Introduction

“How we can restore trust in financial institutions,” “Rock-bottom—that’s where trust in financial services is,” “Barclays boss admits it could take 10 years to rebuild public trust,” and “Banks must ‘raise their game’ to win back public trust’ (respectively Brown 2009; Hargreaves 2007; Monaghan 2013; Trotman 2015). These are just a few news headlines from recent years. The decrease in consumer trustFootnote 1 in the financial sector and the attempts to restore it are receiving a great deal of interest, especially since the financial crisis in late 2008.Footnote 2 EU legislation is one of the ways in which attempts are being made to regain the trust of investors. The focus in this article is on retail investors (consumers) on the market for investment productsFootnote 3; however, considerable parts also apply to the financial market as a whole. It is also worth mentioning that this article will not go into much detail on the role of trust in the 2008 financial crisis because this has already been discussed a lot in the literature (see, e.g., Georgarakos and Pasini 2011; Sapienza and Zingales 2012, p. 723; Zingales 2011; and on the role of information, contracts, and regulation in the 2008 financial crisis: Diamond and Dybvig 1983; Tonkiss 2009).

In the second section, the concept of “trust” will be subjected to an in-depth yet not exhaustive examination, with the aim of reducing its elusiveness. The third section will discuss three recent EU proposals. Examination of these legislative proposals reveals that (1) the term ‘trust’ is not precisely defined, and (2) without stating further reasons, the restoration of trust in the financial sector is considered to be a worthy goal. In light of the above, the fourth section will address the desirability of clarity regarding the term “trust.” Next, the fifth section will assess whether legislation is a suitable means when it comes to restoring consumer trust. However, whether the content of the proposed regulation (e.g., information duties or the remedies available to an investor against breaches of standards of conduct by the provider in contract or tort law) is likely to be effective in restoring trust, falls outside the scope of this article, since this is discussed by others (see, e.g., Guiso 2010; Springford 2011) and is an almost impossible question to answer based on literature because it depends greatly on the specific circumstances and future developments. Finally, the sixth section explores whether the restoration of consumer trust in the financial sector is a worthy goal. Indeed, the European legislator and other policymakers seem to consider a low level of consumer trust as a bad thing, a high level of consumer trust as a good thing, and a higher level of consumer trust an even better thing.Footnote 4 This article will argue that it is doubtful whether EU legislation is a suitable means for restoring consumer trust in the financial sector and, moreover, that considering the perverse incentives in the current financial sector, among other things, a realistic degree of trust, implying a certain distrust, appears to be more desirable.

The Concept of “Trust”

In a now well-known metaphor, the philosopher Baier illustrated the elusiveness of trust by comparing it to clean air (Baier 1986, p. 234). We live in a trust-filled environment the same way that we live in an environment with clean air. Only when it gets difficult for us to breathe and the air is polluted do we notice that we are breathing air. The same goes for trust: we only become aware of it if it is under pressure or if it is not there. In the following, an attempt will be made somewhat to reduce the elusiveness of the concept of trust. It must be noted, however, that this will not include a full summary or the formulation of a definition of trust.Footnote 5

Researchers of various branches of science have paid a great deal of attention to trust, resulting in a kaleidoscopic image (Nooteboom 2002b, p. 19): the perspective from which the concept is viewed determines what is seen.Footnote 6 Economists view trust mainly as the lubricating oil of the financial market, in the sense that it helps achieve economic goals, reduce transaction costs, and increase efficiency (Knack 2001; Knack and Keefer 1997, pp. 1251–1252; Temple and Johnson 1998, pp. 987–988; Zak and Knack 2001, pp. 295–296).Footnote 7 According to social psychologists, trust is rather a sense of goodwill toward others, which is important for many things, including cooperation.Footnote 8 In contrast, sociologists and political scientists consider trust to be the basis for social capital.Footnote 9 As for the mechanisms behind trust, neurologists study the connections in our brains and emphasize that feelings and behaviour related to trust can be learned, while biologists claim that trust is determined, for instance, by hormones and the environment in which people grow up.Footnote 10

Four Elements

In spite of the wide diversity of definitions and insights,Footnote 11 it is generally assumed that trust consists of four elements, which are connected in the following way: I trust you regarding x in certain circumstances. Thus there is, first, a subject that trusts (“I”), which in principle, is a person (Liebsch 2010, p. 185). Many authors point out that some people are more trusting than others (Berg et al. 1995; Evans and Krueger 2009, pp. 1010–1011). These differences are in part predicted (and perhaps caused) by an underlying propensity to trust (Evans and Krueger 2009; Rotter 1967). As mentioned earlier, the focus in this article is on consumers on the market for investment products.

Second, the subject trusts something (you), being the object of trust. Among other things, this could be a person, organization, system, or thing (Nooteboom 2002a, p. 8).Footnote 12 There can be multiple levels of trust (e.g., Nooteboom 2002a, pp. 54–61). Indeed, on the financial market, there are at least three levels of trust: the financial market as a whole, financial institutions (such as banks), and people working at those financial institutions. Accordingly, buying an investment product requires trust in the functioning of the financial markets, in the financial institution offering the product, and in the people working in these institutions. Trust in these objects is closely interrelated. For example, whether a banker can fulfil his or her commitments depends on the interests of the financial institution and common practices within the organization. Furthermore, his or her behaviour will be influenced by incentives on the financial markets (see in more detail “Trust as a Goal of Legislation”). Conversely, trust in financial institutions is influenced by trust in the people working in those particular institutions. The multiple levels of trust can also be illustrated by the financial crisis in 2008. This crisis has caused distrust of bankers (persons) because of greed for money and acting in their own interests instead of acting in their clients’ best interests. This behaviour was and still is caused by perverse incentives within financial institutions and the financial markets, such as a strong preference for short-term profit, neglecting risks in the long run. Since trust in these objects is closely interrelated, they will be all taken into account in this article and could not always be clearly separated.

Third, we have trust in, for instance, the competence or intention of the object (“x”) (Prast et al. 2005, p. 25).Footnote 13 This is a very relevant factor because the actions of the object of trust and the outcomes of these actions entail a number of other causes, which could be referred to as “multiple causality” (Nooteboom 2002a, p. 50). One of the causes is the competence a person needs to achieve an expected level of performance, such as abilities, skills, and knowledge. Furthermore, the person also needs to trust the materials used by the object, the aims of the object, his or her intentions, dedication, care, benevolence, goodwill, and truthfulness (Nooteboom 2002a, pp. 50–54). The distinction between these causes (which are in fact also objects of trust) are important, because it could clarify why people should or should not trust an object, and it could help in deciding which (policy) response is the most appropriate. For example, a lack of competence could be improved by training. If opportunism is the problem, we may consider penalties, replacement, or an appeal to ethical behaviour.

Lastly, the level of trust depends on the circumstances and the context (“circumstances”) (Nooteboom 2010, p. 27). As mentioned earlier, how much someone trusts a banker is partly determined by how much this person trusts banks and the financial sector as a whole, and circumstances can lead to someone being trusted experiencing incentives to be opportunistic.Footnote 14 For example, in an environment where money plays an important role, people tend to be more self-focused and less likely to help others (Vohs et al. 2006). This is in line with Heymann and Ariely (2004) who note that whereas monetary markets encourage quid pro quo behaviour, social markets inspire less calculated acts of reciprocity.

Trust and Reliability

It is important to distinguish between trusting someone and relying on someone (Liebsch 2010, p. 177; Nooteboom 2010, p. 28). Indeed, you can rely on someone without trusting that person, a distinction which can be illustrated with the following example (Nooteboom 2010, p. 28). When a consumer takes out an insurance policy, he or she places his or her reliance in the insurance agent. This, however, does not imply that the insurance agent is actually trusted. In other words, one can rely on someone without trusting that person. In fact, there can be good reasons for expecting this insurance agent to behave predictably and consistently (i.e., to rely on this insurance agent), but naturally this is not indicative of whether he is worthy of this reliance and can therefore be trusted. It must be added that the distinction between reliance and trust is not a clear-cut one. After all, how much someone relies on someone else will affect the level of trust he or she is willing to put in this person. This further shows that trust is not an all-or-nothing concept, but that it can be present to a greater or lesser degree (Nooteboom, p. 27).

According to Casson and Giusta (2006, p. 346), reliability or trustworthiness is an objective characteristic of an individual in a given type of situation, but it cannot be directly observed. Glaeser et al. (2000) conclude from the experiments they conducted that social connection strongly predicts trustworthiness (or in other words, whether someone is reliable) but weakly predicts trust. In particular, the study concludes that national and racial differences between partners strongly predict a tendency to cheat one another. The latter is especially relevant given the diversity in the European Union, for which the new financial legislation will come into force (see Restoring Trust by Means of EU Legislation section).

Trust and Risk

Related to this is another characteristic of trust, i.e., the uncertainty it entails: trust only exists where there is also a risk of it being betrayed (Ben-Ner and Putterman 2001, p. 530; Liebsch 2010, p. 177). It is after all related to the (future) behaviour of another party and can therefore be seen as a fictional security while there is insecurity (Gärling et al., p. 30; Peperzak 2013, p. 18)Footnote 15; or, formulated more concretely, trust transforms insecurity into risk (Luhmann 1979, p. 22). This is clearly reflected in the way Sobel defines trust, being a person’s willingness to let his or her own well-being be determined by another person’s decisions (Sobel 2002, p. 148). The more uncertainty there is, the more trust is required, but trust does not lead to a reduction in uncertainty, but rather to a greater acceptance of it (Sobel 2002, p. 148). Trust can thus at least partly act as compensation for a sense of uncertainty.

Empirical evidence, however, is mixed about the relationship between trust and risk. Fehr (2009) argues that trust is not a form of risk-taking, but based on important forms of social preferences such as betrayal aversion. Eckel and Wilson (2004) conclude that they found no statistical relationship between people’s attitudes to risk and the decision to trust. All in all, the relationship between trust and risk or uncertainty is very complicated (for a more detailed exploration of this subject, see Nooteboom 2006, pp. 38–41). At the very least, trust entails some risk or uncertainty since we can never be completely certain about another’s behaviour.

The Importance of Trust

The above could give rise to the question: Why do people trust when it involves such risk? In this context, the so-called value of trust is relevant. Trust can have both extrinsic and intrinsic value (Nooteboom 2006, pp. 252–253; Nooteboom 2002a, pp. 2–5) for a person.Footnote 16

As an intrinsic value, trust can enhance the quality of our lives. For example, people reporting that they live in a trustworthy environment experience a greater sense of well-being (Helliwell and Wang 2010, p. 21). Trust has extrinsic value in that it can help us achieve social and economic goals. For example, financial products offer consumers the opportunity to do things they otherwise may be could not do, such as purchase a house.

Related to this, an important reason to trust more generally seems to be that it is often connected to the expectation of something positive or important for the one placing trust in the other party.Footnote 17 The unpredictable behaviour of the other can lead to one of two results: a positive one or a negative one.Footnote 18 If the trust was justified, a transaction could result in a higher yield than if no transaction had been involved (a positive result). However, if the trust is betrayed, the loss is often greater than the yield gained had the trust been justified (a negative result). Imagine a banker offering a consumer a financial product, with the promise of a 10% yield on his investment.Footnote 19 If the consumer places his or her trust in the banker and invests EUR 1000 in the financial product in question, this should yield a financial profit of EUR 100. However, if the banker turns out to be untrustworthy, the consumer could then lose the entire investment (EUR 1000). As Liebsch (2010, p. 189) powerfully summarizes: “It is, to be sure, a one-sided, asymmetric ‘investment,’ which makes, as such, no ‘economic’ sense.”

From a societal point of view (which could be categorized as the “extrinsic value of trust”), trust is relevant for the effective functioning of the economy. According to Arrow (1972, p. 357), virtually every commercial transaction has within it an element of trust. Several studies reveal a positive relationship between trust and economic performance or point out, conversely, that a lack of trust can have various drawbacks (e.g., Knack 2001; Knack and Keefer 1997, pp. 1251–1251; Temple and Johnson 1998, pp. 987–988; Zak and Knack 2001, pp. 295). Before providing a brief overview of the relationship between trust and economic outcomes documented in the existing literature, it must be noted that there are also concerns about the causal role of trust in economic (and social) transactions (Fehr 2009). Fehr (2009) argues, for example, that the identification of the exact role of trust in economic transactions has proven elusive. Other studies also dispute the positive link between trust and economic growth, for example Beugelsdijk and Schaik (2003) and Helliwell (1996).

Despite these concerns, most studies have shown that trust is an essential element for an economy to work. Using data from the World Values Survey for 29 market economies, Knack and Keefer (1997) conclude that trust positively correlates with economic performance because an increase of 1 standard deviation in country-level trust predicts an increase in Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of more than one half of a standard deviation. Approximately 10 years later, Dincer and Uslaner (2010) arrived at the same conclusion, i.e., that trust is related to higher GDP. Others highlight the importance of trust in the asset management industry, such as the relationship between investors and portfolio managers (Kostovetsky 2016). In addition, Guiso et al. (2004) show that Italian households invest higher amounts in financial assets when they live in regions with high trust rates. In instrumental terms, the resources of trust promote economic efficiency by reducing the transaction costs of economic exchange, on the assumption that others will behave according to common norms of economic conduct (Tonkiss 2009, p. 196). Finally, Knack (2001) provides arguments and evidence for the importance of high trust in the economic performance of nations.

From an economic point of view, a lack of trust could have negative consequences. Low confidence can turn into a self-fulfilling prophecy which causes an economic recession and puts currencies and payments at risk, for example leading to hyperinflation (Katona 1975). Furthermore, it turned out that low trust environments reduce the rate of (stock) investment (Guiso et al. 2008, p. 2557; Zak and Knack 2001, p. 295).Footnote 20 However, the contribution of trust to stockholding seems to vary across different groups of households (Georgarakos and Pasini 2011).

Low levels of trust have also been studied since the financial crisis of 2008. For example, Zingales (2011) found that investors who plan to decrease their stock investments after the financial crisis are those who have less trust in financial markets and especially in the stock market. He also points out that trust can have important economic effects through additional channels. First, lack of trust affects the ability to experiment and learn. Second, a trusting attitude is self-fulfilling: the more we trust our partners, the more they behave in a trustworthy way and vice versa. Finally, trust can have important economic effects in a situation where multiple equilibria are possible and where the subjective component of trust can determine which equilibrium is selected.

Sources of Trust and Reliability

Regardless of the fact that, depending on circumstances, there are reasons to betray trust, in general there are various incentives encouraging someone not to do so.

At a macro (institutional) level, contracts, legal compulsion, incentives such as reputation, value, standards of good behaviour, sense of duty, and ties of kinship play a role (Nooteboom 2002a, pp. 63–66).Footnote 21 At a micro (relational) level, the following reasons lead people to act reliably: hierarchy, administrative approval, incentives such as dependency, bonuses, empathy, identification, shared norms and values, habit, feelings, and friendship (Nooteboom 2002a, pp. 63–66).Footnote 22 Thus, in summary, there are two instruments for promoting reliability: compulsion (such as legal compulsion or supervision) and incentives (such as reputation).Footnote 23 In addition, norms, values, and empathy can be viewed as causes of reliability.

Two Sources of Trust and Reliability: Contracts and Regulation

As mentioned in the previous subsection, contracts and regulation could be incentives for improving trust and reliability. Since this article focuses on improving trust by means of EU legislation, it is worth providing a brief overview of the existing literature on the role of contracts and regulation in improving trust.

Many scholars in sociology of law are sceptical about the role the legal system can play in supporting trust (Deakin 2006, p. 218). A widely held view in this field is that legal rules and sanctions are marginal to contractual relations. This opinion is based on empirical studies interpreted as showing that parties to business transactions rely mostly on informal norms and “trust” instead of contract law or formal agreements (Beale and Dugdale 1975; Collins 2002: ch. 6; Macaulay 1963).

Against this, many authors see contracts and law as important “mechanisms” for improving trust and trustworthiness (Prast et al. 2005, p. 26). First, regulation or entering into a contract can be a substitute for trust in the sense that it reduces the amount of trust needed (Nooteboom 2006, pp. 257–258; Simpson and Eriksson 2009, p. 63; Tonkiss 2009). In contrast, contracts and trust are constitutive (Nooteboom 2006, pp. 257–258). Some examples can illustrate this. First, because interactions typically cannot foresee all possible contingencies, most contracts are incomplete and as a result difficult to enforce (Bohnet et al. 2001; Engle-Warnick and Slonim 2004). Furthermore, there is a risk in accepting the contract due to incomplete information about, e.g., the seller, which requires trust and may partly be reduced by reputation (Göran and Hägg 1994). In addition, when the trustee fails to fulfil its obligations, the state could support trust and trustworthy behaviour through regulatory legislation (e.g., to cover losses) and supervision. Of course, this presupposes that the state, financial and other supervisors, and the legal system have earned a reputation as trustworthy in the eyes of citizens (Göran and Hägg 1994, p. 447).

Many studies suggest that contracts and regulation are positively related to trust and trustworthiness. Knack and Keefer (1997) and Zak and Knack (2001) present cross-country evidence showing that governmental mechanisms for the effective enforcement of contracts are associated with greater trust. However, it must be noted that the causality of this link could be questioned because causality can easily go in both directions in such relationships (Knack 2001, p. 4). Malhotra and Murnighan (2002) show that in a trust game, trustees send more to their “counterpart” when the trustor agreed to a non-binding contract. Furthermore, the legal system generates incentives for parties to uphold contracts in the form of fines and recognisances and is therefore an important mechanism to reduce transaction risks.

On the other hand, contracts and regulation could also have some drawbacks. As regards contracts, it should first be noted that incomplete information and low financial literacy lead to incomplete and poorly understood contracts (Mosch and Prast 2008, pp. 22–23). This happened during the 2008 collapse of the subprime mortgage market in the USA and elsewhere. For a contract to be effective, it is important that its content is well understood by both parties and based on relevant information (which was often not the case in the subprime mortgage market: Tonkiss 2009, p. 199). Furthermore, it seems that contracts can injure the intrinsic motivators of trust and trustworthiness (Bohnet et al. 2001; Fehr and Rockenbach 2003; Malhotra and Murnighan 2002; Mulder et al. 2006; Simpson and Eriksson 2009). The study of Ben-Ner and Putterman (2009) is also relevant in this context. They studied a one-shot trust game with the opportunities to engage in pre-play communication and to enter binding and non-binding contracts. They found that contracts are largely unnecessary for trusting and trustworthy behaviours and were eschewed by many players. Moreover, legal procedures for enforcing contracts tend to be expensive.

Similarly, regulation is not always positively related to trust and trustworthy behaviour. Evidence from cross-country correlations shows that countries with stronger regulation have lower average levels of trust instead of higher (Aghion et al. 2009; Carlin et al. 2009; Pinotti 2008). This is in line with Guiso (2010, pp. 14–15), who clarifies that the proportion of people supporting more stringent regulation is higher among those whose trust fell during the crisis than among those who continue to trust banks and financial markets. Government regulation seems also strongly negatively related to social capital (Aghion et al. 2009). In this context, Carlin et al. (2009) distinguish between valuable and less valuable social capital in their attempt to analyse the optimal level of regulation. They conclude that where social capital is valuable, regulation and trustfulness are substitutes. In this situation, regulation can cause lower aggregate investment and decreased economic growth. However, when social capital is less valuable, regulation and trustfulness may be complements.

Causal Ambiguity

Trust is often accompanied by causal ambiguity, meaning that it is often hard to determine what exactly caused the failure to achieve a certain result.Footnote 24 For instance, if a consumer has invested money in a complex financial product which, in the end, yields a lower profit than expected, this could then be caused by many things, such as an error or circumstance that nobody could prevent, the people investing the money being incompetent or opportunistic, a lack of research into the product by the investor, incorrect or incomplete information from the financial advisor, conjunctural developments, a lack of competence on the part of the advisor who recommended the product, etc.Footnote 25 The specific characteristics of the financial sector, which “Trust in the Financial Sector: Legislation as a Means” and “Trust as a Goal of Legislation” sections will consider more closely, entail a great degree of causal ambiguity for investors. However, the next section is about the attempts of the EU legislator to restore consumer trust in the financial markets.

Restoring Trust by Means of EU Legislation

Legally, the financial crisis started two movements: one in the area of litigation and the other in the area of legislation.Footnote 26 In the area of litigation, compensation is claimed for people who suffered losses due to risky financial products and fraud. Well-known examples include the Bernard Madoff Lawsuit in the USA and numerous scandals concerning profiteering policies and margin lending.Footnote 27 At the same time, in the area of legislation, various attempts are being made to prevent the recurrence of such situations in the future and to restore the trust that was lost. In this context, three EU legislative proposals will be discussed successively: the introduction of a new pre-contractual information document for complex financial products,Footnote 28 MiFID II (MiFID stands for Markets in Financial Instruments Directive),Footnote 29 and the Mortgage Credit Directive.Footnote 30 These European legislative proposals are for illustrative purposes only, since this article does not provide enough room for a detailed examination of the likely effectiveness in increasing trust in them.

The first example is a Regulation stating that, as of December 2016, providers of complex financial productsFootnote 31 must provide consumers with a short information document—a Key Information Document—in the pre-contractual phase.Footnote 32 This document should include information regarding the costs and risks associated with a financial product.Footnote 33 The Regulation is part of a larger legislative package aiming to restore consumer trust in the financial sector.Footnote 34

In the explanatory memorandum to the proposal, it is established that retail investors have lost money on investments in which the risks were unclear or difficult to understand. Next, it concludesFootnote 35:

This is in a context where investor confidence has collapsed: a recent survey of consumers across the EUFootnote 36 showed they trust the financial services less than all other industry sectors. Rebuilding confidence on a sound basis is vital. Improving provisions on transparency so that they work in favour or retail investors, taking into account their needs is a vital component of this.

A second DirectiveFootnote 37 and RegulationFootnote 38 serving to increase consumers trust in the financial sector is MiFID II. The financial crisis brought to light that the first MiFID DirectiveFootnote 39 had various shortcomings with regard to the operation and transparency of the financial markets.Footnote 40 The aims of the new legislative package are to (a) strengthen the supervisory and regulatory framework for markets in financial instruments in order to promote transparency, protection of investors, and trust and (b) improve the functioning of the internal market in financial instruments.Footnote 41 This should be achieved by measures including new and more stringent rules of conduct for investment firms, transparency requirements concerning stock market trading, a more stringent sanctions regime, and a more extensive set of instruments for regulatory authorities to work with.

As a final example, reference is made to the Mortgage Credit Directive, which can be viewed as a reaction to the problems on the home loan market.Footnote 42 In fact, in the last few years consumers increasingly appear to encounter problems when it comes to paying off their mortgages. To illustrate: in the period from 1 October 2012 to 1 April 2015, the number of consumers with mortgage arrears in the Netherlands increased by more than 40,000 (BKR 2014, 2015).Footnote 43 In this context, irresponsible lending and borrowing practices are regarded as an important factor leading to the credit crunch, since they caused consumers to lose faith in the financial sector.Footnote 44 One of the aims of the Mortgage Credit Directive is therefore to bring about an efficient and competitive single marketFootnote 45 with a high degree of protection for the consumer by increasing consumer trust, among other things.Footnote 46 To achieve this, lenders and credit intermediaries should adhere to a certain code of conduct when lending to consumers (art. 7) as well as meeting a number of minimum competence requirements (art. 9).

The various proposals all appear to be based upon one and the same argument. First, it has been established that the credit crunch brought to light certain problems regarding the financial sector. These problems, including a lack of transparency, have caused consumers to suffer damages and lose trust in the financial sector.Footnote 47 Since trust in the financial sector is deemed desirable, legislation was used in order to restore it. Strikingly, in some proposals, such as the Mortgage Credit Directive, consumer trust is actually used as a means to achieve another goal, an efficient single market.Footnote 48

What exactly the European legislator means by (consumer) trust is not explained in the proposals. Therefore, in addition to providing some reflections on this, the next section will argue that, within this context, some clarification regarding the term “trust” is desirable.

Trust: the Importance of a Closer Look

As “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section already pointed out, the concept of trust is hard to define. There is no uniform definition, and every area of science perceives it differently.Footnote 49 Partly as a result of this, there are many misunderstandings surrounding the concept of trust (Fehr 2009; Glaeser et al. 2000, p. 815; Nooteboom 2002a, p. 1). However, it is in fact because of its versatility that exploration of this concept is recommended, since ambiguity regarding the meaning of trust (1) renders much empirical research, research to which the European Commission also refers unusable; and (2) leads to trust as the goal of legislation being a malleable concept and therefore not very meaningful. Both points will be addressed below.

Unusable Research

Nooteboom and others point out that confusion surrounding the concept of trust has rendered much empirical research useless,Footnote 50 since its various distinctions and misunderstandings receive insufficient attention (Nooteboom 2010, p. 29; Nooteboom 2006, pp. 247–248; Fehr 2009; Glaeser et al. 2000, p. 815).Footnote 51 In relation to this, Nooteboom (2010, p. 29) wonders: “If we have confidence in the police, does this mean that they are good at catching thieves or that they aren’t corrupt?”Footnote 52 Confusion about the meaning of “trust” can cause problems for researchers, for instance when they need to draw conclusions on the basis of research results. Besides, if participants are asked as part of a study how much trust they have in a certain financial institution, then they will interpret the term “trust” in different ways according to their character, experience, the way the question is formulated, and their mood (Glaeser et al. 2000, p. 815; Nooteboom 2010, p. 29). Moreover, if one study is based on a broad interpretation of the concept of trust, conclusions about “consumer trust being high” can be much more easily drawn than in another study based upon a more narrow definition of trust. Finally, an increase or decrease in consumer trust as compared to the results of research conducted for instance a year before is in practice not always an increase or decrease when the concept of trust is surrounded by confusion or when different definitions are used.

Therefore, when the European Commission writes that an EU-wide consumer survey shows that consumers put a lower degree of trust in financial services than in other industry sectors, this appears to be rather uninformative, in light of the aforementioned.Footnote 53 Moreover, the fact that the European Commission does not refer to the location of the results of this survey makes it impossible to determine how it was conducted and which definition of confidence it is based upon.Footnote 54

A Rather Meaningless Goal

In addition to the above, the pursuit of consumer trust as a goal (or means) of EU legislation is rather meaningless if the concept of (consumer) trust is not clearly defined, thus giving rise to the question: “Trust in what way?”Footnote 55 As the following will demonstrate, trust is a comprehensive concept which can be perceived in different ways, and uncertainty surrounding it can make evaluation of legislation aiming to restore it problematic. After all, even if there is a correlation between the requirements needing to be met under this legislation and consumer trust, then this does not necessarily mean that a causal link can be presumed. Therefore, when it comes to the evaluation of an act, how the concept of trust is operationalized will determine whether a guideline is successful. As a result of this “malleability,” trust as a goal of legislation has little meaning. The aforementioned demonstrates the importance of a sound policy theory: the explicit or implicit assumptions underlying policy.Footnote 56 Such a policy theory can be helpful to a policy researcher designing or evaluating policy (Hoogerwerf 1990, p. 285). Although a good policy theory evidently is no guarantee for a successful policy, it does increase the chances of it having the desired effects (Hoogerwerf 1990, p. 285). Unfortunately, the policy theory behind the EU proposals mentioned above is very weak, meaning that, at the very least, its effectiveness can be doubted.

Trust in the Financial Sector: Legislation as a Means

The EU uses legislation in order to restore consumer trust in the financial sector.Footnote 57 It is, however, questionable whether such measures will have the desired effect, since “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section shows that their proliferation could in fact be viewed as proof that trust in the financial sector is currently at a low level, given that it is the people who do not trust financial institutions who seem to be asking for more stringent regulations.Footnote 58

According to Robert Reich (2008), an American economist and former United States Secretary of Labor, legislation is a suitable means for restoring trust in the financial sector: “If what’s lacking is trust rather than capital, the most important steps policy-makers can take would be to rebuild trust. And the best way to do that is through regulations that require financial players to stand behind their promises and tell the truth, along with strict oversight to make sure they do.” A standpoint that is easy to defend, it appears, since regulations which ultimately lead to protection of investors can at least potentially contribute to the regaining of trust.

Reich’s view is supported by several studies described in “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section which are clear that regulation could be an incentive for improving trust and reliability (e.g., Prast et al. 2005, p. 26). In fact, the legal system generates incentives for parties to uphold contracts through fines and recognisances, for instance. In this sense, a properly functioning legal system is an important mechanism to reduce transaction risks.

Nevertheless, “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section also points out that regulation could have some drawbacks. For example, legal procedures tend to be expensive. Therefore, transaction costs are minimized when economic business is done under an implicit rather than an explicit contract, without complicated legal forms to govern each agreement (e.g., Prast et al. 2005, pp. 26–27; Tonkiss 2009, pp. 196–197, and Ben-Ner and Putterman 2009 who provided laboratory evidence for this). In addition, many scholars seem to be sceptical about the role which the legal system can play in supporting trust and argue that parties mostly rely on informal norms instead of governmental regulation (Beale and Dugdale 1975; Collins 2002: ch. 6; Deakin 2006, p. 218; Macaulay 1963). Furthermore, research provides some evidence that countries with stronger regulation have lower average levels of trust (Aghion et al. 2009; Carlin et al. 2009; Guiso 2010; Pinotti 2008).

In sum, the existing literature is unclear about the exact role of regulation in improving trust and trustworthiness. However, based on the specific characteristics of the financial market, it is possible to approach this subject in another way and to provide arguments for the likely effectiveness of legislation as a means for improving consumer trust in the financial market. This will be done in the following subsections.

Distance Between Legislator and Financial Sector

First, in order to draft such legislation, there needs to be sufficient distance between the legislator and the financial sector (Tonkiss 2009, p. 201). However, when the legislation applies to banks that are “too big to fail,” then this distance might be too small, since their going bankrupt or relocating could have disastrous economic consequences for a country. Here, two (public) interests appear to collide: (1) the promotion of a smooth functioning of the financial sector by means of legislation,Footnote 59 and (2) the risk of a financial institution deeming this legislation undesirable to such a degree that it locates elsewhere, with negative consequences for the national economy.Footnote 60 The lobbying power of the financial sector can be viewed as an indication of the distance between the legislator and the financial sector not being optimal. On 17 January 2015, in a letter to the editor, the Dutch Secretary of Finance Jeroen Dijsselbloem (2015) stated that the financial sector is trying to evade anti-crisis measures needed for a lasting recovery of the Dutch economy by using far-fetched and factually inaccurate arguments. He further wrote about an “enormous lobby” and “massive resistance” against, inter alia, capital adequacy requirements for banks and new solvency requirements for insurers.

Legislation as a Determinant of Trust: One of Many, Not One in a Thousand

The literature has addressed the question of how trust in a financial institution comes about and how, if needed, it can be restored, albeit in a limited way (Van der Cruijsen et al. 2013, p. 2).Footnote 61 Seven determinants of trust in financial service providers regularly emerge in varying orders of importanceFootnote 62: competence, stability, integrity, good intentions and customer focus, transparency, value congruence, and reputation. According to Van Raaij, legislation is a means for enforcing integrity (Van Raaij 2009).Footnote 63 However, regardless of the fact that consumers deem integrity important, according to Van Raaij they often experience it as being cool, bureaucratic, and formal.Footnote 64 In addition, legislation can reinforce the other determinants. For instance, minimum competence requirements for lenders and credit intermediaries can lead to a better understanding of financial products as well as customers and their needs (competence), and the provision of a short information document about a financial product may increase transparency.Footnote 65 On the other hand, from empirical researchFootnote 66, it can be gathered that high bonuses are the main reason why people have lost their trust in banks (Jansen et al. 2015).Footnote 67 The question therefore remains whether the new legislation can counterbalance news items about, for instance, generous pay rises for board members of banks as compensation for the ban on bonuses (Deutsch and Neely 2014; Wallace 2015).

Limited Effectiveness

The Guidelines and Regulations include regulations imposed on the financial sector by external sources which therefore may meet with resistance from financial institutions. In connection to this, sometimes it is claimed that the undesirability of the costs that come with such measures could overshadow their potential benefits (Guiso 2010, p. 15). For financial institutions, this could be an incentive to evade the regulations resulting from this legislation to the greatest extent possible (Guiso 2010, p. 15). Or, in the words of a former banker: “No matter what rules you put in place, they’ll always find ways around them.” (Luyendijk 2015, p. 169).Footnote 68 Naturally, the fact that rules are not always observed by everyone is not an argument against rules, such as the described EU legislation.Footnote 69 The expected effectiveness of such legislation can, however, be called into question.Footnote 70

Investor Interests

In addition, investors can perceive measures aiming to protect them to be such a nuisance, that they will probably not object to a financial institution not applying the rules in an entirely correct way. For example, according to both the “new” and the “old” MiFID, banks should classify investors based on their ability to take financial decisions as well as their degree of risk tolerance.Footnote 71 In order to do so, banks can ask their clients for information by means of, for instance, a questionnaire. The drafting, sending, and interpreting of such questionnaires costs time and money, meaning that there are incentives for banks to keep them short and to let investors categorize themselves. Since filling out such questionnaires will often be experienced as tedious by investors, they can be expected not to object too vehemently to such practices, with the result that, for instance, high-risk products, despite legal regulations, could still be sold to investors not wanting to take risks. In such cases, legal regulations do not appear to contribute to the restoration of consumer trust. On the contrary, seeing that communication plays an important role when it comes to trust (see § 4.2), an investor could consider a short questionnaire to be a positive thing: “How considerate of the bank not to bother me with stacks of paperwork.”

Frustrating Goodwill

Finally, flooding the financial sector with all sorts of obligations can actually put off those bankers who, in principle, wish to trade in a reliable way.Footnote 72 As an obstetrician once said: “Well, you see, the problem is it takes longer to do the paperwork than to deliver the baby” (O’Neill 2013). Naturally, a banker works in a different work environment than an obstetrician, as will be seen in the following description of perverse incentives in the financial sector (§4.2). In fact, these incentives could be an important reason for imposing such regulations on financial institutions. Nevertheless, there are people in the financial sector who do wish to give sound advice to consumers. If, as a result of legislation, these well-intentioned financial service providers choose to stop working in the financial sector and continue to work elsewhere, this can at least be considered an adverse side effect of these measures.

Trust as a Goal of Legislation

Not “Trust,” But “a Realistic Degree of Trust”

After having discussed legislation as a means for restoring consumer trust, this article will now address consumer trust as a goal. As mentioned above, the new EU legislation is based on the assumption, without explaining why, that the restoration of trust in the financial sector is a worthy goal. The lack of such reasoning can possibly be explained by the “positive reflex” the concept of trust evokes: Trust is a good thing, right? It appears that the proverb good wine needs no bush is applied analogously to the pursuit of trust.

However, the decrease in consumer trust caused by bankers’ fraudulent behaviour, for instance, can also be seen as proof that apparently too much trust was put in the financial sector.Footnote 73 In other words, it turned out that bankers and financial institutions were less reliable than people thought them to be, and therefore deserved less trust because it became clear that a lot of them acted opportunistically and deceived investors. To clarifyFootnote 74: in the years preceding the financial crisis, many people trusted Mr. Madoff with their money. Since Madoff took off with their savings, they lost trust in him. Now, should this trust be restored as quickly as possible? The answer seems obvious—it would not be desirable outcome, since too much trust was betrayed. More generally, this also applies to consumers’ trust in the financial sector. In fact, it was actually the people who did have trust in the financial sector who invested their money and, as a result of that, are left with the most financial problems due to disappointing results and high residual debts.

In light of the aforementioned, the following will argue that the goal of the European legislator should not be so much a “restoration of trust,” but rather a realistic degree of trust, implying a certain distrust.Footnote 75 It is not possible to determine in absolute terms what exactly constitutes a realistic degree of trust, since this depends, as mentioned above, on four elements: the subject of trust, the object of trust, the competence or intention of the object, and the specific circumstances.

I should stress that I am not arguing that an absolute distrust with regard to the financial sector is recommended, nor that consumers, if this were even possible, should stay away from the financial markets, since trust is of value for consumers and is relevant for the functioning of the economy (as shown in “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section). In this context, I totally agree with Butler et al. (2009, p. 1) who state that it is important not to trust too much or too little. They conclude: “those who trust too little will give up trade and profit opportunities too often, depressing their economic performance; conversely, individuals who trust too much will over-invest in others and get cheated more frequently, hampering their economic outcomes.”

This section is mainly based on the specific characteristics of the financial sector and insights about trust as described in “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section. First, I will explain that there are many perverse incentives in the market for investment products which makes trusting significantly more risky than in other contexts (“Distance Between Legislator and Financial Sector” section). In addition, the fact that trust does not always mirror reliability (“Legislation as a Determinant of Trust: One of Many, Not One in a Thousand” section) and too much trust can cause a chain reaction of distrust (“Limited Effectiveness” section), a realistic degree of trust seems to be better for consumers and the stability of the financial sector.

Perverse Incentives

As became clear in “The Concept of ‘Trust’” section, trust always involves some risk. However, this risk is much more prominent on the market for investment products than in other situations. Therefore, specific characteristics of the financial sector make a certain degree of distrust desirable, or as Peperzak (2013, p. 14) puts it: “[…] trust is preferable over distrust; but the circumstances […] may make naive trust more pernicious than cautious distrust and intelligent lying.”Footnote 76 In the financial markets, these circumstances include so-called perverse incentives: “rewards” for undesirable behaviour. Some perverse incentives will be briefly described, mainly using a book published recently by Luyendijk (2015, but other authors also highlight these perverse incentives, e.g., Springford 2011). This book is an account of conversations Luyendijk—a journalist—had with about 200 employees and former employees in the City, Europe’s financial centre in London. It offers unique insights into the financial world.

Examples

A first perverse incentive is that complexity and a lack of transparency are rewarded (Luyendijk 2015, pp. 151, 175). Since complexity makes it difficult for consumers to compare financial service providers or financial products, they will be less inclined to switch financial institution. Second, people working in the financial sector can be fired in the blink of an eye, as can bankers (Luyendijk 2015, pp. 75–76). If, years after the fact, the sale of a faulty financial product is brought to light, then this may be bad for a bank’s reputation, but who is to say that the banker responsible still works there? Third, risky and opportunistic behaviour is rewarding due to a moral hazard problem. After all, if taking a risk results in negative consequences for a bank, there are all kinds of safety nets in place (Luyendijk 2015, pp. 61–62). If it happens to a listed company, the shareholders are the ones bearing the financial risk. If it concerns a financial institution which cannot go bankrupt—a bank that is “too big to failthen the taxpayer will ultimately pay the price. On the other hand, a risk translating into a success is followed by a reward. In short, whereas the people taking the risks are not the ones bearing them, they do (literally) take credit for any ensuing successes.Footnote 77

No Changes After the Financial Crisis

In spite of the official measures and self-regulation implemented after the financial crisis, perverse incentives do not seem to have disappeared from the financial markets (Luyendijk 2015, pp. 127–129). For example, in April 2014 the chairman of the Dutch Financial Markets Authority said that the measures up until then taken by investment advisors, banks, insurers, accounting firms, and other financial institutions constituted steps in the right direction, but insufficient ones. The real transformation to “a culture of sincerity and honesty,” with a greater emphasis on clients’ interests still has to take place, according to the chairman.Footnote 78 In the UK regulator’s Business Plan 2015/16 (Financial Conduct Authority 2015), Financial Conduct Authority chairman John Griffith-Jones said something similar: “Poor culture and controls continue to concern us, notwithstanding the efforts being made by firms to improve both.” The persistence of perverse incentives can partly be explained by the lack of feelings of guilt or shame on the part of the people working in the financial sector or, as Luyendijk (2015, p. 79) summarizes the prevailing thought among them, “have lunch or be lunch.” “‘Sheep get slaughtered,’ I was told, and given the chance you are to ‘rip your client’s face off’. Others perceive stock market trading to be ‘[…] zero-sum: I can only win if you lose and vice versa’. ‘There is a fool in every trade’ is a standard expression. ‘You have to know who the fool is, because if you don’t, then you are the fool.’” (Luyendijk 2015, p. 79). Therefore, the financial sector does not appear to have changed fundamentally, to have learned much from the financial crisis, or in general to admit to having done anything wrong.

For that matter, people not being good at learning from their mistakes is not unique to the financial sector. A possible explanation for this is what social psychology calls the “fundamental attribution error”: people’s tendency to attribute their own objectionable behaviour to situational factors (e.g., Krause and Corts 2012, pp. 567–568).Footnote 79 The maintaining of self-esteem is a function and often a result of this attribution.

Perverse Incentives as a Constant Factor in the Existing and Future Financial Markets: Financial Products Versus Other Consumer Goods

So far, particular characteristics of the financial sector have prevented the described incentives from disappearing, an important one being that financial products are inherently different from other consumer goods. Comparing investing money into a financial product to buying an apple can illustrate these differences. First, when a consumer buys an apple, he or she can easily distinguish between a good apple and a bad one. With financial products, this is much harder, given their complexity and a general lack of knowledge about them on the side of consumers (e.g., Alessie et al. 2011, pp. 527–528).

A second difference is that as soon as a bite is taken out of the apple it becomes clear whether it tastes as expected. Considering the relatively long-term nature of a financial product, such as a pension product, it will only become clear after a long period of time whether it yields the expected profit. Besides, if the product fails to meet expectations, then causal ambiguity will prevent the customer from knowing why it did so (“Causal Ambiguity” section). Third, after consuming all of the apples, most consumers will buy another batch. If the apples did not taste good or if another grocer offers them at a lower price, then the consumer will most likely buy the apples there. The equivalent of “buying another batch” does not occur often in the financial markets, something which, again, is connected to the long-term nature of these products.Footnote 80 In view of the aforementioned characteristics, perverse incentives will usually have greater influence on the behaviour of financial institutions than their interest in having a good reputation.

Trust Can Be Stimulated and Does Not Always Parallel Reliability

The Concept of ‘Trust’” section points out that trust and reliability do not always go hand-in-hand. This is underlined by several studies that show that trust is also determined by subjective factors. For instance, there are indications that having face-to-face contact with an advisor and the circumstances under which an investment decision is made have a greater effect on investors than the characteristics of the investment product in question (Monti et al. 2014, p. 1751).Footnote 81 This is confirmed by a study by Monti et al. (2014, p. 1749), which concludes that communication and relational aspects are probably the most important factors determining the degree of trust a consumer is willing to put in an advisor. For instance, the quality of the communication between the customer and the advisor is considered more important than the performance and competence of the financial advisor (Monti et al. 2014, p. 1753).Footnote 82 Furthermore, other studies show that we put more trust in a person who is similar to ourselves (DeBruine 2002, pp. 1307–1312). Considering the widespread presence of perverse incentives and the fact that financial institutions are commercial parties, it is not inconceivable for such insights to be used in order to increase consumer trust. Accordingly, with regard to the training of advisors, a communication course appears to be more effective when it comes to building trust than a content-focused course. Similarly, the level of trust can be increased by coupling an advisor with a customer on the basis of their similarities (Pentland 2008, p. 40). Trust can therefore be stimulated. However, if through such actions a greater degree of trust is put in, for instance, through an advisor, this will have little to do with the question of whether this trust is justified (reliability).

Preventing a Chain Reaction of Distrust

Perhaps the crisis of trust in 2008 would have been less substantial if there had been a more realistic degree of trust in the financial sector at the time. News items about opportunistic behaviour in bankers, for instance, would not thus have come as a bolt from the blue; or, to elaborate on Baier’s (1986, p. 234) metaphor above: the investor would then have probably already had some trouble breathing as a result of the polluted airFootnote 83 in the financial market. A more realistic and more stable level of consumer trust would possibly have resulted in a less severe chain reaction of distrust.

Conclusion

The use of EU legislation to regain investor trust is a growing trend. Examination of a number of legislative proposals shows that they (1) do not clearly define “trust,” and (2) they do not explain why a restoration of trust in the financial sector is a worthy goal. With regard to the first point, uncertainty surrounding the concept of trust is undesirable, since it renders a great deal of research useless as well as resulting in trust as a legislative goal being a malleable and therefore rather meaningless one.

This article has therefore attempted to make the concept of trust somewhat tangible by going into a few of its elements and characteristics. In addition, it was argued that the effectiveness of legislation when it comes to promoting consumer trust can be questioned. For instance, there are indications that the distance between the legislator and the financial sector is too small for such legislation to be effective. Furthermore, research suggests that high bonuses are the most important reason for people to lose their trust in banks. For this reason, it remains to be seen whether EU legislation can counterbalance recurring news stories about extravagant pay rises for bankers.

Finally, investor trust as a goal of legislation was discussed. In the new EU legislation, it is assumed, without offering reasons, that the restoration of trust in the financial sector is a necessary pursuit. However, it is not so much the “restoration of trust” but “the pursuit of a realistic degree of trust”—implying a certain distrust—which should be the goal of such legislation, since various perverse incentives and subjective factors play a role in the financial markets.Footnote 84 Considering the complexity of the financial sector and its often intricate products, it is unlikely for such incentives to be removed by market forces. A realistic degree of trust will possibly lead to a more stable level of investor trust, which at the time of the financial crisis could have prevented a chain reaction of distrust, and could hopefully prevent one in the future. What exactly constitutes a realistic degree of trust cannot be established in absolute terms, since it depends on the subject of trust, the object of trust, the competence or intentions of the object, and the specific circumstances.Footnote 85 All in all, the European legislator does not appear to be on the right track in its efforts to restore consumer trust in the financial sector. Instead, a realistic degree of trust, implying a certain distrust, could mean a step in the right direction for consumers, the financial sector, and a smoothly functioning economy!