Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Measuring sustainable development for the future with climate change mitigation; a case study of applying an integrated assessment model under IPCC SRES scenarios

  • Published:
Environment, Development and Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) described mainstreaming climate change mitigation into development choices in its Fourth Assessment Report, chapter 12 of Working Group III. It also pointed out that “few macro-indicators include measures of progress with respect to climate change” despite the needs for the inclusion. This paper tackled this point in the following ways by applying an integrated assessment model. First, this study applied shadow prices and production, endogenously obtained from the model, instead of using market prices and statistical data used in preceding studies in the economics literature. Second, this study measured forecasts of genuine saving (GS) and wealth globally up to the year 2100, while preceding studies were constrained to past and current savings and wealth. Third, this study examined changes in GS and wealth in different future scenarios on IPCC SRES (Special Report on Emissions Scenarios) with CO2 emissions constraints. Finally, the authors adopted a GS estimation methodology of shadow prices in imperfect economies by Kenneth Arrow and Partha Dasgupta, instead of that of perfect economies by Kirk Hamilton et al., on which the authors had based previous studies. This makes the indicator consistent with changes of wealth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. yr = 2010, 2020, …, 2140, 2150, rg = North America, Western Europe, Japan, Oceania, China, South and East Asia including India, Middle East and North Africa, Sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America, and the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe.

  2. Electric machinery products, automobiles, civil engineering and construction (sec).

  3. Mineral resources (mr) are composed of fuel mineral resources (fm) (coal, oil, gas, uranium) and non-fuel resources (nfm) (iron ore, bauxite, copper, lead, zinc, limestone).

  4. Logs, wood pulp, timber/boards, papers (pw).

  5. Pork, chicken, mutton, beef, rice, wheat, corn (fd).

  6. This is computed as follows: the marginal change of social welfare (total net value of utility) V against the marginal change of the import/export amount M (\( {{\partial V} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial V} {\partial M}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M}} \)) divided by the marginal change of social welfare (total net value of utility) V against the marginal change of import/export cost (\( {{\partial X} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial X} {\partial M}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M}} \)).

  7. The environmental impact, which is a non-market asset, could cause damage to the four endpoints (health of human beings, social assets, primary productivity, bio-diversity). Therefore, it is possible to include the primary productivity and biological diversity into the national capital, social assets into physical capital, and health of human beings into human capital, and subtract them as capital depreciation. However, this idea requires further examination.

  8. We assumed that people between the ages of 15–64 are all members of the labor population. Based on the medium-scenario population projection by the United Nations (UN World Population 2300), we computed the labor population rate at the time for each area. We then multiplied these figures by the B2 scenario.

  9. Form of function ϕ is a diminishing return (ϕ′ = dϕ/dS > 0, ϕ″ = d2ϕ/dS2 < 0), when ϕ equals zero when S is zero. ϕ′ is marginal income increase by additional education attainment, corresponds to coefficient (rate of return). ϕ was computed from data in Cuaresma and Lutz (2007), Hall and Jones (1999), Psacharopoulos (1994), Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2004, Barro and Lee (2010), and World Bank (2010).

  10. Adult Survival Rate (ASR) is 1-AMR (Adult Mortality Rate). AMR is weighted average of male and female adult mortality rates taken from the WDI 2010 (“Mortality rate, adult, male”, “Mortality rate, adult, female”, and “Population, female ( % of total)”). Then AMR is expressed as a function of per capita GDP in respective 10 regions. ψ is set .653 from Weil (2007). see detail in Ferreira and Hamilton (2010).

  11. We undertook a social survey of 1,000 people all over Japan in 2006. Based on the survey results, we carried out conjoint analysis to obtain willingness to pay (WTP) (Itsubo et al. 2012). We then applied benefit transfer to areas other than Japan and to a future time point by using elasticity for per capita GDP, based on the review by Pearce (Pearce 2003).

References

  • Arrow, K. J., Dasgupta, P., & Mäler, K.-G. (2003). The genuine savings criterion and the value of population. Economic Theory, 21(2/3), 217–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., et al. (2004). Are we consuming too much? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 147–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., et al. (2007). China, the U.S., and sustainability: Perspectives based on comprehensive wealth. Stanford Center for International Development, Working paper No. 313, January 2007.

  • Arrow, K. J., et al. (2010). Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. NBER Working Paper No. 16599, December 2010, http://www.nber.org/papers/w16599. Accessed 3 May 2012.

  • Asheim, G. B. (2004). Green national accounting with a changing population. Economic Theory, 23(3), 601–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, G., Dietz, S., & Neumayer, E. (Eds.). (2007). Handbook of sustainable development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J. (2010). A new data set of educational attainment in the world 1950–2010, NBER Working Paper No. 15902. http://www.nber.org/papers/w15902. Accessed 3 May 2012.

  • Bulckaen, F., & Stampini, A. M. (2009). On shadow prices for the measurement of sustainability. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 11(6), 1197–1213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuaresma, J. C., & Lutz, W. (2007) Human capital, age structure and economic growth: Evidence from a new dataset. Interim Report IR-07-011, IIASA, Luxemburg, Austria.

  • Cure, J. D., & Acock, B. (1986). Crop responses to carbon dioxide doubling, a literature survey. Agriculture and Forest Meteorology, 38, 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. (2001). Human well-being and the natural environment. Oxford University Press.

  • Dasgupta, P. (2009). The welfare economic theory of green national accounts. Environmental & Resource Economics, 42(1), 3–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Energy Data and Modeling Center, Institute of Energy Economics, Japan (EDMC/IEEJ). (2002). Handbook of Energy & Economic Statistics in Japan 2002. Energy Conservation Center, Tokyo.

  • Environment Agency of Japan. (2000). Threatened wildlife of Japan–red data book, 2nd Edn. Vascular Plants, Vol. 8. Japan Wildlife Research Center, Tokyo.

  • ExternE-Externalities of Energy. (2012). A research project of the European Commission. http://www.externe.info/ (Access date May 3rd, 2012).

  • Ferreira, S., & Hamilton, K. (2010). Comprehensive wealth and its components: Explaining intangible capital, Policy Research Working Paper 5452, Environment and Energy Team, Development Research Group, The World Bank, October 2010.

  • Ferreira, S., & Moro, M. (2011). Constructing genuine savings indicators for Ireland, 1995–2005. Journal of Environmental Management, 92(3), 542–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, K. (2003). Sustaining economic welfare: Estimating changes in total and per capita wealth. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 5(3/4), 419–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, K., & Atkinson, G. (1996). Air pollution and green accounting. Energy Policy, 24(7), 675–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, K., & Atkinson, G. (2006). Wealth, welfare and sustainability: Advances in measuring sustainable development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, K., & Clemens, M. (1999). Genuine savings rates in developing countries. The World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 333–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi, K., Nakagawa, A., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A. (2002). Assessment of impacts due to additional emission of ozone depleting substances. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance (pp. 33–36). Tokyo: The Society of Non-Traditional Technology.

  • Hayashi, K., Okazaki, M., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A. (2004). Development of damage function of acidification for terrestrial ecosystems based on the effect of aluminum toxicity on net primary production. International Journal of Life Cycle Assessment, 9, 13–22.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Hirosaki, J., Itsubo, N., Furota,T., Inaba, A. (2002). Estimation of the damage by eutrophication. In Proceedings of fifth International Conferenceon Eco Balance. The Society of Non-Traditional Technology, Tokyo, pp.45–48.

  • Ii, R., Ikemoto, G., Abe, K., Nakagawa, A., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A. (2002). Life cycle impact assessment for office building considering land use and related impact categories. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance (pp. 367–370). Tokyo: The Society of Non-Traditional Technology.

  • Itsubo, N. & Inaba, A. (Eds). (2010). Lifecycle Impact Assessment Method—LIME, methodology and database for LCA, environmental accounting, and eco-efficiency. Maruzen, Tokyo.

  • Itsubo, N. et al. (2000). Screening life cycle impact assessment with weighting methodology based on simplified damage functions. International Journal of Life Cycle Assessment, 5(5), 273–280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Itsubo, N., Sakagami, M., Kuriyama, K., & Inaba, A. (2012). Statistical analysis for the development of national average weighting factors—visualization of the variability between each individual’s environmental thoughts. International Journal of Life Cycle Assessment, 7(4), 488–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itsubo, N., Sakagami, M., Washida, T., Kokubu, K., & Inaba, A. (2005). Weighting across safeguard subjects for LCIA by the application of conjoint analysis. International Journal of Life Cycle Assessment, 9(3), 196–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itsubo, N., et al. (2000). Development of eco-efficiency indicator in various scales considering external cost. Journal of Environmental Information Science, 18, 373–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iwaki, H. (1981). Regional distribution of phytomass resources in Japan. Environmental Information Science, 10, 54–61. (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosugi, T., et al. (2009). Internalization of the external costs of global environmental damage in an integrated assessment model. Energy Policy, 37(7), 2664–2678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunte, A., et al. (1998). Estimating National Wealth: Methodology and results. Environment Department Working Papers No. 57, 1998, Washington DC, The World Bank.

  • Matsuda, H. (2000). Environmental ecology: A synthesis of sustainable fisheries, biodiversity conservation, ecosystem management and environmental impact assessment. Tokyo: Kyoritsu Publishing, (in Japanese).

  • Matsuda, H., Serizawa, S., Ueda, K., Kato, T., & Yahara, T. (2003). Extinction risk assessment of vascular plants in the 2005 world exposition, Japan. Chemosphere, 53, 325–336.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Metz, B., Davidson, O. R., Bosch, P. R., Dave, R., & Meyer, L. A. (Eds.). (2007). Climate change 2007: Mitigation of climate change, contribution of working group III to the Fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mota, R. P., Domingos, T., & Martins, V. (2010). Analysis of genuine saving and potential green net national income: Portugal, 1990–2005. Ecological Economics, 69(10), 1934–1942.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagata, Y., Ohara, T., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A. (2002). Development of damage functions of air pollutants considering local conditions of Japan. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance (pp. 41–44). Tokyo: The Society of Non-Traditional Technology.

  • Nakagawa, A., Abe, K., Ii, R., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A. (2002). Development of life-cycle impact assessment method for land use based on endpoint damage. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance. The Society of Non-Traditional Technology, Tokyo, pp. 29–32.

  • Nakićenović, N., Grübler, A., & McDonald, A. (Eds.). (1998). Global energy perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakićenović, N., & Swart, R. (Eds.). (2000). Special report on emissions scenarios. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1994). Managing the global commons: The economics of climate change. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D., & Boyer, J. (2000). Warming the world–economic models of global warming. London: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Numata, M. (1987). Biology of plant. Tokyo: Tokai University Press. (in Japanese).

  • Ollivier, T., & Giraud, P.-N. (2011). Assessing sustainability, a comprehensive wealth accounting prospect: An application to Mozambique. Ecological Economics, 70(3), 503–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W. (2003). Conceptual framework for analyzing the distributive impacts of environmental policies. prepared for the OECD Environment Directorate Workshop on the Distribution of Benefits and Costs of Environmental Policies, Paris.

  • Pearce, D. W., & Atkinson, G. (1993). Capital theory and the measurement of sustainable development: An indicator of “weak” sustainability. Ecological Economics, 8(2), 103–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pezzey, J. C. V., & Toman, M. A. (2002). Progress and problems in the economics of sustainability. In T. Tietenberg & H. Folmer (Eds.), The international yearbook of environmental and resource economics 2002/2003. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). Return to investment in education: A global update. World Development, 22(9), 1325–1343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos, G., & Patrinos H. A. (2004). Returns to investment in education: A further update. Education Economics, 12(2), 111–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakao, T., Itsubo, N., Pennington, D. W., Tanaka, Y., Yoshida, K., & Inaba, A. (2002). Development of damage functions for emissions of toxic substances in Japan. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance (pp. 363–366). Tokyo: The Society of Non-Traditional Technology.

  • Simpson, R. D., Toman, M. A., Ayres, R. U. (Eds) (2005). Scarcity and growth revisited: Natural resources and the environment in the new millennium, resources for the future. (Japanese translation Ueta, K. (eds), (2009) Frontier of Environmental and Resource Economics, Nihon Hyoron sya, Co. Ltd. http://www.nippyo.co.jp/book/5053.html. Accessed 3 May 2012).

  • Takahashi, K., Harasawa, H., & Matsuoka, Y. (1997). Climate change impact on global crop production. Journal of Global Environment Engineering, 3, 145–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, C. D. (2004). Extinction risk from climate change. Nature, 427, 145–148.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Tokimatsu, K., et al. (2011). Measuring future dynamics of Genuine saving with changes of population and technology: Application of an integrated assessment model. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 13(4), 703–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol, R. S. J. (2005). The marginal damage costs of carbon dioxide emissions: An assessment of the uncertainties. Energy Policy, 33(16), 2064–2074.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uchida, H., Takahashi, K., Harasawa, H., Itaoka, K., Itsubo, N., & Inaba, A., (2002). Development of damage function relating the loss of crop and plant productivity with the emission of GHGs. In Proceedings of 5th international conference on EcoBalance. The Society of Non-Traditional Technology, Tokyo, pp. 49–52.

  • Uchijima, Z., & Seino, H. (1985). Agroclimatic evaluation of net primary productivity of natural vegetation, (1) Chikugo model for evaluating net primary productivity. Journal of Agricultural Meteorology, 40, 343–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2003). World population prospects: The 2002 revision. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs/Population Division (2003) World Population to 2300.

  • Weil, D. N. (2007). Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 1265–1306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. L. (1976). On the welfare significance of national product in a dynamic economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(1), 156–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WHO. (2004). The global burden of disease: 2004 update. http://www.who.int/healthinfo/global_burden_disease/GBD_report_2004update_full.pdf.

  • WHO. (2010). Comparative quantification of health risks. http://www.who.int/healthinfo/global_burden_disease/cra/en/.

  • Wigley. (2010). Model for the Assessment of Greenhouse-gas Induced Climate Change, A Regional Climate Scenario Generator, http://www.cgd.ucar.edu/cas/wigley/magicc/.

  • World Bank. (2004). World Development Indicators. Washington, DC.

  • World Bank. (2006). Where is the wealth of nations? Measuring capital for the 21st century. Washington, DC.

  • World Bank. (2010). World Development Indicators. Washington, DC.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors express their sincere appreciation to Kyoto University, the National Institute of Advanced Industrial Science and Technology (AIST) for their hospitality and support. The model used in this study is based on our earlier collaboration with Takanobu Kosugi (Ritsumeikan University), Tsuyosi Adachi and Shinsuke Murakami (The University of Tokyo), Norihiro Itsubo (Tokyo City University), Ryota Ii (Pacific Consulting, Co., Ltd.), Atsushi Kurosawa (IAE), Hideto Miyachika (SRC, Co., Ltd.). The lead author (K.T.) expresses his gratitude to those who collaborate with him in developing the model. Any unexpected errors are due to the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Koji Tokimatsu.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A brief outline of our model

1.1.1 Objective function

We assume a social planer who maximizes (intertemporal) social welfare, V(t), expressed by the present discounted value of utility streams:

$$ \max V(t) = \int\limits_{s = t}^{\infty } {N(s) \cdot \log \left( {\frac{C(s)}{N(s)}} \right){\text{e}}^{{ - \rho \left( {s - t} \right)}} {\text{d}}s} $$
(14)

where N(s) is population (exogenously given), C(s) is consumption (endogenous), utility is given by the product of the logarithm of per capita consumption and population, and ρ is the pure rate of time preference or utility discount rate, assumed to be 2 %/year here (see Appendix, Table 5). Here, a caution is warranted that our model is described not in continuous time, but in terms of 10-year time steps (denoted as “yr” hereafter) from 2010 to 2150. The period after 2150 is added by using the sum of an infinite geometric series (unshown in Eq. 15). Geographically, the model divides the world into ten regions (denoted as “rg” hereafter), which are North America, Western Europe, Japan, Oceania, China, East-South Asia (including India), Middle East and North Africa, Sub-Sahara Africa, Latin America, and the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. Hence, Eq. (14) is expressed as follows, where c is per capita consumption:

$$ \max V(2010) = \sum\limits_{rg} {Neg_{rg} \cdot \left( {\sum\limits_{yr = 2010}^{2150} {\left( {\frac{1}{1 + \rho }} \right)^{yr - 2010}\,\cdot\,N_{rg,yr}\,\cdot\,\log c_{rg,yr} } } \right)} $$
(15)
Table 5 Nomenclature of mainframe of the model

For population, the scenario from the Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (SRES) by the IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) is used as exogenous scenario N rg,yr by time step and world region. Neg rg is known as the “Negishi weight,” whose interpretation is that “optimization” determines the efficient competitive-market equilibrium of the different regions.

1.1.2 A macro-economy submodel

Consumption is derived endogenously within a model, similar to the RICE (Nordhaus and Boyer 2000), in which macroeconomic relations are determined among output, investment, capital stock depreciation, intermediate inputs (supply cost of fuel mineral resources, non-fuel mineral resources, and land use), and external damage costs. Specifically, we have:

$$ C_{rg,yr} = Y_{rg,yr} - I_{rg,yr} + IM_{rg,yr} - XP_{rg,yr} $$
(16)

where output, Y, is given by the nested production function, subtracted by costs involved in intermediate inputs such as FC, NFC, LUC, DC:

$$ Y_{rg,yr} = A_{rg,yr} \cdot F_{rg,yr} \left( {K,H,EL,NE,M,LU} \right) - FC_{rg,yr} - NFC_{rg,yr} - LUC_{rg,yr} - DC_{rg,yr} $$
(17)
$$ F_{rg,yr} \left( {K,H,EL,NE,M,LU} \right) = \left[ {\left[ {\left\{ {a_{1} \left( {K_{rg,yr}^{\alpha } H_{rg,yr}^{1 - \alpha } } \right)^{ - \varepsilon } +\,a_{2} \left( {\left( {EL_{rg,yr}^{\beta } \cdot NE_{rg,yr}^{1 - \beta } } \right)^{\gamma } \cdot M_{rg,yr}^{1 - \gamma } } \right)^{ - \varepsilon } } \right\}^{{ - \frac{1}{\varepsilon }}} } \right]^{ - \lambda } + a_{3} \cdot LU_{rg,yr}^{ - \lambda } } \right]^{{ - \frac{1}{\lambda }}} $$
(18)

where K is physical capital stock, H is human capital, EL is electricity, NE is non-electric energy resources, M is non-fuel mineral resources, LU is land resources, and a1, a2, a3, α, β, γ, ε, λ are the parameters. The dynamics of the capital stock is described by:

$$ K_{rg,yr + 1} = \left( {1 - \delta } \right)^{10} \cdot K_{rg,yr} + I_{rg,yr} $$
(19)

where δ is the annual depreciation rate.

A rg,yr is the calibration term between F rg,yr (K,H,EL,NE,M,LU) and the sum of intermediate input costs (FC rg,yr  + NFC rg,yr  + LUC rg,yr ) plus value added (refGDP rg,yr ), which is the benchmark GDP of SRES-B2 scenario adopted in Nakićenović and Swart (2000):

$$ A_{rg,yr} = \frac{{refGDP_{rg,yr} + FC_{rg,yr} + NFC_{rg,yr} + LUC_{rg,yr} }}{{F_{rg,yr} \left( {K,H,EL,NE,M,LU} \right)}} $$
(20)

The aggregate stock of human capital H rg,yr is obtained by multiplying labor population L rg,yr by an individual human capital stock ϕ through average education years S rg,yr (i.e., exp(ϕ(S))), and human health (i.e., exp(Ψ ASR)).

$$ H_{rg,yr} = \exp (\varphi (S)) \cdot \exp (\psi \cdot ASR) \cdot L_{rg,yr} $$
(21)

FC rg,yr , NFC rg,yr , LUC rg,yr , DC rg,yr are fuel mineral supply cost, non-fuel mineral supply cost, land-use cost for food supply, and damage cost, respectively, which are explained in the following sections.

1.1.3 Fuel and non-fuel minerals (FC, NFC)

The submodel of mineral resources treats fuel minerals (fm; oil, gas, coal, uranium) and non-fuel mineral resources (nfm; iron, bauxite, copper, lead, zinc, limestone). This is a demand and supply model, in which supply deals with mining, milling, dressing, smelting, and refining for nfm, the electrical or chemical conversion process for energy, transportation among the ten global regions, to the final demand of both energy (EL rg,yr and NE rg,yr ) and materials (MD sec,nfm,rg,yr ) by three representative manufacturing sectors (electricity and machinery, construction and building, motor cycles). The nfm exist as in-use stocks of goods produced during the assumed products lifetime, after which they become out-of-use stocks and then are finally disposed of or recycled.

1.1.4 Land use and land-use change (LUC)

The land-use submodel calculates the endogenous five categories of land use (forestry, grassland, cropland, urban, others) and 20 kinds of land-use change among the categories (= five times four), by satisfying exogenous demand for food and area of urban land (i.e., land area requirement for human settlement), by the use of exogenous costs of land rent, land conversion, and food production.

The food demands are expressed as both calorie based and protein based, which are satisfied by crop productions in croplands and by meat productions in grasslands. Each production is converted by use of yield to area of cropland and grassland (pasture land). The area of urban land is calculated from population and population density. Forest area is calculated via (1) deforestation and reforestation due to carbon release and absorption, (2) conversion to cropland and grassland for food production requirements. The land category of “other” includes all others such as desert terrain and reservation land, whose area will be kept constant. In short, the land area of “others” is constant, urban area is decided by population and population density, forestry is driven by food demand and global warming constraints, and both grassland and cropland satisfy aggregated food demand.

1.1.5 External damage costs (DC)

Damage cost (DC) can be calculated by:

$$ DC_{rg,yr} = \sum\limits_{sgo} {WF_{sgo,rg,yr} \cdot \sum\limits_{sbs} {DR_{sgo,sbs,rg,yr} \cdot Inv_{sbs,rg,yr} } } $$
(22)

where

$$ WF_{sgo,rg,yr} = WF_{{sgo,JPN,yr_{0} }} \cdot \left( {\frac{{{{Y_{rg,yr} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Y_{rg,yr} } {N_{rg,yr} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {N_{rg,yr} }}}}{{{{Y_{{JPN,yr_{0} }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{Y_{{JPN,yr_{0} }} } {N_{{JPN,yr_{0} }} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {N_{{JPN,yr_{0} }} }}}}} \right)^{\sigma } $$
(23)

sgo = human health, social capital, net primary production (NPP), and biodiversity, sbs = greenhouse gases, ozone depletion substances (ODS), extraction and disposal of nfm, LU&LUC.

The weighting factor, WF (or MWTP), and the dose–response relation, DR, are exogenously given by LIME. They are related to four endpoints (or safe guard objects) by way of the DR relationship described in (Itsubo and Inaba 2000; Itsubo et al. 2005) then aggregated into monetary terms by WF obtained through conjoint analysis (Itsubo et al. 2005, 2012). INV is inventories treated in the model, such as CO2, SO x , and NO x from fuel combustion, CO2 release via deforestation, five kinds of non-CO2 greenhouse gas GHG (NCGHG), 14 kinds of ozone depletion substances (ODS), and extraction and disposal of nfm, LU&LUC. NCGHG and ODS are exogenous; all the others are endogenous. DR and WF in LIME are adjusted to be compatible with all regions and time steps in our model. The WF is transferred by using benefit transfer expressed in Eq. (A10) (income elasticity σ of 0.5 from Pearce 2003).

The Dose–Response relations in Japan are indicated in LIME, which is adjusted to all regions and time steps to suit our model. The differences in region and time compared to present-day Japan are reflected by using a zero-order approximation that considers the damage and impact to safe guard objects (Kosugi et al. 2009). To be specific, the ratio (between the value in a region in a time step as numerator and the value of the present day as a denominator) is multiplied by values of dose–response in present-day Japan. The ratio of population density ratio for human health, the ratio of population density for human health per capita GDP for social capital, potential NPP for NPP, and the extinction risk of vascular plants for biodiversity, are applied to the multiplication.

1.2 Impact categories treated in our model (see Appendix Table 6)

1.2.1 Global warming

In order to develop damage functions for the safeguard subjects of human health (WHO 2010), social assets (Uchida et al. 2002) and biodiversity (Thomas 2004), (1) damage due to the impact pathway with and without emissions perturbations for CO2, NOx, SOx, as was carried out in papers by R.S.J. Tol (e.g., Tol 2005), by using the MAGICC/SCENGEN 5.3 model (Wigley 2010); (2) time series impacts were estimated by interpolation and extrapolation based on the benchmark impacts considering regional population change and economic development (United Nations 2003, Nakićenović et al. 1998, WHO 2004); (3) the damages were aggregated as functions of global mean temperature rise.

Table 6 Category endpoints considered in LIME in relation to impact categories and safeguard subjects
1.2.1.1 Damages for human health

The human health impacts till the end of this century are extrapolated from WHO 2004, for malaria, diarrhea, malnutrition, coastal floods, inland floods and landslides. The damage is calculated between damages between with and without the perturbations for the following equation: (global mean temperature rise) * (baseline scenario for outbreaks of illness) * (relative risks − 1) * (baseline scenario for population) * (DALY per case).

1.2.1.2 Damages for social capital stock

Future crop productions without CO2 fertilization effects were extrapolated results from the model of potential crop productivity developed by Kyoto University and the National Institute of Environmental Studies, Japan (Takahashi et al. 1997). In addition, the CO2 fertilization effect was calculated based on the study by (Cure and Acock 1986). To estimate the change in energy consumption for heating and cooling resulting from global warming, future heating and cooling degree days were calculated, and the interaction between economic growth and heating and cooling energy consumption was analyzed using empirical energy consumption data for Japan (EDMC/IEEJ 2002). The land elevation dataset ETOPO5 accessible via GRID-Tsukuba, originally developed by the NOAA National Geophysical Data Center (NGDC), was used to calculate the areas of submergence in the case of a 0.5-meter sea-level rise that plausibly corresponds to a doubled CO2 concentration in 2100.

1.2.1.3 Damages for biodiversity

Relationships between relative change for land use and global mean temperature are derived from Thomas 2004 using species-area relationships. The impacts are converted into relative risk changes modeled in the original LIME model (Itsubo 2010), as a function of global mean temperature rise.

1.2.2 Land use

The increment of extinction risk of vascular species and the decrement of net primary production (NPP) of vegetation, as indicators of biodiversity and primary productivity, respectively, were assessed as damage indicators (Nakagawa et al. 2002). These damages were considered to be incurred by land use (land occupation) and land-use change (land transformation).

1.2.2.1 Damages to biodiversity

The extinction risk as employed in LIME is defined as the inverse number of the average years from the present until the extinction of a threatened vascular plant, originally based on the idea of extinction probability. A statistical model developed by Matsuda (Matsuda 2000; Matsuda et al. 2003) based on the Red Data Book (RDB) in Japan (Environment Agency of Japan 2000) was applied to estimate extinction probability. The damage factor corresponding to the location of land use was established by assessing regional biodiversity using the distribution of the RDB public species, which is called the hot spot map, accessible via the Internet from the Biodiversity Center of Japan.

1.2.2.2 Damages to primary productivity

NPP loss due to land use was derived by subtracting the actual NPP from the potential NPP, whereas that due to land-use change was assessed in terms of the potential decrease of NPP based on when the former area of land use would be recovered, taking into account the time necessary for recovering an area’s potential. The recovery time was set according to the results reported by (Numata 1987). The Chikugo model (Uchijima and Seino 1985) including climatic data was applied to the calculation of the potential NPP. The field-surveyed NPP data compiled by (Iwaki 1981) were utilized for the actual NPP.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Tokimatsu, K., Yamaguchi, R., Sato, M. et al. Measuring sustainable development for the future with climate change mitigation; a case study of applying an integrated assessment model under IPCC SRES scenarios. Environ Dev Sustain 14, 915–938 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-012-9360-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-012-9360-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation