Skip to main content
Log in

Cournot–Bertrand comparison in a mixed oligopoly

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We revisit the classic discussion comparing price and quantity competition, but in a mixed oligopoly in which one state-owned public firm competes against private firms. It has been shown that in a mixed duopoly, price competition yields a larger profit for the private firm. This implies that firms face weaker competition under price competition, which contrasts sharply with the case of a private oligopoly. Here, we adopt a standard differentiated oligopoly with a linear demand. We find that regardless of the number of firms, price competition yields higher welfare. However, the profit ranking depends on the number of private firms. We find that if the number of private firms is greater than or equal to five, it is possible that quantity competition yields a larger profit for each private firm. We also endogenize the price-quantity choice. Here, we find that Bertrand competition can fail to be an equilibrium, unless there is only one private firm.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Shubik and Levitan (1980) and Vives (1985).

  2. Analyses of mixed oligopolies date back to Merrill and Schneider (1966). Their study, and many others in the field, assume that a public firm maximizes welfare (consumer surplus plus firm profits), while private firms maximize profits.

  3. See also Nakamura (2013), who include a network externality.

  4. Haraguchi and Matsumura (2014) showed that this result holds, regardless of the nationality of the private firm. Chirco et al. (2014) showed that both firms choose a price contract when the organizational structure is endogenized. However, Scrimitore (2013) showed that both firms can choose a quantity contract if a production subsidy is introduced.

  5. See, among others, De Fraja and Delbono (1989), Fjell and Pal (1996), Matsumura and Kanda (2005), Lin and Matsumura (2012), and Ghosh et al. (2015). An example of such market is the Japanese overnight delivery market. Here, Japan Post competes against private firms such as Yamato, Sagawa, and Seinou.

  6. These are satisfied if \(a_0=a_i\). Note that if \(\delta \) is close to one, \(a_i-a_0\) must be close to zero.

  7. We can show that the Bertrand model yields higher welfare and a larger profit in each private firm than does the Cournot model in the case in which one private firm competes against multiple public firms. This is the opposite case of the basic model.

  8. We can show that Bertrand competition is an equilibrium if two public firms compete against one private firm.

  9. For discussions on free-entry markets in mixed oligopolies, see Matsumura and Kanda (2005), Brandão and Castro (2007), Fujiwara (2007), Ino and Matsumura (2010), and Wang and Chen (2010). For recent developments in this field, see Cato and Matsumura (2012, 2013), Ghosh et al. (2015), Ghosh and Sen (2012), and Wang and Lee (2013).

  10. Our result depends on the linearity of cost function. For example, if we consider a quadratic production cost function, we can show that Cournot competition may yield a larger profit of each private firm than the Bertrand competition even when \(n \le 4\).

  11. A proof that does not rely on accompanying figure is available upon request.

  12. A proof that does not rely on accompanying figure is available upon request.

References

  • Bose A, Gupta B (2013) Mixed markets in bilateral monopoly. J Econ 110(2):141–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandão A, Castro S (2007) State-owned enterprises as indirect instruments of entry regulation. J Econ 92(3):263–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cato S, Matsumura T (2012) Long-run effects of foreign penetration on privatization policies. J Inst Theor Econ 168(3):444–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cato S, Matsumura T (2013) Long-run effects of tax policies in a mixed market. FinanzArchiv 69(2):215–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng L (1985) Comparing Bertrand and Cournot equilibria: a geometric approach. RAND J Econ 16(1):146–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirco A, Colombo C, Scrimitore M (2014) Organizational structure and the choice of price versus quantity in a mixed duopoly. Jpn Econ Rev 65(4):521–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Fraja G, Delbono F (1989) Alternative strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly. Oxf Econ Pap 41(2):302–311

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK (1979) A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers. Bell J Econ 10(1):20–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Pal D (1996) A mixed oligopoly in the presence of foreign private firms. Can J Econ 29(3):737–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujiwara K (2007) Partial privatization in a differentiated mixed oligopoly. J Econ 92(1):51–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh A, Mitra M (2010) Comparing Bertrand and Cournot in mixed markets. Econ Lett 109(2):72–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh A, Mitra M (2014) Reversal of Bertrand–Cournot rankings in the presence of welfare concerns. J Inst Theor Econ 170(3):496–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh A, Sen P (2012) Privatization in a small open economy with imperfect competition. J Public Econ Theory 14(3):441–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh A, Mitra M, Saha B (2015) Privatization, underpricing and welfare in the presence of foreign competition. J Public Econ Theory 17(3):433–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haraguchi J, Matsumura T (2014) Price versus quantity in a mixed duopoly with foreign penetration. Res Econ 68(4):338–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ino H, Matsumura T (2010) What role should public enterprises play in free-entry markets? J Econ 101(3):213–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin MH, Matsumura T (2012) Presence of foreign investors in privatized firms and privatization policy. J Econ 107(1):71–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (1998) Partial privatization in mixed duopoly. J Public Econ 70(3):473–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Kanda O (2005) Mixed oligopoly at free entry markets. J Econ 84(1):27–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N (2012) Airport privatization and international competition. Jpn Econ Rev 63(4):431–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Ogawa A (2012) Price versus quantity in a mixed duopoly. Econ Lett 116(2):174–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Okumura Y (2013) Privatization neutrality theorem revisited. Econ Lett 118(2):324–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Shimizu D (2010) Privatization waves. Manch Sch 78(6):609–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merrill WC, Schneider N (1966) Government firms in oligopoly industries: a short-run analysis. Q J Econ 80(3):400–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura Y (2013) Social welfare under quantity competition and price competition in a mixed duopoly with network effects: an analysis. Theor Econ Lett 3:211–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scrimitore M (2013) Price or quantity?: the strategic choice of subsidized firms in a mixed duopoly. Econ Lett 118(2):337–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scrimitore M (2014) Profitability under commitment in Cournot and Bertrand mixed markets. J Inst Theor Econ 170(4):684–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shubik M, Levitan R (1980) Market structure and behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Singh N, Vives X (1984) Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. RAND J Econ 15(4):546–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka Y (2001a) Profitability of price and quantity strategies in an oligopoly. J Math Econ 35(3):409–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka Y (2001b) Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation. Econ Theory 17(3):693–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tasnádi A (2006) Price vs quantity in oligopoly games. Int J Ind Organ 24(3):541–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vives X (1985) On the efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria with product differentiation. J Econ Theory 36:166–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS, Chen TL (2010) Do cost efficiency gap and foreign competitors matter concerning optimal privatization policy at the free entry market? J Econ 100(1):33–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS, Lee JY (2013) Foreign penetration and undesirable competition. Econ Model 30(1):729–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Junichi Haraguchi.

Additional information

J. Haraguchi and T. Matsumura are indebted to two anonymous referees for their valuable and constructive suggestions. J. Haraguchi and T. Matsumura are grateful to Dan Sasaki and participants of the seminars at The University of Tokyo, Nippon University and annual meeting of JEA 2014 spring for their helpful comments and suggestions. T. Matsumura acknowledges the financial support of the Murata Science Foundation and JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 15k03347. Any remaining errors are our own.

Appendices

Appendix A

$$\begin{aligned} H_1\equiv & {} \delta (1-\delta )(a_i^2-2\delta a_0a_i+\delta a_0^2)n^2+((3-\delta )a_i^2-2\delta (3-\delta )a_0a_i\\&+\delta (\delta ^2-3\delta +4)a_0^2)n+a_0^2(2-\delta )^2\\ H_2\equiv & {} \delta ^4(a_i-2\delta a_0a_i+\delta a_0^2)n^5+(1-\delta )\delta ^3(6a_i^2-12\delta a_0a_i+7\delta a_0^2)n^4 \\&-(1-\delta )\delta ^2((11\delta -12)a_i^2+(-22\delta ^2+24 \delta )a_0a_i+(18\delta ^2-19\delta )a_0^2)n^3\\&+(1-\delta )\delta (6\delta ^2-17\delta +10)a_i^2+ (-12\delta ^3+34\delta ^2-20\delta )a_0a_i\\&+(18\delta ^3-44\delta ^2+25\delta )a_0)n^2-(1-\delta )^3((\delta -3) a_i^2+(-2\delta ^2+6\delta )a_0a_i\\&+(7\delta ^2-16\delta )a_0^2)n+(1-\delta )^3(2-\delta )^2a_0^2\\ H_3\equiv & {} 4(a_j-a_i)^2\delta ^5m^5-2\delta ^4(13a_j^2\delta -22a_i a_j\delta +13a_i^2\delta -11a_j^2+18a_i a_j\\&-11a_i^2)m^4+\delta ^3(65a_j^2\delta ^2-86a_i a_j\delta ^2 +69a_i^2\delta ^2-110a_j^2\delta +140a_i a_j\delta \\&-118a_i^2\delta +46a_j^2-56a_i a_j+50a_i^2)m^3 +(1-\delta )\delta ^2(75a_j^2\delta ^2-64a_i a_j\delta ^2\\&+83a_i^2\delta ^2-116a_j^2\delta +92a_i a_j\delta -132a_i^2 \delta +44a_j^2-32a_i a_j+52a_i^2)m^2\\&+(1-\delta )^2\delta (40a_j^2\delta ^2-16a_i a_j\delta ^2 +45a_i^2\delta ^2-56a_j^2\delta +20a_i a_j\delta -66a_i^2\delta \\&+19a_j^2-6a_i a_j+24a_i^2)m+(1-\delta )^3(8a_j^2\delta ^2 +9a_i^2\delta ^2-10a_j^2\delta \\&-12a_i^2\delta +3a_j^2+4a_i^2)\\ H_4\equiv & {} 2(a_j-a_i)^2(2-\delta )\delta ^2m^2+\delta (3a_j^2 \delta ^2-2a_i a_j\delta ^2+3a_i^2\delta ^2-10a_j^2\delta +8a_i a_j\delta \\&-10a_i^2\delta +7a_j^2-6a_i a_j+8a_i^2)m +(1-\delta )(a_j^2\delta ^2+a_i^2\delta ^2-4a_j^2\delta \\&-4a_i^2\delta +3a_j^2+4a_i^2) \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} H_5\equiv & {} -(1-\delta )\delta ^4n^4+(1-\delta )(3\delta -2) \delta ^3n^3+(3\delta ^3-7\delta ^2+2\delta +3)\delta ^2n^2 \\&+(1-\delta )(4-\delta )(2-\delta ^2)\delta n+(1-\delta )^2 (2-\delta )(2+\delta )\\ H_6\equiv & {} \delta ^3(\delta ^2-3\delta +3)n^3+ \delta ^2(1-\delta )(\delta ^2-6\delta +11)n^2+ \delta (1-\delta )(3\delta ^2-14\delta +12)n\\&-(1-\delta )(2-\delta )(3\delta -2)\\ H_{7}\equiv & {} 2\delta ^3c_0n^3-\delta ^2(2c_i(7\delta -8)c_0 -2\alpha (1-\delta ))n^2+\delta ((3\delta -2)c_i\\&+(5\delta ^2-19\delta +10)c_0+(3\delta ^2-5\delta +2)\alpha )n -(\delta (\delta -2)c_i\\&-(2\delta ^3+7\delta -2-12 \delta +4)c_0+\alpha \delta (\delta ^2-3\delta +2))\\ H_{8}\equiv & {} 2\delta ^3c_in^3-\delta ^2((9\delta -6)c_i-2 \delta c_0-2(1-\delta )\alpha )n^2+\delta ((8\delta ^2-16\delta +6) c_i\\&-\delta (5\delta -4)c_0+(5\delta ^2-9\delta +4)\alpha )n +(\delta ^3+7\delta ^2-7\delta +2)c_i\\&+\delta (2\delta ^2-5\delta +2)c_0 -(2\delta ^3-7\delta ^2+7\delta -2)\alpha \\ H_{9}\equiv & {} -(\delta ^3n^3-\delta ^3n^2+3\delta ^2n-3\delta n- \delta ^3-\delta ^2+4\delta -2)(4\delta ^5n^5-26\delta ^5n^4\\&+24\delta ^4n^4+57\delta ^5n^3-118\delta ^4n^3+56\delta ^3n^3 -49\delta ^5n^2+186\delta ^4n^2-198\delta ^3n^2\\&+64\delta ^2n^2 +12\delta ^5n-103\delta ^4n+201\delta ^3n-146\delta ^2n+36\delta n+ \delta ^5+13\delta ^4\\&-54\delta ^3+72\delta ^2-40\delta +8)\\ H_{10}\equiv & {} (2\delta ^3n^3-9\delta ^3n^2+8\delta ^2n^2+8\delta ^3n-21\delta ^2n+10\delta n+\delta ^3+9\delta ^2-12\delta +4)^2\\ H_{11}\equiv & {} \delta c_i^2n^2-2\delta ^2c_0c_in^2+2\alpha \delta ^2c_in^2-2\alpha \delta c_in^2+\delta ^2c_0^2n^2- \alpha ^2\delta ^2n^2+\alpha ^2\delta n^2\\&+2\delta c_i^2n+3c_i^2n-4\delta ^2c_0c_in-6\delta c_0c_in +4\alpha \delta ^2c_in+2\alpha \delta c_in-6\alpha c_in\\&+\delta ^2c_0^2n+4\delta c_0^2n+2\alpha \delta ^2c_0n-2\alpha \delta c_0n-3\alpha ^2\delta ^2n+3\alpha ^2n-\delta ^3c_0^2-3 \delta ^2c_0^2\\&+4c_0^2+2\alpha \delta ^3c_0+6\alpha \delta ^2c_0-8\alpha c_0-\alpha ^2\delta ^3-3\alpha ^2\delta ^2+4\alpha ^2 \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} H_{12}\equiv & {} 8\delta ^5m^5-16\delta ^4m^5+10\delta ^3m^5 -32\delta ^5m^4+76\delta ^4m^4-70\delta ^3m^4+25\delta ^2m^4\\&+50\delta ^5m^3-132\delta ^4m^3+138\delta ^3m^3-74\delta ^2m^3 +18\delta m^3-38\delta ^5m^2+113\delta ^4m^2\\&-126\delta ^3m^2+69\delta ^2m^2-22\delta m^2+4m^2+14\delta ^5m -48\delta ^4m+60\delta ^3m\\&-32\delta ^2m+6\delta m-2\delta ^5 +8\delta ^4-12\delta ^3+8\delta ^2-2\delta \\ H_{13}\equiv & {} 4 \delta ^2 m^4+8 \delta ^4 m^3-32 \delta ^3 m^3 +18 \delta ^2 m^3+2 \delta m^3-12 \delta ^4 m^2+64 \delta ^3 m^2\\&-77 \delta ^2 m^2+26 \delta m^2+6 \delta ^4 m-40 \delta ^3 m +68 \delta ^2 m-42 \delta m+8 m-\delta ^4+8 \delta ^3\\&-17\delta ^2+14 \delta -4 \end{aligned}$$

Appendix B

Proof of Proposition 1

From (4) and (2), we have

$$\begin{aligned}&\pi _i^{B}-\pi _i^{C}\\&\quad =\frac{\delta ^2n(a_i-\delta a_0)^2H_5}{\beta (1+n\delta )(1-\delta )(2-\delta +n\delta (1-\delta ))^2(\delta ^2n^2+3\delta (1- \delta )n+(1-\delta )(2-\delta ))^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\pi _i^{B}-\pi _i^{C}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(H_5(n,\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). Figure 1 describes the region for \(H_5(n,\delta )<0\). This shows (i) and (ii).Footnote 11

We have \(\lim _{n\rightarrow \infty }H_5(n,\delta )=-\infty .\) This implies (iii). Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 2

From (3) and (1), we have

$$\begin{aligned}&SW^{B}-SW^{C} \\&\quad =\frac{\delta ^2n^2 (a_1-\delta a_0)^2H_6}{2\beta (1+n\delta )(1-\delta )(2- \delta +n\delta (1-\delta ))^2(\delta ^2n^2+3\delta (1-\delta )n+(1-\delta )(2-\delta ))^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(SW^{B}-SW^{C}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(H_6(n,\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). We now show that \(H_6(1,\delta )>0\) and that \(H_6(n,\delta )\) is increasing in n for \(n \ge 1\).

Substituting \(n=1\) into \(H_6(n,\delta )\), we have \(H_6(1,\delta )= (2-\delta ^2)^2>0\). We show that \(H_6(n,\delta )\) is increasing in n for \(n \ge 1\) if \(\delta \in (0,1)\). We have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial H_6(n,\delta )}{\partial n}= & {} 3\delta ^3(\delta ^2-3\delta +3)n^2+2\delta ^2(1-\delta ) (\delta ^2-6\delta +11)n\\&+\delta (1-\delta )(3\delta ^2-14\delta +12). \end{aligned}$$

This is increasing in n. Substituting in \(n=1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial H_6(n,\delta )}{\partial n}|_{n=1}= \delta ^4(2+\delta )+4\delta (1-\delta )(3+2\delta ) >0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(\frac{\partial H_6(n,\delta )}{\partial n }>0\) for \(n \ge 1\). Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 3

We have already discussed the equilibrium profit of each private firm when all firms choose the price contract (\(\pi _i^B\)). We show that given the contracts of other firms, a private firm has an incentive to choose the quantity contract.

Consider the subgame in which one private firm chooses the quantity contract and all the other firms choose the price contract. In equilibrium, the public firm names the following price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_0=\frac{H_{7}}{2\delta ^3 n^3+\delta ^2(8-9\delta )n^2+\delta (\delta -2)(8\delta -5)n+(2-3\delta )^2}, \end{aligned}$$

the private firms that choose the price contract name the following price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_i= & {} \frac{H_{8}}{2\delta ^3 n^3+\delta ^2(8-9\delta )n^2+\delta (\delta -2)(8\delta -5)n+(2-3\delta )^2},\\&\quad (i=1,2,\ldots ,n-1), \end{aligned}$$

and the private firm that chooses the quantity contract selects the following quantity:

$$\begin{aligned} q_n=\frac{(a_i-\delta a_0)(1+\delta (n-2))(2+\delta (2n-3))}{\beta (2\delta ^3(1-\delta )n^3+\delta ^2(9\delta ^2-17\delta +8)n^2-\delta (8\delta ^3-29\delta ^2+31\delta -10)n-(\delta ^4+8\delta ^3-21\delta ^2+16\delta -4))}. \end{aligned}$$

The private firm that chooses the quantity contract obtains the following profit:

$$\begin{aligned}&\pi ^{p,\ldots ,p,q}\nonumber \\&\quad =\frac{(a_i-\delta a_0)^2(1+n\delta )((n-2\delta )+1)^2((2n-3)\delta +2)^2}{\beta (1-\delta )(\delta (n-1)+1)(2\delta ^3n^3+\delta ^2(8-9\delta )n^2+\delta (8\delta ^2-21\delta +10)n+(\delta ^3+9\delta ^2-12\delta +4))^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

From (4) and (9), we have that

$$\begin{aligned}&\pi _i^{B}-\pi ^{p,\ldots ,p,q} \\&\quad = \frac{\delta ^2(a_i-\delta a_0)^2H_{9}}{\beta (1-\delta )(\delta n+1)(\delta n-\delta +1) (\delta ^2n^2-3\delta ^2n+3\delta n+\delta ^2-3\delta +2)^2 H_{10}}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\pi _i^{B}-\pi ^{p,\ldots ,p,q}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(H_{9}(n,\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). Figure 8 describes the region for \(H_9(n,\delta )<0\). This shows (i).Footnote 12

Fig. 8
figure 8

The region for the Bertrand model fails to be an equilibrium

\(\lim _{n \rightarrow \infty }H_{9}(n,\delta )=-\infty .\) This implies (ii).

We have already discussed the equilibrium welfare when all firms choose the quantity contract (\(SW^{C}\)). We show that given the contracts of all private firms, the public firm has an incentive to choose the price contract, regardless of \(\delta \).

Consider the subgame in which the public firm chooses the price contract and all private firms choose the quantity contract. In equilibrium, the public firm names the following price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_0=m_0, \end{aligned}$$

and all private firms selects the following quantity:

$$\begin{aligned} q_i=\frac{a_i-\delta a_0}{\beta (1-\delta )(2+\delta (1+n))} \quad (i=1,2,\ldots ,n). \end{aligned}$$

Substituting these equilibrium price and quantity into the payoff function, we have the following welfare:

$$\begin{aligned} SW^{p,q,\ldots ,q}=\frac{H_{11}}{2\beta (1-\delta )(\delta n+\delta +2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

From (1) and (10), we have that

$$\begin{aligned} SW^{p,q,\ldots ,q}-SW^{C} = \frac{n\delta ^2(a_i-\delta a_0)^2(\delta n (2-\delta ^2)+\delta (2-\delta )+4)}{2\beta (1-\delta )(\delta n+\delta +2)^2(\delta ^2n-\delta n+\delta -2)^2}>0. \end{aligned}$$

This implies (iii). Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 4

Let \(\pi _j^{B}\) and \(\pi _j^{C}\) be the profit of each private firm under Bertrand and Cournot competition, respectively. From (5) and (7), we have that \(\pi _j^{B}-\pi _j^{C}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\delta ^2(\delta m(a_i-a_j)-(1-\delta )a_j)^2H_{12}}{\beta (1-\delta )(2\delta m-\delta +1)(\delta m(2\delta -3)- (1-\delta )(2-\delta ))^2(2\delta ^2m(m-3)+5\delta m+(1-\delta )(2-3\delta ))^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\pi _j^{B}-\pi _j^{C}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(H_{12}(m,\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). We show that \(H_{12}(1,\delta )\) is positive, and \(H_{12}(m,\delta )\) is increasing in m for \(m\ge 1\). Substituting \(m=1\) into \(H_{12}(m,\delta )\), we have \(H_{12}(1,\delta )=\delta ^4-4\delta ^2+4>0\). We have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {H_{12}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}= & {} \delta ^3 (10m^3-6m^2-2m-2)m+4\delta ^2(1-\delta )(13\delta ^2+6(1-\delta )\\&+19(1-\delta )^2)m^3+(25(1-\delta )^4+5\delta ^3(1-\delta )^3 +4\delta ^2(1-\delta )^4\\&+(1-\delta )^5+(1-\delta )^6+\delta ^2f_2(\delta ))m^2 +(2(1-\delta )^4+17\delta ^3(1-\delta )^4\\&+21\delta ^3(1-\delta )^3+15\delta ^2(1-\delta )^5+2(1-\delta )^7+\delta ^3f_3(\delta ))m\\&+2\delta (7\delta ^4-24\delta ^3+30\delta ^2-16\delta +3), \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} f_2(\delta )\equiv & {} 8\delta ^3+21\delta ^2-57\delta +29,\\ f_3(\delta )\equiv & {} 21\delta ^3+52\delta ^2-41\delta +11. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(m=1\) into this, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {H_{12}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}|_{m=1}=2(2-\delta )(\delta (4-3\delta )+2)>0. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\frac{\partial H_{12}(m,\delta )}{\partial m}\) is increasing in m for \(m\ge 1\) if \(f_2(\delta )>0\) and \(f_3(\delta )>0\).

First, we show that \(f_2(\delta )>0\). We have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d f_2(\delta )}{d \delta }=24\delta ^2+42\delta -57. \end{aligned}$$

Solving \(\frac{d f_2(\delta )}{d \delta }=0\) leads to the following solutions:

$$\begin{aligned} \delta =\frac{-7+\sqrt{201}}{8},\quad \delta =\frac{-7-\sqrt{201}}{8}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(f_2(\delta )\) is minimized when \(\delta =\frac{-7+\sqrt{201}}{8}\) for \(\delta \in (0,1)\). Since

$$\begin{aligned} f_2\left( \frac{-7+\sqrt{201}}{8} \right) =\frac{2867-201^{3/2}}{8}>0. \end{aligned}$$

\(f_2(\delta ) >0\) for \(\delta \in (0,1)\).

Next, we show that \(f_3(\delta )>0\). We have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d f_3(\delta )}{d \delta }=-63\delta ^2+104\delta -41. \end{aligned}$$

Solving \(\frac{d f_3(\delta )}{d \delta }=0\) leads to the following solutions:

$$\begin{aligned} \delta =\frac{41}{63},\quad \delta =1. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(f_3(\delta )\) is minimized when \(\delta =\frac{41}{63}\) for \(\delta \in (0,1)\). Since

$$\begin{aligned} f_3 \left( \frac{41}{63} \right)= & {} \frac{6583}{11907}>0, \end{aligned}$$

\(f_3(\delta ) >0\) for \(\delta \in (0,1)\).

Therefore, \(\frac{\partial {H_{12}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}>0\) for \(m \ge 1\).

We now compare the welfare. From (6) and (8), we have that \(SW^{B}-SW^{C}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\delta ^2m(\delta m-\delta +1)(\delta m(a_i-a_j)-(1-\delta )a_j)^2H_{13}}{2\beta (1-\delta )(2\delta m-\delta +1)(\delta m(2\delta -3)-(1-\delta )(2-\delta ))^2(\delta m(2\delta m-6\delta +5)+(\delta -1)(3\delta -2))^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(SW^{B}-SW^{C}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(H_{13}(m,\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). We show that \(H_{13}(1,\delta )\) is positive, and \(H_{13}(m,\delta )\) is increasing in m for \(m>1\). Substituting \(m=1\) into \(H_{13}(m,\delta )\) we have \(H_{13}(1,\delta )=\delta ^4-4\delta ^2+4>0\). We show that \(H_{13}(m,\delta )\) is increasing in m for \(m \ge 1\) if \(\delta \in (0,1)\).

We have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {H_{13}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}= & {} 4\delta ^2(4m^2-3m-1)m+6\delta (1-\delta )(4\delta (1-\delta )+8\delta +1)m^2+2\delta f_4(\delta ) m \\&+6\delta ^4-40\delta ^3+68\delta ^2-42\delta +8, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} f_4(\delta )\equiv & {} -12\delta ^3+64\delta ^2-75\delta +26. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting in \(m=1\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial {H_{13}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}\Big |_{m=1}=6\delta ^4-8\delta ^3-16\delta ^2+16\delta +8>0. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(\frac{\partial {H_{13}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}\) is increasing in m for \(m\ge 1\) if \(f_4(\delta )>0\). We show \(f_4(\delta )\) is positive if \(\delta \in (0,1)\). We have that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d f_4(\delta )}{d \delta }=-36\delta ^2+128\delta -75. \end{aligned}$$

Solving \(\frac{d f_4(\delta )}{d \delta }=0\) leads to the following solutions:

$$\begin{aligned} \delta =\frac{32+\sqrt{349}}{18},\quad \delta =\frac{32-\sqrt{349}}{18}. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(f_4(\delta )\) is minimized when \(\delta =\frac{32-\sqrt{349}}{18}\). Because

$$\begin{aligned} f_4 \left( \frac{32-\sqrt{349}}{18} \right) =\frac{6686-349^{3/2}}{243}>0, \end{aligned}$$

\(f_4(\delta ) >0\) for \(\delta \in (0,1)\). Thus, \(\frac{\partial {H_{13}(m,\delta )}}{\partial {m}}>0\) for \(m \ge 1\). Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 5

We have already discussed the equilibrium profit of each private firm when all firms choose the price contract. Let \(\pi _j^B\) denote this profit. We show that given the contracts of other firms, a private firm has an incentive to deviate and chooses the quantity contract. We consider the subgame in which one private firm (firm 3) chooses the quantity contract and all the other firms (firm 0, firm 1, and firm 2) choose the price contract. In equilibrium , the public firms (firm 0 and firm 1) name the following price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_i=\frac{(5\delta ^3+7\delta ^2+2\delta )m_j+(-13\delta ^2 -16\delta -4)m_i+5\alpha \delta ^3-3\alpha \delta ^2-2\alpha \delta }{10\delta ^3-9\delta ^2-16\delta -4}\quad (i=0,1), \end{aligned}$$

the private firm that chooses the price contract (firm 2) names the following price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_2=\frac{(10\delta ^3-4\delta ^2-9\delta -2)m_j+(-10\delta ^2-4\delta )m_i+5\alpha \delta ^2-3\alpha \delta -2\alpha }{10\delta ^3-9\delta ^2-16\delta -4}, \end{aligned}$$

and the private firm that chooses the quantity contract (firm 3) selects the following quantity:

$$\begin{aligned} q_3=\frac{-(3\delta ^2+5\delta +2)m_j-(-6\delta ^2-4\delta )m_i-3\alpha \delta ^2+\alpha \delta +2\alpha }{10\beta \delta ^4-19\beta \delta ^3-7\beta \delta ^2+12\beta \delta +4\beta }. \end{aligned}$$

The private firm that chooses the quantity contract (firm 3) obtains the following profit:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^{p,p,p,q}=\frac{(1+3\delta )(2+3\delta )^2(\delta (a_j-a_i)+(1-\delta )a_i)^2}{\beta (1-\delta )(1+2\delta )(10\delta ^3-9\delta ^2-16\delta -4)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Substituting \(m=2\) into (5) we have that \(\pi _j^{B}\) for \(m=2\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _j^{B}=\frac{(1+\delta )^2(1+2\delta )(\delta (a_j-a_i) +(1-\delta )a_i)^2}{\beta (1-\delta )(1+3\delta )(\delta ^2-5 \delta -2)^2}\quad (j=2,3). \end{aligned}$$
(12)

From (12) and (11), we have that \(\pi _j^{B}-\pi ^{p,p,p,q}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\delta ^2f_5(\delta )(20\delta ^3(1-\delta ^2)+21\delta ^3(1-\delta )+44\delta ^3+126\delta ^2+56\delta +8)(\delta (a_j-a_i)+(1-\delta )a_i)^2}{\beta (1-\delta )(1+2\delta )(1+3\delta )(\delta ^2-5\delta -2)^2(10 \delta ^3-9\delta ^2-16\delta -4)^2}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(f_5(\delta )=-20\delta ^3-3\delta ^2+13\delta +4\).

Here, \(\pi _j^{B}-\pi ^{p,p,p,q}\) is positive (res. negative, zero) if \(f_5(\delta )\) is positive (res. negative, zero). \(f_5(\delta )<0\) if \(\delta > \delta ^* \simeq 0.867.\) Q.E.D.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Haraguchi, J., Matsumura, T. Cournot–Bertrand comparison in a mixed oligopoly. J Econ 117, 117–136 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-015-0452-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-015-0452-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation