Skip to main content
Log in

The logic of public policy design: Linking policy actors and plausible instruments

  • Feature Articles
  • Published:
Knowledge and Policy

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

References

  • Adler, R., & Pittle, D. (1984). Cajolery or command?Yale Journal on Regulations, 1, 159–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander, E. (1986).Approaches to planning. New York: Gordon & Breach.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alterman, R., & MacRae, D. Jr. (1983). Planning and policy analysis: Converging or diverging trends?Journal of the American Planning Association, 49, 200–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur D. Little, Inc. (1981). Auditing.Public Policy Notes, 2, 1–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardach, E., & Kagan, R.A. (1982).Going by the book: The problem of regulatory unreasonableness. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, G. (1973).Politicians, bureaucrats, and consultants. New York: Basic books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. G. (1982).Regulation and its reform. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. (1969). Reforms as experiments.American Psychologist, 24, 409–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dryzek, J. (1983). Don’t toss coins into garbage cans.Journal of Public Policy, 3, 345–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunn, W. (1981).Public policy analysis: An introduction. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elmore, R. (1985). Forward and backward mapping: Reversible logic in the analysis of public policy. In K. Hauf & T. Toonen (Eds.).Policy implementation in federal and unitary systems. Dodrecht, The Netherlands: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J. (1987).Planning in the public domain. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn, E., & Pejovich, S. (1972). Property rights and economic theory.Journal of Economic Literature, 10, 1137–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, V. (1976). Regulation and administered contracts.Bell Journal of Economics and Management, 7, 426–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gormley, W. (1987). Institutional policy analysis: A critical review.Journal of Policy Analysis and management, 6, 153–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C. (1984).The tools of government. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogwood, B., & Peters, B.G. (1985).Policy dynamics. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, R., van de Graaf, H., & Van Dijk, A (1987). Implementation research and policy design: Problem tractibility, policy theory, and feasibility testing.International Review of Administrative Sciences, 53, 581–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • House, P. (1982).The art of public policy analysis. Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingram, H., & Schneider, A. (1988). Improving implementation through policy design: Framing smarter statutes. Unpublished paper delivered at the American Political Science Association Meeting, Washington, DC.

  • Kaufmann, F., Majone, G., & Ostrom, C. (1986).Guidance, performance and evaluation in the public sector. New York: Walter deGruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelman, S. (1981).Regulating America, regulating Sweden: A comparative study of occupational and health policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kingdon, J. (1984).Agendas, alternatives, and public policy. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kneese, A., & Schultze, C. (1975).Pollution, and public policy. Washington, DC: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer, E. (1980).Specification searches. New York: John Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, C. (1985). Where policy comes from: Ideas innovations and agenda choices.Public Administration Review, 45, 255–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, A., & Shakun, M. (1976). Situational normativism.Policy Sciences, 7, 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichfield, N., Kettle, P., Whitebread, M. (1975).Evaluation in the planning process. New York: Pergamon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linder, S., Peters, B.G. (1989). Instrument of government: Perceptions and contexts.Journal of Public Policy, 9, 35–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linder, S., & Peters, B.G. (1984). From social theory to policy design.Journal of Public Policy, 4, 237–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J., & Roberts, R. (1989). Why comply: One-sided enforcement of price controls and victimless crime laws.Journal of Legal Studies, 18, 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majone, G. (1989).Evidence, argument and persuasion in the policy process. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • May, P. (1981). Hints for crafting alternative policies.Policy Analysis, 7, 227–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikesell, J. L. (1986). Amnesties for state tax evaders: The nature of and response to recent programs.National Tax Journal, 39, 507–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, T. (1984). Conclusion: A design science perspective. In T. Miller (Ed.),Public sector performance. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishan, E. (1981).Introduction to normative economics. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitroff, I., Mason, R., & Barabba, V. (1982). Policy as argument: A ligic for ill-structured decision problems.Management Science, 28, 1391–1404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perritt, H. (1986). Negotiated rulemaking in practice.Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 5, 482–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polisky, A. (1979). Private versus public enforcement of fines.Journa, of Legal Studies, 8, 105–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quade, E. (1982).Analysis for public decisions (2nd ed.). New York: Elsvier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1987). On how to decide what to do.Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 494–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vining, A., & Weimer, D. (1989). Information asymmetry favoring sellers: A policy framework.Policy Sciences, 21, 281–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, L. (1981).Reforming regulations. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolf, C. (1979). A theory of non-marker failure.Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 119–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolf, C. (1988).Markers or governments: Choosing between imperfect alternatives. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

His principal interest lies in policy analysis, currently focusing on policy design and implementation issues. His most recent work has appeared inPolicy Studies Review, Milbank Quarterly, andJournal of Policy Analysis and Management.

He currently is working on several research interests in comparative public administration and policy design.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Linder, S., Peters, B.G. The logic of public policy design: Linking policy actors and plausible instruments. Knowledge and Policy 4, 125–151 (1991). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02692751

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02692751

Keywords

Navigation