Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Energy, knowledge and economic growth

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is argued that the explosive growth experienced in much of the World since the middle of the 19th Century is due to the exploitation and use of fossil fuels which, in turn, was made possible by capital good innovations that enabled this source of energy to be used effectively. Economic growth is viewed as the outcome autocatalytic co-evolution of energy use and the application of new knowledge associated with energy use. It is argued that models of economic growth should be built from innovation diffusion processes, unfolding in history, rather than from a timeless aggregate production function. A simple ‘evolutionary macroeconomic’ model of economic growth is developed and tested using almost two centuries of British data. The empirical findings strongly support the hypothesis that growth has been due to the presence of a ‘super-radical innovation diffusion process’ following the industrial deployment of fossil fuels on a large scale in the 19th Century. Also, the evidence suggests that large and sustained movements in energy prices have had a very significant long term role to play.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Galor and Michalopoulos (2012) claimed that it is possible to capture entrepreneurship in a neoclassical model. Typically, their highly mathematical model contains many very abstract assumptions that invalidate its relevance to the history that they discuss.

  2. It is instructive that Aghion and Howitt (1998), who hijacked the term ‘Schumpeterian’ for their endogenous growth theorizing, do not even have ‘entrepreneur’ or ‘entrepreneurship’ in the index of their 190 page book.

  3. See, for example, Deane (1969), Harley (1982), Crafts (2005) and Wrigley (2010) for extended discussion concerning the existence, or otherwise, of the first industrial revolution.

  4. Harris (1967) pointed out that steam engines were used extensively in the 18th Century to pump water out of coal mines, even though they were relatively inefficient, because they used ‘waste’ coal fragments that had little commercial value.

  5. Field (2011) has provided convincing evidence that, in the US case, this resulted in a sharp rise in inventive and innovative behaviour in the 1930s.

  6. It has been commonly assumed in a number of neoclassically-based studies of economic growth that the capital-output and/or the capital-labour ratio have been approximately constant. In the British case, the former in 2010 was about 2.5 times greater that it was in 1900 and the latter about 12 times greater.

  7. The two negative blips are caused by the potato famine (1845-1852) and Irish independence (1922).

  8. Interestingly, despite its reputation as a ‘mature’ economy, the UK continued, up to the recession of 2009, to record a labour productivity growth rate that was not only consistently positive but on a continual rising trend, despite the massive shift towards service sector activities.

  9. Stern and Kander (2012) stepped back from the endogenous growth framework, instead, employing a variant of the Solow growth model using a CES production function with time varying elasticities of substitution. They reported that, for Sweden, energy seems to have played an important role in the determination of economic growth over two centuries. Ayres and Warr (2009) also viewed the Cobb-Douglas specification as too restrictive, preferring a more realistic Linex production function to which they add ‘useful work’ to capture energy flow and energy efficiency effects.

  10. There is no particular focus on energy in most endogenous growth models although it does figure in some studies (see Pittel and Rübbelke (2010) for a review).

  11. Howitt and Aghion (1998) also, saw the capital stock as the main conduit for innovation. However, the neoclassically-based theory that they offer is very different, analytically, to the evolutionary macroeconomic one proposed here and it is not operationalisable econometrically.

  12. The results reported using the logistic specification are very similar but the Gompertz results offer a much more plausible representation of the diffusion process at that has been at work.

  13. Since all product innovations are the outcome of the efforts of labour and there are also continual increases in the efficiency of energy use, making it cheaper per joule, acan be viewed as the sum of two connected diffusion coefficients. Thus, it is possible for GDP to grow at a faster rate than these inputs.

  14. Foster and Wild (1999b) provide evidence suggesting that the errors in an innovation diffusion growth model should not be strictly random.

  15. This formulation is similar to the ‘capital stock adjustment principle’ (Matthews 1959), not in a cyclical context where GDP is the main independent variable, but operative over the much longer time scale relevant to economic growth.

  16. Irish independence shifted population and GDP time series for the UK in the Maddison data. The impact of this was checked in the modelling and found not to be a problem.

  17. There has been considerable controversy concerning the reliability of data used by ‘cliometricians’ prior to 1830. See, For example, Allen (2008)

  18. Note that the total energy consumption data used in the modeling was for England and Wales, rather than the UK. So there is an implicit assumption that there is a fixed ratio between the two. Examination of Scottish and UK population statistics suggested that England and Wales, indeed, is a good proxy, especially when it is the rate of growth of total energy consumption that is the explanatory variable used in the modeling.

  19. Instrument List: e t −1 , e t −2 , e t −4 , h t −1 , h t −1 , DUM 184042, DUM 1856, DUM 1919, DUM 1941, DUM 2009, gpop t , gpop t −1 , gpop t −2 , gpop t −5 , gpop t −6 , gpop t −7 , E t −1

  20. It should be borne in mind that the presence of measurement error in explanatory variables biases estimated coefficients downwards. This is likely to be the case when using long series of annual data. However, it is not possible to assess the magnitude of such bias except to note that the observed stability of estimated coefficients in different sample periods suggest that such bias is likely to be small.

  21. Energy prices are sourced from Fouquet (2011). It is inadvisable to go further back in history than 1850 because earlier estimates of energy prices, based upon very fragmentary, infrequent and localized data, are notoriously unreliable.

  22. See Gordon (2012) for discussion, using a different perspective, of the prospects of future growth in what is currently the World’s leading economy, the United States.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2012) Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. Mass, MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2008) A review of Gregory Clark’s a farewell to alms: a brief economic history of the world. J Econ Lit 46(4):946–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2009) The british industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29(3):155–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur WB (1994) Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres RU, Warr B (2009) The economic growth engine: how energy and work drive material prosperity. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ (2002) The free market innovation machine: analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Boretos GP (2009) The future of the global economy. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 76(2009):316–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JH, Burnside WR, Davidson AD, DeLong JP, Dunn WC et al. (2011) Energetic limits to economic growth. BioScience 61:19–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapman SD (1970) Fixed capital formation in the british cotton industry, 1770–1815. Econ Hist Rev 23(2):235–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N (2005) The first industrial revolution: resolving the slow growth/rapid industrialization paradox. J Eur Econ Assoc 3(2–3):525–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson JEH, Hendry DF, Srba F, Yeo S (1978) Econometric modelling of the aggregate time series relationship between consumers’ expenditure and income in the UK. Econ J 88:661–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deane P (1969) The first industrial revolution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Denison EF (1974) Accounting for United States economic growth 1929-1969. The Brookings Institution, Washington D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond J (2005) Collapse: how societies choose to fail or succeed. Viking Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (1986) The histonomic approach to economics: beyond pure theory and pure experience. J Econ Issues XX(4):989–1010

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (2006) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyke C (1990) Cities as dissipative structures. In: Weber B, Depew DJ, Smith JD (eds) Entropy, information, and evolution: new perspectives on physical and biological evolution. Mass.: MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 162–185

    Google Scholar 

  • Field AJ (2011) A great leap forward: 1930s depression and U.S. economic growth. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Fine B (2000) Endogenous growth theory: a critical assessment. Camb J Econ 24(2):245–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J (1987) Evolutionary macroeconomics. Unwin Hyman, London (Reproduced in the Routledge Revivals Series, 2011)

  • Foster J (2005) From simplistic to complex adaptive systems in economics. Camb J Econ 29:873–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J (2011a) Evolutionary macroeconomics: a research agenda. J Evol Econ Springer 21(1):5–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J (2011b) Energy, aesthetics and knowledge in complex economic systems. J Econ Behav Organ 80(1):88–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Metcalfe JS (2012) Economic emergence: an evolutionary economic perspective. J Econ Behav Organ Elsevier 82(2):420–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Wild P (1999a) Econometric modelling in the presence of evolutionary change. Camb J Econ 23:749–770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Wild P (1999b) Detecting self-organisational change in economic processes exhibiting logistic growth. J Evol Econ 9:109–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet R (2008) Heat power and light. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet R (2011) Divergences in long run trends in the prices of energy and energy services. Rev Environ Econ Policy 5(2):196–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman C, Louca F (2002) As time goes by: from the industrial revolutions to the information revolution. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Michalopoulos S (2012) Evolution and the growth process: natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. J Econ Theory 147(2):756–777

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen N (1971) The entropy law and the economic process. Harvard University Press, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (2012) Is US growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds. NBER Working Paper No. 18315, http://www.nber.org/papers/w18315

  • Harley CK (1982) British industrialization before 1841: evidence of slower growth during the industrial revolution. J Econ Hist 42(2):267–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris JR (1967) The employment of steam power in the Eigtheenth Century. History 52(175):133–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howitt P, Aghion P (1998) Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth. J Econ Growth 3:111–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jevons WS (1866) The coal question. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes DS (1998) The wealth and poverty of nations: why are some so rich and others so poor? W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2008a) Statistics on world population, GDP and per capita GDP, 1–2006 AD. http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/

  • Maddison A (2008b) The west and the rest in the world economy: 1000–2030, Maddisonian and Malthusian interpretations. World Econ 9(4)

  • Madsen JB, Ang JB, Banerjee R (2010) Four centuries of British economic growth: the roles of technology and population. J Econ Growth 15:263–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews RCO (1959) The trade cycle. James Nisbet Ltd at, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS (2003) Industrial growth and the theory of retardation. precursors of an adaptive evolutionary theory of economic change. Revue économique, Presses de Sciences-Po 54(2):407–431

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey D (2010) Bourgeois dignity: why economics can’t explain the modern world. University of Chicago Press

  • Miranda LCM, Lima CAS (2011) On the forecasting of the challenging world future scenarios. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 78:1445–1470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2002) The gifts of athena: historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton University press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Mass.: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn N, Qian N (2011) The Potato’s contribution to population and urbanization: evidence from a historical experiment. Q J Econ 126:593–650

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perez (2002) Technological revolutions and financial capital. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pittel K, Rübbelke D (2010) Energy supply and the sustainability of endogenous growth BC3 Working Paper Series (No.10, July) Basque Centre for Climate Change

  • Schneider ED, Kay JJ (1994) Life as a manifestation of the second law of thermodynamics. Math Comput Model 19:25–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider ED, Sagan D (2005) Into the cool: energy flow, thermodynamics and life. University of Chicago press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Smil V (2008) Energy in nature and society: general energetics of complex systems. MIT Press

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39(3):312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (2007) The last 50 years in growth theory and the next 10. Oxford review of economic policy, vol 23(1) Oxford University Press, pp 3–14, Spring

  • Stern DI (2011) The role of energy in economic growth in ecological economic reviews. Robert Costanza, Karin Limburg & Ida Kubiszewski, Eds. Ann. N.Y. Acad. Sci. 1219:26–51

  • Stern DI, Kander A (2012) The role of energy in the industrial revolution and modern economic growth. Energy J 33(3):125–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tainter JA (1988) The collapse of complex societies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA (2010) Energy and the english industrial revolution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John Foster.

Additional information

This paper was presented in preliminary form as the Presidential Address at the International J.A. Schumpeter Society Conference, July2–5th 2012, University of Queensland, Brisbane, Australia. I would like to thank Maxine Darnell for providing advice concerning the treatment of energy in the British economic history literature. Roger Fouquet and Jakob Madsen kindly provided me with their historical data. Thanks are also due to Stan Metcalfe, Jakob Madsen and David Stern for their extensive comments and criticisms of a previous version of this paper. However, all errors and omissions remain the responsibility of the author.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Foster, J. Energy, knowledge and economic growth. J Evol Econ 24, 209–238 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0348-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0348-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation