Skip to main content
Log in

Who knows it is a game? On strategic awareness and cognitive ability

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine strategic awareness in experimental games, that is, the question of whether subjects realize they are playing a game and thus have to form beliefs about others’ actions. We conduct a beauty contest game and elicit measures of cognitive ability and beliefs about others’ cognitive ability. We show that the effect of cognitive ability is highly non-linear. Subjects below a certain threshold choose numbers in the whole interval and their behavior does not correlate with beliefs about others’ ability. In contrast, subjects who exceed the threshold avoid choices above 50 and react very sensitively to beliefs about the cognitive ability of others.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is some evidence that individuals do not consider other individuals behavior when making decisions. For example, individuals compete too much on easy tasks and too little on hard tasks (Moore and Cain 2007), ignore competitors’ characteristics that are payoff-relevant (Camerer and Lovallo 1999) or take competitors behavior as given (Goldfarb and Xiao 2011).

  2. This finding is in line with other recent evidence on the presence of non-strategic players in the BCG. For example, a study by Agranov, Caplin and Tergiman (2015) identifies a large proportion of k  =  0 players (43 percent) by observing players’ provisional BCG choices within a 3 min time frame. Related, Burchardi and Penczynski (2014) use communication protocols among team members playing a BCG to classify strategic and non-strategic reasoning (about 33 percent).

  3. Branas-Garza, Garcia-Munoz and Gonzalez (2012) use the Raven test and the cognitive reflection test (CRT) to measure subjects’ cognitive ability and relate the test scores to behavior in six BCGs with varying p. They find no effect for cognitive ability in the first two beauty contests (with p  =  2/3 and p  =  1/8), but in the remaining BCGs (p  =  1/5, p  =  1/3, p = 1/2, p  =  3/4) they observe a negative correlation of CRT and chosen numbers. Similarly, Gill and Prowse (2015) find no relationship between Raven’s test scores and choices in the first round of a repeated BCG (p  =  7/10), but they observe that more cognitively able subjects converge more frequently to equilibrium over time. Georganas, Healy and Weber (2015) find that CRT scores are related to level-2 play in a variety of 2-person BCGs.

  4. Alaoui and Penta (2015) show theoretically that their experimental results are consistent with individuals engaging in a cost-benefit analysis of applying additional rounds of reasoning. See also Strzalecki (2014) for an alternative theoretical approach in which behavior also depends on own bounded rationality and beliefs about opponents’ bounds.

  5. Other studies find that higher cognitive ability is, for example, related to better financial decision making (Agarwal and Mazumder 2013) and stock market participation (Christelis et al. 2010) or health insurance take up (Fang et al. 2008).

  6. The BCG was conducted alongside other experimental modules (for details and subjects characteristics, see Appendix A and Fehr 2013). Subjects were recruited through ORSEE (Greiner 2015) and the experiment was run with z-tree (Fischbacher 2007).

  7. In four sessions subjects were unintentional matched in groups of twelve and thus in total there are 36 groups in the BCG. While the average choice turned out to be similar in groups of twelve (42.3) and six (45.8), the regression analysis controls for group-size effects.

  8. The three questions are the following: A bat and a ball cost 1.10 Euro in total. The bat costs 1.00 Euro more than the ball. How much does the ball cost? If it takes 5 machines 5 min to make 5 widgets, how long would it take 100 machines to make 100 widgets? In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to cover half of the lake?

  9. The used questions can be found in Appendix D. For general information about the test see www.wonderlic.com.

  10. In one session there was a false fire alarm during the WPT and hence the test scores are not used in the analysis. The other tasks were not affected because they were completed before the false alarm.

  11. Branas-Garza et al. (2012) report an average choice of 43.2 \( (p = 2/3\;{\text{BCG}}) \) and (Gill and Prowse 2015) find an average choice of 44.2 \( (p = 7/10\;{\text{BCG}}) \). Using two-player teams in a \( p = 2/3\;{\text{BCG,}} \) Burchardi and Penczynski (2014) find that the suggested average choices of subjects in a team are 43.9 (the final average choice was 39.7 after communication).

  12. Other studies find similar shares. For example, Branas-Garza et al. (2012) find that 16 percent of subjects choose a number in the interval [2/3*100, 100], Burnham et al. (2009) find that about 20 percent of subjects choose a number in the interval [1/2*100, 100] and Allred et al. (2014) find that 33 percent of their subjects choose a number in [2/3*10, 10]. Relatedly, Agranov et al. (2015) show that when subjects can modify their choice as often as they want within a three-minute time frame, more than 50 percent of subjects choose at least once an action in the interval [2/3*100, 100]. In their setup, non-strategic subjects switch their choices more than five times as often as strategic subjects and the average choices of non-strategic subjects are remarkably close to 50. Similarly, we find that, in particular, the choices of subjects with a CRT score of 0 or 1 are on average close to 50.

  13. The average score in the 3-item CRT is 1.49. About 48 % of the subjects have one or less answer correct and 52 % of the subjects have 2 or 3 answers correct. Other studies find similar average scores. For instance, the mean score of the whole sample in Frederick (2005) was 1.24 (with a maximum of 2.18 and a minimum of 0.57), whereas Hoppe and Kusterer (2011) and Oechssler et al. (2009) report slightly higher scores of 1.84 and 2.05 among German students, respectively.

  14. The “Bat and Ball” question (BBQ) refers to the following question: A bat and a ball cost 1.10 Euro in total. The bat costs 1.00 Euro more than the ball. How much does the ball cost?

  15. It is also the case that subjects who answered the BBQ correctly were more likely to win the prize (p  =  0.04, χ²-test).

  16. That the BBQ is an important indicator for choices in the BCG is also confirmed by testing the predictive power that each of the three CRT questions provides, conditional on the other questions. That is, including a dummy variable for each correctly answered question reveals that the BBQ has by far the largest the impact on choices in the BCG and we can reject the hypothesis that all three questions are equally predictive (Wald test, p  =  0.058, two sided).

  17. A similar problem may arise by using post-experimental questions. Even though such questions cannot influence behavior in the game, they can induce biased responses because subjects may realize ex-post that the decision environment was strategic. Note that in the BCG it is not possible to distinguish cleanly between non-strategic and strategic behavior, since low numbers might be evidence for both.

  18. It also seems possible that administering the CRT before the BCG makes subjects who gave the correct answers more suspicious and raises their awareness in the subsequent BCG, because giving the correct answer often requires suppressing the intuitive, but wrong answer. Note that, in principle, changing the order of the tasks may lead to the related issue of BCG-play influencing awareness in the CRT. However, as pointed out by a referee, it seems unlikely that a potentially higher awareness due to the task order would only affect subjects with the maximum CRT score of three.

  19. Relatedly, the BBQ (and more generally the CRT) is a good predictor for rational thinking, i.e., individuals’ immunity to cognitive biases (see e.g., Toplak et al. 2011).

  20. Gill and Prowse (2015) find a similar result in an environment that facilitates learning. Using data from a repeated BCG they find that subjects with higher cognitive ability vary their level of reasoning depending on the known cognitive ability of their opponents, whereas low ability subjects do not react at all to the cognitive ability of their opponents. However, they do not find differences between high and low ability subject for initial responses in the BCG.

  21. For example, different framing of instructions may induce strategic awareness. Suggestive evidence comes from 2-person guessing games where the choice of zero is weakly dominant (see e.g., Grosskopf and Nagel 2008). Chou et al. (2009) show that, while standard descriptions of the payoff function leads to frequent violations of weak dominance, framing the game as a “battle”—you win the battle if your chosen location is higher than your opponent’s—improves compliance dramatically. However, their setup leaves open whether subjects just followed the advice in the instructions, or whether the variation indeed induced subjects to reason strategically.

  22. Although we can rule out that our finding is affected by reverse causality because subjects were not aware of the BCG when stating their beliefs about others’ cognitive ability, exogenous variation in beliefs would be useful to account for unobserved factors that may influence subjects’ beliefs about the cognitive skills of others.

References

  • Agarwal, S., & Mazumder, B. (2013). Cognitive abilities and household financial decision making. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(1), 193–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agranov, M., Caplin, A., & Tergiman, C. (2015). Naive play and the process of choice in guessing games. Journal of the Economic Science Association (forthcoming).

  • Agranov, M., Potamites, E., Schotter, A., & Tergiman, C. (2012). Beliefs and endogenous cognitive levels: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 75(2), 449–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alaoui, L., & Penta A. (2015). Endogenous depth of reasoning. Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming).

  • Allred, S., Duffy, S., & Smith, J. (2014). Cognitive load and strategic sophistication. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin, D. J., Brown, S. A., & Shapiro, J. M. (2013). Who is behavioral? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(6), 1231–1255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branas-Garza, P., Garcia-Munoz, T., & Gonzalez, R. (2012). Cognitive effort in the beauty contest game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 83(2), 254–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burchardi, K., & Penczynski, S. (2014). Out of your mind: Eliciting individual reasoning in one shot games. Games and Economic Behavior, 84, 39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burks, S. V., Carpenter, J. P., Goette, L., & Rustichini, A. (2009). Cognitive skills affect economic preferences, strategic behavior, and job attachment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106(19), 7745–7750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, T. C., Cesarini, D., Johannesson, M., Lichtenstein, P., & Wallace, B. (2009). Higher cognitive ability is associated with lower entries in a p-beauty contest. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72(1), 171–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Lovallo, D. (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 89(1), 306–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J., Graham, M., & Wolf, J. (2013). Cognitive ability and strategic sophistication. Games and Economic Behavior, 80, 115–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chater, N., Huck, S., & Inderst, R. (2010). Consumer decision making in retail financial services. Report prepared for SANCO/EC.

  • Chou, E., Margaret, M., Rosemarie, N., & Plott, C. (2009). The control of game form recognition in experiments: Understanding dominant strategy failures in a simple two person “guessing” game. Experimental Economics, 12(2), 159–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christelis, D., Tullio, J., & Padula, M. (2010). Cognitive abilities and portfolio choice. European Economic Review, 54(1), 18–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coricelli, G., & Nagel, R. (2009). Neural correlates of depth of strategic reasoning in medial prefrontal cortex. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: Economic Sciences, 106(23), 9163–9168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Crawford, V. P. (2006). Cognition and behavior in two-person guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1737–1768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, V. P., Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Iriberri, N. (2013). Structural models of nonequilibrium strategic thinking: Theory, evidence, and applications. Journal of Economic Literature, 51(1), 5–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? American Economic Review, 100(3), 1238–1260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H., Keane, M. P., & Silverman, D. (2008). Sources of advantageous selection: Evidence from the medigap insurance market. Journal of Political Economy, 116(2), 303–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, D. (2013). Foregone costly communication and coordination failure. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georganas, S., Healy, P., & Weber, R. (2015). On the persistence of strategic sophistication. Journal of Economic Theory (forthcoming).

  • Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2015). Cognitive ability, character skills, and learning to play equilibrium: A level-k analysis. Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming).

  • Goldfarb, A., & Xiao, M. (2011). Who thinks about the competition? Managerial ability and strategic entry in US local telephone markets. American Economic Review, 101(5), 3130–3161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimm, V., & Mengel, F. (2012). An experiment on learning in a multiple games environment. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(6), 2220–2259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosskopf, B., & Nagel, R. (2008). The two-person beauty contest. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(1), 93–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1998). Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental p-beauty contests. American Economic Review, 88(4), 947–969.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, E., & Kusterer, D. J. (2011). Behavioral biases and cognitive reflection. Economics Letters, 110(2), 97–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., Normann, H.-T., & Oechssler, J. (1999). Learning in cournot oligopoly: An experiment. Economic Journal, 109(454), C80–C95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., & Weizsäcker, G. (1999). Risk, complexity, and deviations from expected-value maximization. Journal of Economic Psychology, 20(6), 699–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderst, R., & Ottaviani, M. (2012). How (not) to pay for advice: A framework for consumer financial protection. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(2), 393–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, A., Spunt, B., & Frederick, S. (2013). The bat and ball problem. New York: Mimeo.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, D. A., & Cain, D. (2007). Overconfidence and underconfidence: When and why people underestimate (and overestimate) the competition. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 103(2), 197–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagel, R. (1995). Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1313–1326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oechssler, J., Roider, A., & Schmitz, P. W. (2009). Cognitive abilities and behavioral biases. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72(1), 147–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strzalecki, T. (2014). Depth of reasoning and higher order beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 108–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toplak, M. E., West, R. F., & Stanovich, K. E. (2011). The cognitive reflection test as a predictor of performance on heuristics-and-biases tasks. Memory and Cognition, 39(7), 1275–1289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the Editor, Jacob Goeree, and two anonymous reviewers for thoughtful comments. We are also grateful to Terry Burnham, Brit Grosskopf, Rosemarie Nagel, Joerg Oechssler and Andrew Schotter for helpful conversations as well as seminar participants for comments. We thank David Cesarini, Pablo Branas-Garza and Teresa Garcia-Munoz for sharing their data. Financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) through the SFB 649 “Economic Risk” is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dietmar Fehr.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 133 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fehr, D., Huck, S. Who knows it is a game? On strategic awareness and cognitive ability. Exp Econ 19, 713–726 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9461-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9461-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation