.

    Pande and Udry (2005), p. 17.

  17. 17.

    See, for example: Bruno et al. (2011), where the authors exploit regional institutional variations within Russia to explain differences in entry rates; and Pamukçu et al. (2009), where the authors analyze the impact of the change in trade policy on entry rates in Turkey’s manufacturing sector.

  18. 18.

    15 U.S.C § 78dd–1.

  19. 19.

    Leff (1964), p. 10.

  20. 20.

    Mauro (1995), p. 685.

  21. 21.

    Leff (1964), pp. 10–11.

  22. 22.

    Mauro (1995), p. 683.

  23. 23.

    Id., p. 698.

  24. 24.

    Id., pp. 699–700. Another study that finds a significant negative association between corruption and economic performance is Knack and Keefer (1995).

  25. 25.

    Mauro (1995), p. 698.

  26. 26.

    Wei (2000).

  27. 27.

    Id., p. 5.

  28. 28.

    Ibid.

  29. 29.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), p. 527.

  30. 30.

    Id., p. 514.

  31. 31.

    Ibid.

  32. 32.

    Id., p. 527.

  33. 33.

    Mauro (1995), p. 690.

  34. 34.

    Id., p. 700.

  35. 35.

    Asiedu and Freeman (2009).

  36. 36.

    Id., p. 204.

  37. 37.

    Id., pp. 204–205.

  38. 38.

    Id., p. 204.

  39. 39.

    Id., p. 207.

  40. 40.

    Ibid.

  41. 41.

    Id., p. 209.

  42. 42.

    Gaviria (2002).

  43. 43.

    Id., p. 250.

  44. 44.

    Id., p. 252.

  45. 45.

    Id., p. 262.

  46. 46.

    Asiedu and Freeman (2009), p. 212.

  47. 47.

    Id., at 204 and Gaviria (2002), p. 259.

  48. 48.

    Mauro (1995), p. 697 (Table V).

  49. 49.

    Alesina and Perotti (1996), p. 1205.

  50. 50.

    Id., p. 1206.

  51. 51.

    Feng (2001), p. 273.

  52. 52.

    Id., p. 275.

  53. 53.

    Barro (1991), p. 426.

  54. 54.

    Levine and Renelt (1992), p. 946.

  55. 55.

    Mauro (1995), p. 686.

  56. 56.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), p. 523.

  57. 57.

    Aisen and Veiga (2013), p. 153.

  58. 58.

    Feng (2001), p. 278 3.

  59. 59.

    Id., p. 277.

  60. 60.

    Alesina and Perotti (1996), pp. 1207–1208.

  61. 61.

    Intelligence Unit, the Economist (2009). Political Instability Index: Vulnerability to Social and Political Unrest (Methodology). Available at http://viewswire.eiu.com/index.asp?layout=VWArticleVW3&article_id=874361472.

  62. 62.

    Barro (1991), p. 432.

  63. 63.

    Ibid.

  64. 64.

    Levine and Renelt (1992), p. 950.

  65. 65.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), p. 522.

  66. 66.

    Id., pp. 522–523.

  67. 67.

    Aisen and Veiga (2013), p. 162.

  68. 68.

    Ibid.

  69. 69.

    Alesina and Perotti (1996), p. 1217.

  70. 70.

    Id., pp. 1219–1223.

  71. 71.

    Feng (2001), p. 283.

  72. 72.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), p. 529 (n. 15).

  73. 73.

    Alesina and Perotti (1996), p. 1214.

  74. 74.

    Aisen and Veiga (2013), p. 154.

  75. 75.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), p. 525.

  76. 76.

    Ibid.

  77. 77.

    Henisz (2000), pp. 3–4.

  78. 78.

    Id., p. 1.

  79. 79.

    Id., p. 5.

  80. 80.

    Ibid.

  81. 81.

    Ibid.

  82. 82.

    Id., p. 23.

  83. 83.

    15 U.S.C. §§ 12–17, 29 U.S.C §§ 52–53.

  84. 84.

    See, for example, Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 316 (1962).

  85. 85.

    15 U.S.C. §§ 1–7.

  86. 86.

    148 F.2d 416, 428 (1945).

  87. 87.

    21 Cong. Record, 2457.

  88. 88.

    Gerber (1994), p. 73.

  89. 89.

    Streit (1992), p. 689.

  90. 90.

    Carlton and Perloff (2005), p. 3.

  91. 91.

    Id., at 23.

  92. 92.

    Acemoglu et al. (2006).

  93. 93.

    Id., pp. 38–39.

  94. 94.

    Id., p. 39. See also Krusell and Ríos-Rull (1996).

  95. 95.

    Tybout (2000), p. 16.

  96. 96.

    Gauthier and Gersovitz (1997), pp. 416–417.

  97. 97.

    Tybout (2000), pp. 13–14.

  98. 98.

    Id. p. 29.

  99. 99.

    The author, as many other theoretical and empirical works, uses the term lobby instead of interest groups. This can lead to a confusion of concepts, because the model incorporates the variable of political contributions, which may not be, strictly speaking, lobbying efforts. In other works, the term lobbying is distinguished from campaign donations. In this strand of the literature, lobby refers to activities aimed to influence already elected officials on specific policy outcomes. Therefore, in the present research, more general terms such as interest groups are preferred to lobbying organizations, and the term lobbying is used only in its strict meaning.

  100. 100.

    Mitra (1999), p. 1130.

  101. 101.

    Id., p. 1117.

  102. 102.

    Krusell and Ríos-Rull (1996).

  103. 103.

    Id., pp. 302–303.

  104. 104.

    Id., p. 303.

  105. 105.

    Mitra (1999), p. 1122.

  106. 106.

    Id., pp. 1127–1128.

  107. 107.

    Baumgartner et al. (2009).

  108. 108.

    Id., at 23.

  109. 109.

    Mitra (1999), p. 1126.

  110. 110.

    Ibid.

  111. 111.

    Id., p. 1131.

  112. 112.

    Grossman and Helpman (1996), pp. 274–275.

  113. 113.

    Mitra (1999), p. 1121.

  114. 114.

    Grossman and Helpman (1996), p. 268.

  115. 115.

    Bennedsen et al. (2011).

  116. 116.

    Id., p. 18.

  117. 117.

    Id. p. 23.

  118. 118.

    Id., p. 18.

  119. 119.

    Posner (2001), p. 24.

  120. 120.

    Labeling such considerations as noneconomic is a recurrent theme with advocates of the Chicago School of Antitrust. The problem is, however, an economic one and vastly addressed in the political economy literature. To ignore this is to not recognize that the economics profession has certainly broader boundaries than those of price theory and industrial organization.

  121. 121.

    Posner (2001), p. 25.

  122. 122.

    Ibid.

  123. 123.

    Posner (1970), p. 402.

  124. 124.

    Dick (1996), p. 267.

  125. 125.

    Bennedsen et al. (2011), p. 3.

  126. 126.

    Id., p. 18.

  127. 127.

    Id., pp. 19–20.

  128. 128.

    Id., p. 20.

  129. 129.

    Kerr et al. (2014).

  130. 130.

    Id., pp. 6–7.

  131. 131.

    Id., p. 8.

  132. 132.

    Duso and Jung (2012).

  133. 133.

    Id., pp. 181–184.

  134. 134.

    Id., p. 194.

  135. 135.

    Claessens et al. (2008).

  136. 136.

    Id., pp. 558–559. The authors argue that a change in the rate of return of shares means that the market expects the contributing firms to obtain political favors that increase their profits. They justify their access to finance hypothesis on the peculiarities of the Brazilian financial industry where loans at competitive rates can only be obtained from state-controlled banks.

  137. 137.

    Id., p. 559.

  138. 138.

    Id., pp. 559–560.

  139. 139.

    Id., pp. 566, 568–569, and 571–573 (tables 5–10).

  140. 140.

    Bain (1956), p. 55.

  141. 141.

    Id., p. 145.

  142. 142.

    Stigler (1967), p. 292.

  143. 143.

    Carlton and Perloff (2005), p. 80.

  144. 144.

    Areeda et al. (2007), p. 81.

  145. 145.

    Posner (2001), pp. 211–213.

  146. 146.

    Demsetz (1982), p. 50.

  147. 147.

    Levine (2002), pp. 400–401.

  148. 148.

    Id., p. 401.

  149. 149.

    The potential positive and negative effects of banks and stock markets on investment and economic performance is largely drawn from Ndikumana (2001).

  150. 150.

    Love and Zicchino (2006), p. 190.

  151. 151.

    Ndikumana (2001), p. 6.

  152. 152.

    Pagano (1993), p. 615.

  153. 153.

    Ndikumana (2001), p. 10.

  154. 154.

    Id., p. 10.

  155. 155.

    Rajan (1992), p. 1368.

  156. 156.

    Wenger and Kaserer (1998), p. 504.

  157. 157.

    Stiglitz (1985), pp. 145–146.

  158. 158.

    Bhide (1993), p. 50.

  159. 159.

    Lucas (1988), p. 6.

  160. 160.

    Levine and Zervos (1998), p. 540.

  161. 161.

    Ibid. See also Ndikumana (2001), p. 14.

  162. 162.

    Xu (2000), p. 334.

  163. 163.

    See King and Levine (1993).

  164. 164.

    Levine and Zervos (1998), p. 542.

  165. 165.

    Xu (2000), p. 334.

  166. 166.

    Levine and Zervos (1998), pp. 540–541.

  167. 167.

    Id, p. 540.

  168. 168.

    Id., p. 538.

  169. 169.

    Id., p. 546.

  170. 170.

    Id., p. 554.

  171. 171.

    Levine (2002), pp. 414–415; and Ndikumana (2001), pp. 224–226.

  172. 172.

    Thornton (1994).

  173. 173.

    Id., p. 42.

  174. 174.

    Id., p. 46.

  175. 175.

    Xu (2000), p. 337.

  176. 176.

    Id., p. 341.

  177. 177.

    Levine and Zervos (1998), pp. 544–545.

  178. 178.

    Id., p. 546.

  179. 179.

    Love and Zicchino (2006), p. 195; Ndikumana (2001), p. 18; and Becker and Sivadasan (2010), p. 2.

  180. 180.

    Becker and Sivadasan (2010), p. 18; Ndikumana (2001), p. 17; and Levine and Zervos (1998), p. 544.

  181. 181.

    Becker and Sivadasan (2010), p. 1.

  182. 182.

    Ibid.

  183. 183.

    Id., pp. 1–2.

  184. 184.

    Id., p. 22.

  185. 185.

    Id., pp. 20–22.

  186. 186.

    Id., p. 2.

  187. 187.

    Aghion et al. (2007).

  188. 188.

    Id., p. 14.

  189. 189.

    Id., p. 19.

  190. 190.

    Id., pp. 20–21.

  191. 191.

    Id., p. 14.

  192. 192.

    Grossman and Helpman (1996), p. 268.

  193. 193.

    Mankiw et al. (1992).

  194. 194.

    Id., pp. 416–418.

  195. 195.

    Romer (1994), p. 4.

  196. 196.

    Solow (1956).

  197. 197.

    Romer (1994), p. 4.

  198. 198.

    Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), p. 155.

  199. 199.

    See, for example: Lucas (1988); Grossman and Helpman (1991); and Aghion et al. (1998).

  200. 200.

    Romer (1990), p. 79.

  201. 201.

    Grier and Tullock (1989), p. 262.

  202. 202.

    Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), p. 155.

  203. 203.

    Ibid.

  204. 204.

    Ibid.

  205. 205.

    Id., p. 163.

  206. 206.

    Ibid. (citing Lucas (1990)).

  207. 207.

    Mauro (1995), p. 699.

  208. 208.

    Ibid.

  209. 209.

    Wei (2000), pp. 6–7.

  210. 210.

    Id., p. 7.

  211. 211.

    See for example Berger and Fisher (2013), p. 7. The authors find a high correlation between the educational attainment of the workforce and wages across states in the US.

  212. 212.

    Brunetti and Weder (1998), pp. 518–519.

  213. 213.

    Id., p. 518.

  214. 214.

    Henisz (2000), p. 24.

  215. 215.

    Id., p. 20.

  216. 216.

    Id., p. 24.

  217. 217.

    Mankiw et al. (1992), pp. 413–414. The authors use the data in Summers and Heston (1988). They divide it in three sub-samples: the first comprises all countries from these data set excluding oil producers were most of their income is conceived to be produced by extraction of resources and not added value. The second excludes countries whose data are considered unreliable or whose population is lower than one million. The third sample consists of the 22 OECD countries with population greater than one million.

  218. 218.

    Mankiw et al. (1992), pp. 412–413.

  219. 219.

    Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), p. 146.

  220. 220.

    Id., p. 149.

  221. 221.

    Id., pp. 144–145.

  222. 222.

    Id., p. 158.

  223. 223.

    Id., p. 159.

  224. 224.

    Id., p. 161.

  225. 225.

    Id., p. 162.

  226. 226.

    Id., p. 164.

  227. 227.

    Hanushek and Woessmann (2008), p. 629.

  228. 228.

    Id., p. 638.

  229. 229.

    Id., p. 658.

  230. 230.

    Id., p. 639.

  231. 231.

    Hanushek and Kimko (2000), p. 1197.

  232. 232.

    Id., p. 1194.

  233. 233.

    Sala-i-Martin (1996), p. 1020.

  234. 234.

    Id., p. 1025.

  235. 235.

    Abramovitz (1986), p. 386.

  236. 236.

    Sala-i-Martin (1996), p. 1020.

  237. 237.

    Id., pp. 1026–1027.

  238. 238.

    Abramovitz (1986), p. 387.

  239. 239.

    Id., p. 388.

  240. 240.

    Id., p. 387.

  241. 241.

    Krusell and Ríos-Rull (1996).

  242. 242.

    Acemoglu et al. (2006).

  243. 243.

    Abramovitz (1986), p. 394.

  244. 244.

    Ibid.

  245. 245.

    Sala-i-Martin (1996), pp. 1023–1025.

  246. 246.

    Barro (1991), p. 407.

  247. 247.

    Mankiw et al. (1992), p. 422.

  248. 248.

    Id., p. 422.

  249. 249.

    Id., p. 425.

  250. 250.

    Sala-i-Martin (1996), p. 1028.

  251. 251.

    Ibid.

  252. 252.

    See, for example: Henisz (2000), p. 24; Sala-i-Martin et al. (2004), p. 827; Mauro (1995), pp. 699–702; and Levine and Renelt (1992), pp. 946–950.

  253. 253.

    Mankiw et al. (1992), p. 423.

  254. 254.

    Id., p. 428.

  255. 255.

    Abramovitz (1986), p. 395.

  256. 256.

    Levine and Renelt (1992), p. 959.

  257. 257.

    Id., p. 945.

References

  • Abramovitz M (1986) Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. J Econ Hist 46(2):385–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Zilibotti F (2006) Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. J Eur Econ Assoc 4(1):37–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P, Brant-Collett M, García-Peñalosa C (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Fally T, Scarpetta S (2007) Credit constraints as a barrier to the entry and post-entry growth of firms. Econ Policy 22(52):732–779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aisen A, Veiga F (2013) How does political instability affect economic growth? Eur J Polit Econ 29:151–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Perotti R (1996) Income distribution, political instability, and investment. Eur Econ Rev 40(6):1203–1228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Areeda P, Solow J, Hovenkamp H (2007) Antitrust law–an analysis of antitrust principles and their application. Aspen Publishers, United States of America

    Google Scholar 

  • Asiedu E, Freeman J (2009) The effect of corruption on investment growth: evidence from firms in Latin America, Sub-Saharan Africa, and transition countries. Rev Dev Econ 13(2):200–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain J (1956) Barriers to new competition, their character and consequences in manufacturing industries. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1991) Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q J Econ 106(2):407–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner F, Berry J, Hojnacki M, Kimball D, Leech B (2009) Lobbying and policy change: who wins, who loses, and why. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker B, Sivadasan J (2010) The effect of financial development on the investment-cash flow relationship: cross-country evidence from Europe. BE J Econ Anal Policy 10(1):1–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger N, Fisher P (2013) A well-educated workforce is key to state prosperity. Econ Policy Inst 22(1):1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Spiegel M (1994) The role of human capital in economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J Monet Econ 34(2):143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen M, Feldmann S, Lassen D (2011) Lobbying and bribes–a survey-based analysis of the demand for influence and corruption. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 3496. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1873891

  • Bhide A (1993) The hidden costs of stock market liquidity. J Financ Econ 34(1):31–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti A, Weder B (1998) Investment and institutional uncertainty: a comparative study of different uncertainty measures. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 134(4):513–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno R, Bytchkova M, Estrin S (2011) Institutions and entry: a cross-regional analysis in Russia. IZA Discussion Papers 5504, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). http://ftp.iza.org/dp5504.pdf

  • Carlton D, Perloff J (2005) Modern industrial organization. Pearson/Addison-Wesley, United States of America

    Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Feijen E, Laeven L (2008) Political connections and preferential access to finance: the role of campaign contributions. J Financ Econ 88(3):554–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase R (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Leon I (2009) An institutional assessment of antitrust policy: the Latin American experience. Kluwer, The Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz H (1982) Barriers to entry. Am Econ Rev 72(1):47–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Dick A (1996) When are cartels stable contracts? J Law Econ 39(1):241–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Pindyck R (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duso T, Jung A (2012) Product market competition and lobbying coordination in the US mobile telecommunications industry. J Ind Compet Trade 12(2):177–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng Y (2001) Political freedom, political instability, and policy uncertainty: a study of political institutions and private investment in developing countries. Int Stud Q 45(2):271–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fox E, Bakhoum M (2019) Making markets work for Africa: markets, development, and competition law in Sub-Saharan Africa. OUP, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gauthier B, Gersovitz M (1997) Revenue erosion through exemption and evasion in Cameroon, 1993. J Public Econ 64(3):407–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaviria A (2002) Assessing the effects of corruption and crime on firm performance: evidence from Latin America. Emerg Mark Rev 3(3):245–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber D (1994) Constitutionalizing the economy: German neoliberalism, competition law and the “new” Europe. Am J Comp Law 42(1):25–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber D (2010) Global competition: law, markets, and globalization. OUP, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grier K, Tullock G (1989) An empirical analysis of cross-national economic growth, 1951–1980. J Monet Econ 24(2):259–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Rev Econ Stud 58(1):43–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1996) Electoral competition and special interest politics. Rev Econ Stud 63(2):265–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek E, Kimko D (2000) Schooling, labor-force quality, and the growth of nations. Am Econ Rev 90(5):1184–1208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek E, Woessmann L (2008) The role of cognitive skills in economic development. J Econ Lit 46(3):607–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz W (2000) The institutional environment for economic growth. Econ Polit 12(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr W, Lincoln W, Mishra P (2014) The dynamics of firm lobbying. Am Econ J: Econ Policy 6(4):343–379

    Google Scholar 

  • King R, Levine R (1993) Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Q J Econ 108(3):717–737

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack S, Keefer P (1995) Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Econ Polit 7(3):207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krusell P, Ríos-Rull J (1996) Vested interests in a positive theory of stagnation and growth. Rev Econ Stud 63(2):301–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leff N (1964) Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. Am Behav Sci 8(3):8–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2002) Bank-based or market-based financial systems: which is better? J Financ Intermed 11(4):398–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R, Renelt D (1992) A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. Am Econ Rev 82(4):942–963

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R, Zervos S (1998) Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 88(3):537–558

    Google Scholar 

  • Love I, Zicchino L (2006) Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: evidence from panel VAR. Q Rev Econ Finance 46(2):190–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1990) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am Econ Rev 80(2):92–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw N, Romer D, Weil D (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107(2):407–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110(3):681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra D (1999) Endogenous lobby formation and endogenous protection: a long-run model of trade policy determination. Am Econ Rev 89(5):1116–1134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ndikumana L (2001) Financial markets and economic development in Africa. PERI Working Paper No. 17. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.333321

  • North D (1989) Institutions and economic growth: an historical introduction. World Dev 17(9):1319–1332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagano M (1993) Financial markets and growth: an overview. Eur Econ Rev 37(2–3):613–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pamukçu T, Sekkat K, Taymaz E (2009) Entry, exit and productivity in Turkish manufacturing industries. In: Sekkat K (ed) Market dynamics and productivity in developing countries. Springer, New York, pp 109–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Pande R, Udry C (2005) Institutions and development: a view from below. Yale University Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 928. https://ssrn.com/abstract=864044m

  • Posner R (1970) A statistical study of antitrust enforcement. J Law Econ 13(2):365–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner R (2001) Antitrust law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan R (1992) Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and arm’s-length debt. J Finance 47(4):1367–1400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(5):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1994) The origins of endogenous growth. J Econ Perspect 8(1):3–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin X (1996) The classical approach to convergence analysis. Econ J 106(437):1019–1036

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin X, Doppelhofer G, Miller R (2004) Determinants of long-term growth: a bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. Am Econ Rev 94(4):813–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70(1):65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler G (1967) Imperfections in the capital market. J Polit Econ 75(3):287–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J (1985) Credit markets and the control of capital. J Money Credit Bank 17(2):133–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streit M (1992) Economic order, private law and public policy The Freiburg school of law and economics in perspective. J Inst Theor Econ (JITE)/Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft 148(4):675–704

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers R, Heston A (1988) A new set of international comparisons of real product and price levels estimates for 130 countries, 1950–1985. Rev Income Wealth 34(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thornton J (1994) Financial deepening and economic growth: evidence from Asian economies. Sav Dev 18(1):41–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Tybout J (2000) Manufacturing firms in developing countries: how well do they do, and why? J Econ Lit 38(1):11–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei S (2000) How taxing is corruption on international investors? Rev Econ Stat 82(1):1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wenger E, Kaserer C (1998) German banks and corporate governance: a critical view. In: Hopt et al (eds) Comparative corporate governance-the state of the art and emerging research. Oxford University Press, Great Britain, pp 499–536

    Google Scholar 

  • Xu Z (2000) Financial development, investment, and economic growth. Econ Inq 38(2):331–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer-Verlag GmbH, DE , part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Beneke Avila, F.E. (2021). Determinants of the Investment Rate in the Economy and Their Relevance in Entry Analysis. In: Market Entry and Competition Law in Latin America. Munich Studies on Innovation and Competition, vol 14. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-62347-3_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-62347-3_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-662-62346-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-62347-3

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics