Skip to main content

2015 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

17. A Simulation Model for Understanding the Consequences of Alternative Water and Wastewater Tariff Structures: A Case Study of Fayoum, Egypt

verfasst von : Céline Nauges, Dale Whittington, Mohamed El-Alfy

Erschienen in: Understanding and Managing Urban Water in Transition

Verlag: Springer Netherlands

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Egypt has successfully made the transition to high quality piped water services. Currently 98 % of urban households and 96 % of rural households have access to piped water services, primarily through private connections for the exclusive use of household members. Now that water supply coverage with piped networks has been largely accomplished, the water and wastewater utility companies in Egypt face new challenges. One of the most pressing is the need to generate revenues that are sufficient for a financially sustainable future. Today most of the financial resources needed by the water supply sector come from government development grants which finance capital expenditures and some subsidies to cover operation and maintenance costs. The Egyptian government wants to reduce this financial support and encourage the water and wastewater sector to gradually become financially self-sufficient. In this chapter we present a simulation model that was designed to assist the Egyptian Water Regulatory Agency to better navigate the tariff reform process. We simulate the effects of alternative tariff structures on customer water use, which in turn affects utility revenues and costs. The different tariff structures are compared in terms of their achieving the following four objectives: (1) financial cost recovery, (2) economic efficiency, (3) fairness and equity, including affordability, and (4) tariff simplicity.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
The entire survey by Global Water International is available at http://​www.​globalwaterintel​.​com/​tariff-survey-2009/​
 
2
The approximate exchange rate was LE 5.4 = USD 1.0 in mid-2010.
 
3
In an unpublished report to the Egyptian Water Regulatory Agency we estimated a stochastic cost frontier using cost data from 19 Egyptian utilities. We considered separate cost functions for water and wastewater and included as inputs the price of labour and the price of electricity. We estimated the economy-of-scale factor to be 0.68 (95 % confidence interval 0.52–0.84) for water services and 0.60 (95 % C.I. of 0.52–0.68) for wastewater services.
 
4
The general cost function is O&M Costs = K × [water sales]γ where γ = economy-of-scale factor. The cost is 83 (from column a in Table 17.1) and sales are 95 (from column c). Inserting these values into Eq. 17.1 and solving yields K = 5.4.
 
5
The amount of wastewater is approximated by the amount of water sold to customers with wastewater services.
 
6
This fact – that an increasing block tariff does not actually help poorer households – has been noted in other studies. See, for example, Komives et al. (2005), Boland and Whittington (2000), and Whittington (1992).
 
7
The economy-of-scale factor in Eqs. 17.1 and 17.2 is the ratio of marginal to average cost. The average cost of water service can be estimated from Eq. 17.1 using an exponent of –0.4 instead of 0.6 (i.e. by dividing Eq. 17.1 by sales).
 
8
The estimation of the stochastic cost frontier on data from Egyptian utilities (see note 3 above) confirms that, for most utilities, the marginal cost of providing wastewater services is higher than the marginal cost of supplying water, so the wastewater surcharge should be at least 100 %. However, when working on tariff design with the Egyptian Water Regulatory Agency, we were asked to consider a maximum of 100 % for the wastewater surcharge.
 
9
Affordability assessment to support the development of a financing strategy for the water supply and sanitation sector in Egypt. Final report, 161 pp.
 
10
Customers are in fact billed monthly. However, the distribution of monthly records does not show any significant seasonal pattern (e.g. there is no significant increase in water use in the summer). For this reason, it is reasonable to use as a benchmark the average monthly water use for the entire fiscal year.
 
12
This is unrealistic because in some cases there is no sewer line in a specific area. When one is installed, many households there may choose to connect. However, this assumption will not have much effect on our simulation results.
 
13
The volumetric price in block 2 is chosen such that it is equal to the marginal cost, itself being a function of total water sales.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Arbués, F., Garcia-Valiñas, M., & Martinez-Espiñeira, R. (2003). Estimation of residential water demand: A state-of-the-art review. Journal of Socio-Economics, 32, 81–102.CrossRef Arbués, F., Garcia-Valiñas, M., & Martinez-Espiñeira, R. (2003). Estimation of residential water demand: A state-of-the-art review. Journal of Socio-Economics, 32, 81–102.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boland, J., & Whittington, D. (2000). The political economy of increasing block water tariffs in developing countries. In A. Dinar (Ed.), The political economy of water pricing reforms (pp. 215–236). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Boland, J., & Whittington, D. (2000). The political economy of increasing block water tariffs in developing countries. In A. Dinar (Ed.), The political economy of water pricing reforms (pp. 215–236). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Chemonics Egypt. (2009). Affordability assessment to support the development of a financing strategy for the water supply and sanitation sector in Egypt. Final report prepared within the framework of the Mediterranean Component of the EU Water Initiative (MED EUWI) Egypt Country Dialogue on Water, February 2009, pp. 161. Chemonics Egypt. (2009). Affordability assessment to support the development of a financing strategy for the water supply and sanitation sector in Egypt. Final report prepared within the framework of the Mediterranean Component of the EU Water Initiative (MED EUWI) Egypt Country Dialogue on Water, February 2009, pp. 161.
Zurück zum Zitat Griffin, R. C., & Mjele, J. W. (2011). Distributing nature’s bounty. Ecological Economics, 72, 116–128.CrossRef Griffin, R. C., & Mjele, J. W. (2011). Distributing nature’s bounty. Ecological Economics, 72, 116–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahnemann, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.CrossRef Kahnemann, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knetsch, J. (2010). Values of gains and losses: Reference states and choice of measure. Environmental and Resource Economics, 46, 179–188.CrossRef Knetsch, J. (2010). Values of gains and losses: Reference states and choice of measure. Environmental and Resource Economics, 46, 179–188.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Komives, K., Foster, V., Halpern, J., & Wodon, Q. (2005). Water, electricity, and the poor: Who benefits from utility subsidies? Directions in development. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef Komives, K., Foster, V., Halpern, J., & Wodon, Q. (2005). Water, electricity, and the poor: Who benefits from utility subsidies? Directions in development. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Water Resources and Irrigation. (2005). Water for the future. National water resources plan 2017. Cairo: MWRI. Ministry of Water Resources and Irrigation. (2005). Water for the future. National water resources plan 2017. Cairo: MWRI.
Zurück zum Zitat Nauges, C., & Whittington, D. (2010). Estimation of water demand in developing countries: An overview. World Bank Research Observer, 25(2), 263–294.CrossRef Nauges, C., & Whittington, D. (2010). Estimation of water demand in developing countries: An overview. World Bank Research Observer, 25(2), 263–294.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Whittington, D. (1992). Possible adverse effects of increasing block water tariff in developing countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 41(1), 75–87.CrossRef Whittington, D. (1992). Possible adverse effects of increasing block water tariff in developing countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 41(1), 75–87.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
A Simulation Model for Understanding the Consequences of Alternative Water and Wastewater Tariff Structures: A Case Study of Fayoum, Egypt
verfasst von
Céline Nauges
Dale Whittington
Mohamed El-Alfy
Copyright-Jahr
2015
Verlag
Springer Netherlands
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9801-3_17