Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The effects at home of initiating production abroad: evidence from matched French firms

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Based on matching techniques in combination with a difference-in-difference estimator, this paper estimates the effects at home of initiating production abroad through the establishment of a foreign production affiliate. The analysis covers manufacturing and service firms active in France during the period 1987–1999. We show that the motivation to start producing abroad is an important determinant of its impact at home. Market-seeking foreign direct investment (FDI) in manufacturing is associated with significant scale effects, resulting in job creation. By contrast, factor-seeking FDI in manufacturing has no significant effect on employment. However, there is some evidence that this type of FDI is associated with technology effects, in the form of greater capital-intensity and efficiency, as well as larger exports. Finally, FDI in service sectors is associated with significant positive employment effects, presumably reflecting the importance of the market-seeking motive in these sectors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The main concern is in this case to evaluate whether exporters are better performers because of self-selection into export market or whereas this reflects learning-by-exporting (see amongst others Clerides et al. 1998; Girma et al. 2004).

  2. A substantial number of papers however has looked at the related but different issue of the effects of foreign takeovers on local plants. See for example Arnold and Javorcik (2009) and Girma and Görg (2007).

  3. Another reason why vertical FDI usually raises more important social concerns than horizontal FDI is that the jobs destroyed as a result of relocation tend to be very different from those created as a result of indirect effects.

  4. As we are only interested in firms that establish a first foreign affiliate, complex forms of foreign direct investment necessarily reflect establishments which are likely to be motivated by both horizontal and vertical motives. While theoretically the effects of complex forms, as defined here, on observable outcomes at home simply present a linear combination of the two pure investment strategies, failure to disentangle those different forms empirically does not allow one to grasp their implications appropriately.

  5. See Lechner (2001) and Blundell et al. (2005) for more details on multiple treatment effects.

  6. As discussed below, this is true with very few exceptions, which we classify as investors in a high-income location.

  7. Nevertheless, the improvement of information and communication technologies has rendered the proximity requirement less systematic, as illustrated by the growing concerns surrounding services offshoring. Moreover, given the importance of producer services for manufacturing production, the increasing international fragmentation of production has tended to go hand-in-hand with FDI in services, since multinational firms often need their service providers to extend in parallel to them. However, the link between FDI in manufacturing and FDI services does not appear to have much bearing on the impact of FDI in services on the parent firm, except perhaps an additional need for co-ordination, a rather skill-intensive activity.

  8. However, it would still be interesting to analyze how the impact of services FDI differs across services activities since the nature of FDI is likely to differ substantially across say business services, transportation services and hotels and restaurants. Unfortunately, the relatively small number of foreign-direct investments in services and their concentration in business and computing services does not allow us to make meaningful comparisons of the impact of services FDI across sectors. The sectoral breakdown of the estimation sample of matched firm pairs is shown in "Appendix 2" Table 3.

  9. As emphasized below, the sector classification concerns the activity of the investing firms, not of its affiliates. Our analysis thus concerns investment by service firms. However, it is not clear how important that difference is in practice. We implicitly assume that services firms invest in services sectors abroad.

  10. See Blundell and Costa Dias (2002) for a survey of the alternative approaches to evaluation problems.

  11. Consequently, in contrast to ordinary least squares, matching does not rely on assumptions regarding functional form (i.e. linearity) and homogenous treatment effects (that the treatment effect is identical across individuals).

  12. More specifically, the survey conducted by Direction des Relations Economiques Extérieures on French affiliates abroad is used to sort out the treated from the untreated, while the EAE is used to analyse why firms decide to establish a foreign affiliate abroad and how this affects their performance. See below for details on data sources.

  13. More recently, Hahn (1998) has shown that using the propensity score may also improve the efficiency of ATT by reducing the number of dimensions.

  14. In practical terms, implementing the DID estimator involves estimating a fixed effects model on the difference in the means between treated and untreated firms.

  15. The sampling method used in services since 1997 is based upon a threshold. This threshold is generally set at 30 employees or a turnover of at least 5 million euros. All firms beyond the threshold are systematically surveyed each year, while only a sample of other firms below the threshold are surveyed each year.

  16. Strictly speaking, a sufficient condition would have been to require the panel to be balanced up to t-star, the year in which firms switch. However, having a completely balanced panel facilitates the interpretation of the results as it removes any effects which are due to changes in the composition of firms after t-star. Barba Navaretti et al. (2010) also use a balanced panel but do not define cohorts.

  17. A similar methodology is used in Jacobson et al. (1993).

  18. Only 12 such examples are found in the matched estimation sample for manufacturing, 9 for services.

  19. When imposing the common support, not all treated firms have a control on the common support. Accordingly, 286 matched firm pairs are studied below in manufacturing and 151 in services.

  20. The definition of multinationals is restricted here to firms having invested abroad at least 3 years before.

  21. In a manner similar to the Ashenfelter dip in the labour economics literature.

  22. Since differences in average wage are more likely to result from differences in the composition of the workforce than pay differences across firms for similar workers we interpret this variable as a measure of skill-intensity.

References

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S.-J. (2005). Fear of service outsourcing: Is it justified? Economic Policy, 20, 308–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S.-J. (2008). Does service offshoring lead to job losses? In M. Reinsdorf & M. Slaughter (Eds.), International trade in services and intangibles in the era of globalization (pp. 227–246). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S.-J. (2009). Service offshoring and productivity: Evidence from the US. The World Economy, 32(2), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. M., & Javorcik, B. (2009). Gifted kids or pushy parents? Foreign acquisitions and plant performance in Indonesia. Journal of International Economics, 79(1), 42–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barba Navaretti, G., & Castellani, D. (2003). Investments abroad and performance at home. (CEPR Discussion Paper 4284).

  • Barba Navaretti, G., Castellani, D., & Disdier, A.-C. (2010). How does investing in cheap labour countries affect performance at home? Oxford Economic Papers, 62(2), 234–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Mündler, M.-A. (2008). The effect of FDI on job security. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 8(1), article 8.

  • Bender, S., & Von Wachter, T. (2006). In the right place at the wrong time: The role of firms and luck in young workers’ careers. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1679–1705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A., Jensen, J., Redding, S., & Schott, P. (2007). Firms in international trade. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 105–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. (2006). Offshoring: The next industrial revolution. Foreign Affairs, 85(2), 113–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B. A., & Wang, M. G. (2005). Inappropriate pooling of wealthy and poor countries in empirical FDI studies. In T. H. Moran, E. M. Graham, & M. Blomstrom (Eds.), Does foreign direct investment promote development? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, Center for Global Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Costa Dias, M. (2002). Alternative approaches to evaluation in empirical microeconomics. (IFS CEMMAP Working Papers CWP10/02). London: Institute for Fiscal Studies.

  • Blundell, R., Costa Dias, M., Meghir, C., & Van Reenen, J. (2004). Evaluating the employment impact of a mandatory job search program. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(4), 569–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Dearden, L., & Sianesi, B. (2005). Evaluating the effect of education on earnings: Models, methods and results from the National Child Development Survey. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A, 168(3), 473–512.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clerides, S. K., Lach, S., & Tybout, J. R. (1998). Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Columbia, Mexico, and Morocco. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 903–948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crinò, R. (2010). Service offshoring and white-collar employment. Review of Economic Studies, 77(2), 595–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debaere, P., Lee, H., & Lee, J. (2010). Does where you go matter? The impact of outward foreign direct investment on multinationals’ employment at home. Journal of Development Economics, 91(2), 301–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, P., & Pfaffermayr, M. (2003). The counterfactual to investing abroad: An endogenous treatment approach of foreign affiliate activity. (Working Paper 2003/02). University of Innsbruck.

  • Ekholm, K., & Hakkala, K. (2005). The effect of offshoring on labor demand: Evidence from Sweden. (Research Institute of Industrial Economics Working Paper 654). Stockholm: IUI.

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francois, J., & Hoekman, B. (2010). ‘Services trade and policy. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(3), 642–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma, S., & Görg, H. (2007). Evaluating the foreign ownership wage premium using a difference-in-differences matching approach. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 97–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma, S., Greenaway, D., & Kneller, R. (2004). Does exporting lead to better performance: A microeconometric analysis of matched firms. Review of International Economics, 12(5), 855–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, J. (1998). On the role of the propensity score in efficient semiparametric estimation of average treatment effects. Econometrica, 66, 315–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, A. E., McMillan, M. S., & Null, C. (2007). U.S. multinational activity abroad and U.S. Jobs: Substitutes or complements? Industrial Relations, 46(19), 347–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Head, K., & Ries, J. (2002). Offshore production and skill upgrading by Japanese manufacturing firms. Journal of International Economics, 58(1), 81–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., Ichimura, H., & Todd, P. (1997). Matching as an econometric estimator: Evidence from evaluating a job training programme. Review of Economic Studies, 64(4), 605–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Yeaple, S. (2004). Exports versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Görg, H., & Hine, R. C. (2005). International outsourcing and the skill structure of labor demand in the United Kingdom. Economic Journal, 115(506), 860–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Inui, T., & Todo, Y. (2007). The effects of multinational production on domestic performance: Evidence from Japanese firms. (RIETI Discussion Paper 07006). Tokyo: RIETI.

  • Jacobson, L. S., LaLonde, R. L., & Sullivan, D. G. (1993). Earnings losses of displaced workers. American Economic Review, 83(4), 685–709.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinert, J., & Toubal F. (2007). The impact of locating production abroad on activities at home: Evidence from German firm-level data. (Discussion Paper 314). University of Tubingen.

  • Klette, T. J. (1999). Market power, economies of scale and productivity: Estimates from a panel of establishment data. Journal of Industrial Economics, 47, 451–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad, I., & Villanger, E. (2008). Determinants of foreign direct investment in services. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(2), 518–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechner, M. (2001). Identification and estimation of causal effects of multiple treatments under the conditional independence assumption. In M. Lechner & F. Pfeiffer (Eds.), Econometric evaluation of labour market policies (pp. 43–58). Heidelberg: Physica.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Swagel, P. (2006). The politics and economics of offshore outsourcing. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(5), 1027–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R. (1984). Multinationals, multi-plant economies, and the gains from trade. Journal of International Economics, 16(3–4), 205–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R., & Maskus, K. E. (2001). General-equilibrium approaches to the multinational firm: A review of theory and evidence. (NBER Working Paper 8334). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Mélitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munch, J. R., & Skaksen, J. R. (2009). Specialisation, outsourcing, and wages. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 145(1), 57–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mündler, M.-A., & Becker, S. O. (2010). Margins of multinational labor substitution. American Economic Review, 100(5), 1999–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, P., & Rubin, D. (1983). The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika, 70, 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum, P., & Rubin, D. (1985). Constructing a control group using multivariate matched sampling methods that incorporate the propensity score. The American Statistician, 39(1), 33–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sianesi, B. (2004). An evaluation of the Swedish system of active labor market programs in the 1990 s. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(1), 133–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, M. J. (2000). Production transfer within multinational enterprises and american wages. Journal of International Economics, 50(2), 449–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeaple, S. (2003). The complex integration strategies of multinational firms and cross-country dependencies in the structure of foreign direct investment. Journal of International Economics, 60(2), 293–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We like to thank Richard Upward for very helpful comments and suggestions on an earlier draft as well as an anonymous referee and participants of the ISIT Conference in Stockholm, the COMPPRESS workshop in Budapest and seminar participants in Nottingham and Paris. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the OECD or its member states. All remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sébastien Jean.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Measuring TFP

In order to measure TFP we apply the mean value theorem as suggested by Klette (1999). In practice this means that we transform the data in differences from the industry median within each year. There are two advantages to this transformation: (i) it increases the flexibility to deal with firm heterogeneity within the industry; (ii) it removes the need to use industry-level price deflators which are difficult to obtain for services. After transforming the data we estimate TFP as the residual of a Cobb–Douglas production function of capital, labour and materials. The production function controls for the possible correlation between input-choice and time-invariant productivity shocks by including individual-specific fixed effects.

1.2 Data management

In order to follow individual firms through time we organise the data around cohorts. Cohorts are defined as 6-year windows around year t [t − 2;  t + 3] in which domestic firms establish a foreign presence. We impose the condition that within a 6-year window the panel should be balanced. After having defined the cohorts we stack them together in order to create a ‘panel of cohorts’ running from 1988–1998 for manufacturing. Bender and Von Wachter (2006) observe that this effectively gives a system of seemingly unrelated regressions with cross-equation restrictions.

Appendix 2: Additional results

See Tables 3, 4, 5, and 6 and Fig. 6.

Table 3 Breakdown of matched firm pairs by sector
Table 4 Balancing tests for multiple treatment matching
Table 5 Semi-parametric estimates of the impact of FDI on employment
Table 6 Semi-parametric estimates of the impact of FDI on TFP
Fig. 6
figure 6

Impact of foreign investment on skill-intensity, by income level of the recipient country and by sector. Notes: As in Fig. 2. Average labour skill is measured as the average yearly wage in the firm

About this article

Cite this article

Hijzen, A., Jean, S. & Mayer, T. The effects at home of initiating production abroad: evidence from matched French firms. Rev World Econ 147, 457–483 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0094-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0094-x

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation