Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

An Evolutionary Model of Endogenous Business Cycles

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we present an evolutionary model of industry dynamics yielding endogenous business cycles with ‘Keynesian’ features. The model describes an economy composed of firms and consumers/workers. Firms belong to two industries. The first one performs R&D and produces heterogeneous machine tools. Firms in the second industry invest in new machines and produce a homogenous consumption good. Consumers sell their labor and fully consume their income. In line with the empirical literature on investment patterns, we assume that the investment decisions by firms are lumpy and constrained by their financial structures. Moreover, drawing from behavioral theories of the firm, we assume boundedly rational expectation formation. Simulation results show that the model is able to deliver self-sustaining patterns of growth characterized by the presence of endogenous business cycles. The model can also replicate the most important stylized facts concerning micro- and macro-economic dynamics. Indeed, we find that investment is more volatile than GDP; consumption is less volatile than GDP; investment, consumption and change in stocks are procyclical and coincident variables; employment is procyclical; unemployment rate is anticyclical; firm size distributions are skewed but depart from log-normality; firm growth distributions are tent-shaped.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Agresti, A. and Mojon, B. (2001). Some stylized facts on the euro area business cycle, Working Paper 95, European Central Bank.

  • Bartelsman, E. and Doms, M. (2000). Understanding productivity: Lessons from longitudinal microdata. Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 569–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, M. and King, R. (1999). Measuring business cycle: Approximate band-pass filter for economic time series. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 575–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. and Maccini, L. (1991). Taking stock: A critical assessment of recent research on inventories. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, 73–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S. and Meghir, C. (1994). Dynamic investment models and the firms financial policy. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 197–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, G., Cefis E., and Dosi, G. (2002). Corporate growth and industrial structures: Some evidence from the Italian manufacturing industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 705–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, G. and Secchi, A. (2003a). Common properties and sectoral specificities in the dynamics of U.S. manufacturign firms. Review of Industrial Organization, 23, 217–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, G. and Secchi, A. (2003b). Why are distribution of firm growth rates tent-shaped? Economic Letters, 80, 415–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burns, A.F. and Mitchell, W.C. (1946). Measuring Business Cycles. New York, NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R. (1999). Aggregate investment in Taylor, J. and M. Woodford (eds.). Handbook of Macroeconomics. Amsterdam, Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiaromonte, F. and Dosi, G. (1993). Heterogeneity competition and macroeconomic dynamics. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 4, 39–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cyert, R. and March, J. (1989). A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. 2nd edition, Cambridge, Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doms, M. and Dunne, T. (1998). Capital adjustment patterns in manufacturing plants. Review Economic Dynamics, 1, 409–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1988). Sources procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 126–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. and Egidi, M. (1991). Substantive and procedural uncertainty: An exploration of economic behaviours in changing environments. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1, 145–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Fabiani, S., Aversi, R. and Meacci, M. (1994). The Dynamics of international differentiation: a multi-country evolutionary model. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3, 225–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Fagiolo G., and Roventini, A. (2005). Animal spirits, lumpy investment and Endogenous Business Cycles, Working Paper 2005/04, Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM), Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa, Italy.

  • Dosi, G., Freeman C., and Fabiani, S. (1994). The process of economic development: Introducing some stylized facts and theories on technologies, firms and institutions. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3, 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Marengo L., and Fagiolo, G. (2005). Learning in evolutionary environment. in Dopfer, K. (ed.), Evolutionary Principles of Economics. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Marsili, O., Orsenigo, L. and Salvatore, R. (1995). Learning, market selection and the evolution of industrial structures. Small Business Economics, 7, 411–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. and Nelson, R. (1994). An introduction to evolutionary theories in economics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 4, 153–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. and Winter, S. (2002). Interpreting economic change: Evolution, structures and games in Augier, M. and J. March (eds.). The Economics of Choice, Change, and Organizations. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisner, R. (1972). Components of capital expenditures: Replacement and modernization versus expansion. Review of Economics and Statistics, 54, 297–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, J. and Axtell, R. (1996). Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom-Up. Washington D.C., MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erickson, T. and Whited, T. (2000). Measurement error and the relationship between investment and q. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1027–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo, G. and Dosi, G. (2003). Exploitation, exploration and innovation in a model of endogenous growth with locally interacting agents. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 14, 237–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari, S. and Athey, M. (1987). Asymmetric information, financing constraints, and investments. Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 481–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari, S., Hubbard R., and Petersen, B. (1988). Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 141–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. and Foot, D. (1971). The other half of gross investment: Replacement and modernization expenditures. Review of Economics and Statistics, 53, 49–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (1982). The Economics of Industrial Innovation. London, Francis Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goolsbee, A. (1998). The business cycle, financial performance, and the retirement of capital goods, Working Paper 6392, NBER.

  • Greenwald, B. and Stiglitz, S. (1993). Financial market imperfections and business cycles. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 77–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, R. (1998). Capital-market imperfections and investment. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 193–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S. and Zingales, L. (1997). Do investment-cashflow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 169–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katona, G. and Morgan, J.N. (1952). The quantitative study of factors determining business decisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 66, 67–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, R. and Rebelo, S. (1999). Resuscitating real business cycles. in Taylor, J. and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Macroeoconomics. Amsterdam, Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirman, A. (1989). The intrinsic limits of modern economic theory: the emperor has no clothes. Economic Journal, 99, 126–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirman, A. (1992). Whom or what does the representative individual represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6, 117–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1930). Secular Movements in Production and Prices. Boston, Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwasnicki, W. (1998). Simulation methodology in evolutionary economics. in Schweitzer, F. and G. Silverberg (eds.), Evolution and Self-Organization in Economics. Berlin, Duncker & Humbold.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. (1990). Business cycles: Real facts and a monetary myth. Federal Reserve of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Spring 1990, 3–18.

  • Lane, D.A. (1993a). Artificial worlds and economics, part I. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3, 89–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, D.A. (1993b). Artificial worlds and economics, Part II. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3, 177–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G.N. and Romer, D. (eds.) (1991). New Keynesian Economics, Cambridge MA, MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Napoletano, M., Roventini A., and Sapio, S. (2006). Are business cycles all alike? a bandpass filter analysis of the Italian and US cycles. Rivista Italiana degli Economisti, Forthcoming.

  • Nelson, R. (1981). Research on productivity growth and productivity difference: Dead ends and new departures. Journal of Economic Literature, 19, 1029–1064.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pyka, A. and Fagiolo, G. (2005). Agent-based modelling: A methodology for neo-schumpeterian economics. in Hanusch, H. and A. Pyka (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the Blackbox. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1994). Exploring the Black Box : Technology, Economics and History. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G. and Lehnert, D. (1994). Growth fluctuations in an evolutionary model of creative destruction. in Silverberg, G. and L. Soete (eds.), The economics of growth and technical change. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70: 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stadler, G.W. (1994). Real business cycles. Journal of Economic Literature, 32 (4), 1750–1783.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1999). Business cycle fluctuations in U.S. macroeconomic time series. in Taylor, J. and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics. Amsterdam, Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion, L. (1997). How economists can get ALife. in Arthur, W., S. Durlauf and D. Lane (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II. Santa Fe Institute, Santa Fe and Reading, MA, Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, L. (2002). Is lumpy investment relevant for business cycle? Journal of Political Economy, 110, 508–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarnowitz, V. (1985). Recent works on business cycles in historical perspectives: A review of theories and evidence. Journal of Economic Literature, 23, 523–580.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zarnowitz, V. (1997). Business cycles observed and assessed: Why and how they matter. Working Paper 6230, NBER.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giovanni Dosi.

Additional information

JEL Classifications: C15, C22, C49, E17, E22, E32.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G. & Roventini, A. An Evolutionary Model of Endogenous Business Cycles. Comput Econ 27, 3–34 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-005-9014-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-005-9014-2

Keywords

Navigation