Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Competition, R&D and innovation: testing the inverted-U in a simultaneous system

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To address the relationship between innovation and competition we jointly estimate the opportunity, production, and impact functions of innovation in a simultaneous system. Based on Swiss micro-data, we apply a 3-SLS system estimation. The findings confirm a robust inverted-U relationship, in which a rise in the number of competitors at low levels of initial competition increases the firm’s research effort, but at a diminishing rate, and the research effort ultimately decreases at high levels of competition. When we split the sample by firm types, the inverted-U shape is steeper for creative firms than for adaptive ones. The numerical solution indicates three particular configurations of interest: (i) an uncontested monopoly with low innovation; (ii) low competition with high innovation; and (iii) a ‘no innovation trap’ at very high levels of competition. The distinction between solution (i) and (ii) corresponds to Arrow’s positive effect of competition on innovation, whereas the difference between outcomes (ii) and (iii) captures Schumpeter’s positive effect of market power on innovation. Simulating changes of the exogenous variables, technology potential, demand growth, firm size and exports have a positive impact on innovation, while foreign ownership has a negative effect, and higher appropriability has a positive impact on the number of competitors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One should not conflate this with his hypothesis of a positive impact of firm size on innovation Schumpeter (1942).

  2. See, e.g. Geroski (2003) and the model of Grossman and Shapiro (1987).

  3. See, e.g., Loury (1979) or Cellini and Lambertini (2005, 2011).

  4. See, e.g. Sutton (1991, 1998).

  5. Similarly, we assume that the influence of increasing returns in knowledge creation on the R&D incentives of Eq. 1 is only indirect and depends on their impact on the probability of innovation success.

  6. The questionnaires are available in German, Italian, and French.

  7. Even though the circular causation invokes a certain time pattern and the data are available in a panel format, we do not apply lagged variables for two reasons. First and foremost, we have no information on the accurate time period required for R&D inputs in 1 year to yield successful innovations in a later year. Second, the type of firm activities shows relatively little variation over time. Third, the panel is highly imbalanced and consequently too many observations would be lost if we only operated with those firms reporting in every period.

  8. Hence, we could also use R&D expenditures as a continuous variable instead of firm types. However, we chose the ordinal classification, mainly because it is more robust to data noise and because it better fits the ordinal structure of the two other endogenous variables. When we tested whether the system was also robust to the use of R&D expenditures as a continuous variable, the functional forms were confirmed and significant for each equation.

  9. All mentioned categories are exclusive, i.e. each firm has only one value. The identification rules are hierarchical. For example, firms carrying out own innovations in addition to adopting new technology are classified in the higher rank ‘4’. Overall, the firm types aim to combine various qualitative dimensions from the innovation survey (e.g., innovation vs. no innovation; innovations new to the firm vs. those new to the market; or process vs. product innovations) within a new and single variable of genuine meaning (e.g., that of ‘adaptive’ vs. ‘creative entrepreneurship’). For a detailed explanation see Peneder (2010).

  10. For lively debates on the use of instrumental variables with respect to causal inference, theoretical priors and randomized controlled experiments, see Pearl (2009), Angrist and Pischke (2010), Leamer (2010) or Deaton (2010).

  11. Of related interest, see e.g. Bloch et al. (2012) presenting a dynamic game of position strategies determining the equilibrium number of active firms.

  12. Please note that this argument does not imply that increasing innovation is always the best strategy for a firm, since the argument does not include the cost of increased market power. To understand the innovation incentives for a firm, one must again turn to the opportunity function.

  13. However, see also the more detailed case-based discussions on antitrust in innovative industries, e.g. by Crandall and Jackson (2011), Owen (2011) or Wright (2011).

References

  • Aghion P, Griffith R (2005) Competition and growth. Reconciling theory and evidence. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (2009) The economics of growth. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P (2005) Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Q J Econ 120:701–728

    Google Scholar 

  • Alder S (2010) Competition and innovation: does the distance to the technology frontier matter? University of Zürich, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics. Working Paper No. 493

  • Angrist JD, Pischke JS (2010) The credibility revolution in empirical economics: how better research design is taking the con out of econometrics. J Econ Perspect 24(2):3–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson R (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 609–626

    Google Scholar 

  • Artes J (2009) Long-run versus short-run decisions: R&D and market structure in Spanish firms. Res Policy 38:120–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch H, Eaton BC, Rothschild R (2012) Does market size matter? A dynamic model of oligopolistic market structure, featuring costs of creating and maintaining a market position, mimeo

  • Blundell R, Griffith R, van Reenen J (1999) Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Rev Econ Stud 66:529–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone J (2008a) Competition: theoretical paramaterizations and empirical measures. J Inst Theor Econ 164(4):587–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone J (2008b) A new way to measure competition. Econ J 118(531):1245–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2000) Technological regimes and Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Econ J 110:388–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castellacci F (2010) How does competition affect the relationship between innovation and productivity? Estimation of a CDM model for Norway. Econ Innov New Technol 19:1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castellacci F, Zheng J (2010) Technological regimes, Schumpeterian patterns of innovation and firm-level productivity growth. Ind Corp Chang 19(6):1829–1865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R, Lambertini L (2005) R&D incentives and market structure: dynamic analysis. J Optim Theory Appl 126:85–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R, Lambertini L (2011) R&D incentives under Bertrand competition: a differential game. Japan Econ Rev 62(3):387–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM (1995) Empirical studies of innovative activity. In: Stoneman P (ed) Handbook of the economics of innovation and technological change. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM (2010) Fifty years of empirical studies of innovative activity and performance. In: Hall BW, Rosenberg N (eds) Handbook of the economics of innovation. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 129–213

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levin R (1989) Empirical studies of R&D and market structure. In: Schmalensee R, Willig R (eds) Handbook of industrial organization. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1059–1107

    Google Scholar 

  • Correa JA (2012) Innovation and competition: an unstable relationship. J Appl Econ 27:160–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crandall RW, Jackson CL (2011) Antitrust in high-tech industries. Rev Ind Organ 38(4):319–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crépon B, Duguet E, Mairesse J (1998) Research and development, innovation and productivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Econ Innov New Technol 7(2):115–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Czarnitzki D, Etro F, Kraft C (2011) Endogenous market structures and innovation by leaders: an empirical test. Working Paper No. 04/WP/2011, University of Venice (Department of Economics)

  • Darai D, Sacco D, Schmutzler A (2010) Competition and innovation: an experimental investigation. Exp Econ 13:439–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Stiglitz J (1980) Industrial structure and the nature of innovative activity. Econ J 90(358):266–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (2010) Instruments, randomization, and learning about development. J Econ Lit 48:424–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt R (1977) Innovative activities and barriers to entry. Eur Econ Rev 10:95–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt R, Vandekerckhove J (2012) Reflections on the relation between competition and innovation. J Ind Compet Trade 12(1):7–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delbono F, Denicolo V (1991) Incentives to innovate in a cournot oligopoly. Q J Econ 106:951–961

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski PA (1995) Market structure, corporate performance and innovative activity. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski PA (2003) Competition in markets and competition for markets. J Ind Compet Trade 3(3):151–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert R (2006) Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: where are we in the competition-innovation debate? In: Jaffe AB, Lerner J, Stern S (eds) Innovation policy and the economy, vol 6, pp 159–215

  • Gilbert RJ, Newberry DMG (1982) Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. Am Econ Rev 72(3):514–526

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert RJ, Newberry DMG (1984) Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly: reply. Am Econ Rev 74(1):251–253

    Google Scholar 

  • Gottschalk S, Janz N (2001) Innovation dynamics and endogenous market structure. Econometric results from aggregated survey data. ZEW Discussion Paper 01–39, Mannheim

  • Grossman GM, Shapiro C (1987) Dynamic R&D competition. Econ J 97(386):372–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashmi AR, Van Biesebroeck J (2010) Market structure and innovation: a dynamic analysis of the global automobile industry. NBER Working Paper 15959. http://www.nber.org/papers/w15959

  • Kamien MI, Schwartz NL (1972) Timing of innovations under rivalry. Econometrica 40:43–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Schwartz NL (1974) Patent life and R&D rivalry. Am Econ Rev 64(1):183–187

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Schwartz NL (1976) On the degree of rivalry for maximum innovative activity. Q J Econ 90:245–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kraft K (1989) Market structure, firm characteristics and innovative activity. J Ind Econ 37:329–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (2010) Tantalus on the road to asymptopia. J Econ Perspect 24(2):31–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee T, Wilde L (1980) Market structure and innovation: a reformulation. Q J Econ 94:395–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin RC, Cohen WM, Mowery DC (1985) R&D appropriability, opportunity and market structure: new evidence on some Schumpeterian hypotheses. Am Econ Rev Proc 75:20–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Loury GC (1979) Market structure and innovation. Q J Econ 93(3):395–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madansky A (1964) On the efficiency of three-stage least squares estimation. Econometrica 32:55

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2007) Innovation and the dynamics and evolution of industries: progress and challenges. Int J Ind Organ 25:675–699

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1993) Technological regimes and firm behaviour. Ind Corp Chang 2(1):45–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (1997) Technological regimes and sectoral patterns of innovative activities. Ind Corp Chang 6:83–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E (1963) Size of firm, market structure, and innovation. J Polit Econ 76(6):556–576

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickel S (1996) Competition and corporate performance. J Polit Econ 104:724–746

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen BM (2011) Antitrust and vertical integration in “new economy” industries with application to broadband access. Rev Ind Organ 38(4):363–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearl J (2009) Causality, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Peneder M (2009) The meaning of entrepreneurship: a modular concept. J Ind Compet Trade 9(2):77–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peneder M (2010) Technological regimes and the variety of innovation behavior: creating integrated taxonomies of firms and sectors. Res Policy 39:323–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polder M, Veldhuizen E (2012) Innovation and competition in the Netherlands: testing the inverted U for industries and firms. J Ind Compet Trade 12(1–2):67–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum JF (1985) A two-stage model of research and development with endogenous second mover advantages. Int J Ind Org 3:61–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum JF (1989) The timing of innovation: research, development and diffusion. In: Schmalensee R, Willig R (eds) Handbook of industrial organization. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacco D, Schmutzler A (2011) Is there a U-shaped relation between competition and investment? Int J Ind Organ 29(1):65–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos CD (2010) Competition, product and process innovation: an empirical analysis. IVIE Working Paper WP-AD 2010-26

  • Scherer FM (1967a) Market structure and the employment of scientists and engineers. Am Econ Rev 57:524–531

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM (1967b) Research and development resource allocation under rivalry. Q J Econ 81:359–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmutzler A (2010) The relation between competition and innovation—why is it such a mess? University of Zurich. Discussion Paper No. 0716

  • Schumpeter JA (1911) Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, 4th edn. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7(2):149–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott JT (2009) Competition in research and development: a theory for contradictory predictions. Rev Ind Organ 34:153–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C, Lerner J (2011) Competition and innovation: did arrow hit the bull’s eye? In: Stern S (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity revisited. NBER, Cambridge. (Quote from draft)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton J (1991) Sunk costs and market structure. Price competition, advertising and the evolution of concentration. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutton J (1998) Technology and market structure. Theory and history. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Tang J (2006) Competition and innovation behavior. Res Policy 35:68–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tingvall PG, Poldahl A (2006) Is there really an inverted U-shaped relation between competition an R&D. Econ Innov New Technol 15(2):101–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tishler A, Milstein I (2009) R&D wars and the effects of innovation on the success and survivability of firms in oligopoly markets. Int J Ind Organ 27:519–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Wiel H (2010) Competition and innovation: together a tricky rollercoaster for productivity. Tilburg University, Tilburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Vives X (2008) Innovation and competitive pressure. J Ind Econ 56:419–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright JD (2011) Does antitrust enforcement in high tech markets benefit consumers? Stock price evidence from FTC v. Intel. Rev Ind Organ 38(4):387–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper has benefitted from critical comments and thoughtful considerations provided at numerous discussions and presentations at conferences or seminars, e.g. at KOF-ETH, WIFO, SPRU, IPTS, IIOC, or ISS. Among these, we are most indebted to Michael Pfaffermayr and Serguei Kaniovski as well as Esben Sloth Andersen, Spyros Arvanitis, Harald Badinger, Harry Bloch, Herbert Dawid, Erik Dietzenbacher, Kurt Dopfer, Giovanni Dosi, Peter Egger, Peter Fleissner, Klaus Gugler, Heinz Hollenstein, Werner Hölzl, Andreas Reinstaller, Manuel Wäckerle, Carl-Christian von Weizsäcker, Ulrich Witt, Christine Zulehner and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful to Eva Sokoll and Astrid Nolte for their invaluable technical assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Peneder.

Appendices

Annex 1: Reduced form solution

We can also solve the system of Eqs. 1 to 3 in reduced form. For the sake of simplicity, we omit the subscripts for firms i when substituting Eq. 1 in Eq. 2:

$$I=\alpha_2 +\beta_2 \left( {\alpha_1 +\beta_1 C+\theta C^2+\gamma_1 X+\delta_1 O_j} \right)+\gamma_2 X+\delta_2 M_j $$

By substitution in Eq. 3, we get the following reduced form for the number of competitors:

$$\begin{array}{rll} C&=&\alpha_3 +\beta_3 \left[ {\alpha_2 +\beta_2 \left( {\alpha_1 +\beta _1 C+\theta C^2+\gamma_1 X+\delta_1 O_j} \right)+\gamma_2 X+\delta_2 M_j} \right]\\ &&+\gamma_3 X+\delta_3 A_j \end{array} $$

Multiplication of terms yields:

$$\begin{array}{rll} C&=&\alpha_3 +\alpha_2 \beta_3 +\alpha_1 \beta_2 \beta_3 +\beta_1\beta_2 \beta_3 C+\beta_2 \beta_3 \theta C^2+\beta_2 \beta_3 \gamma_1 X \\ &&+\beta_2 \beta_3 \delta_1 O_j +\beta_3 \gamma_2 X+\beta_3 \delta_2 M_j +\gamma_3 X+\delta_3 A_j \end{array} $$

Some rearrangement leads to the following expression of a quadratic function:

$$\begin{array}{l} \beta_2 \beta_3 \theta C^2+\left( {\beta_1 \beta_2 \beta_3 -1} \right)C+\beta_2 \beta_3 \gamma_1 X+\beta_3 \gamma_2 X+\gamma_3 X+\beta_2 \beta_3 \delta_1 O_j \\ \quad +\beta_3 \delta_2 M_j +\delta_3 A_j+\alpha_1 \beta_2 \beta_3 +\alpha _2 \beta_3 +\alpha_3 =0 \end{array} $$

We thus have a quadratic system \(\alpha C^{2} + bC + c = 0\), which can be solved by

$$C_{1,2} =\frac{-b\pm \sqrt {b^2-4\alpha c}} {2\alpha} $$

for \(a =\beta _{2}\beta _{3}\theta , b = (\beta _{1}\beta _{2}\beta _{3}-1)\), and \(c=\alpha _1 \beta _2 \beta _3 +\alpha _2 \beta _3 +\alpha _3 +\beta _2 \beta _3 \gamma _1 X+\beta _3 \gamma _2 X+\gamma _3 X+\beta _2 \beta _3 \delta _1 O_j +\beta _3 \delta _2 M_j +\delta _3 A_j \), and provided \(b^{2}-4\alpha c\ge 0\).

Substituting Eq. 2 directly into Eq. 3, we get the following expression relating research effort E to the number of competitors C:

$$\begin{array}{rll} C&=&\alpha_3 +\beta_3 \left( {\alpha_2 +\beta_2 E+\gamma_2 X+\delta_2 M_j} \right)+\gamma_3 X+\delta_3 A_j \\ C&=&\beta_2 \beta_3 E+\alpha_3 +\alpha_2 \beta_3 +\beta_3 \gamma_2 X+\gamma_3 X+\beta_3 \delta_2 M_j +\delta_3 A_j \\ \beta_2 \beta_3 E&=&C-\left( {\alpha_3 +\alpha_2 \beta_3 +\beta _3 \gamma_2 X+\gamma_3 X+\beta_3 \delta_2 M_j +\delta_3 A_j}\right)=C-Intercept\\ E&=&\frac{C-Intercept}{\beta_2 \beta_3} \end{array} $$

Annex 2: Supplementary tables

Tables 8, 9, 10 and 11

Table 8 Number of firms by industry and year
Table 9 3 SLS estimations with time-varying instruments (standard errors in brackets)
Table 10 3 SLS estimations with \(\mathbf {C_i^{squared}}\) also instrumented (standard errors in brackets)
Table 11 Reduced form \(\mathbf {C_i^{squared}}\) (standard errors in brackets)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Peneder, M., Woerter, M. Competition, R&D and innovation: testing the inverted-U in a simultaneous system. J Evol Econ 24, 653–687 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0310-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0310-z

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation