Skip to main content
Log in

Measures to enhance the success of global climate treaties

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze important forces that hamper the formation of successful self-enforcing agreements to mitigate global warming from an economic point of view. The analysis combines two modules: (a) an integrated assessment model that captures the feedback between the economy, environmental damages and the climate system and (b) a game theoretic model that determines stable coalitions in the presence of free-riding incentives. We consider two types of measures to enhance the success of international environmental treaty-making: (a) transfers, aiming at balancing asymmetric gains from cooperation; (b) institutional changes, aiming at making it more difficult to upset stability of a treaty. We find that institutional changes may be as important as transfers and should therefore receive more attention in future international negotiations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A notable exception is for instance Bosello, Buchner, and Carraro (2003).

  2. An overview of the equations and parameters of the model is provided in the Appendix. A more detailed exposition of the model can be found in Eyckmans and Tulkens (2003).

  3. We choose a sufficiently long time period to avoid “end point bias”. However, due to discounting, only a shorter period is strategically relevant for players.

  4. The mirror image is: abatement constitutes a positive externality. See Subsect. 3.2.

  5. This assumption is widely made in coalition theory. See Bloch (1997) and Yi (1997).

  6. That is, the calibration of our model implies that there are leakage effects but they are relatively small. In other words, the slope of the reaction function of regions is negative but the absolute value is less than one. This is in line with the assumptions of most theoretical models. See Finus (2003).

  7. The concept of internal & external stability that we apply is due to d’ Aspremont et al. (1983). It is de facto a Nash equilibrium where no player has an incentive to revise his decision about membership. For an overview of other concepts applied in the environmental context, see Finus (2003). Note that the fundamental difference to the γ-core applied in Eyckmans and Tulkens (2003) is related to internal stability. Internal stability implies that if a member of coalition S left, the remaining coalition members \({\hbox{S}\backslash \{\hbox{i}\}}\) would stick together whereas the γ-core assumes that \({\hbox{S}\backslash \{\hbox{i}\}}\) would break apart. Given the fact that coalition formation exhibits a positive externality on outsiders (due to increased abatement efforts by the coalition), the implicit punishment after a member of S leaves this coalition is stronger for the γ-core than for internal stability. This explains why in the presence of free-rider incentives the grand coalition is usually not internally stable though it lies in the core. See Tulkens (1998) and Finus and Rundshagen (2006) for details.

  8. This procedure is valid because we assume a lump sum transfer of discounted payoffs for simplicity. That is, transfers have no effect on equilibrium economic strategy vectors in our framework, i.e., the game is a transferable utility game (TU-game) as assumed almost throughout the literature on coalition formation. A formal proof can be found in Eyckmans and Tulkens (2003).

  9. “Total transfers” in the last column of Table 3 are the sum of all positive transfers (=sum of all negative transfers) but not the sum of all transfers that are zero by definition. Total transfers are an indicator of the amount of financial resources redistributed by the transfer scheme. It is important to note that because transfers are computed according to (5) it can happen that total transfers exceed the total gain from cooperation. For instance, suppose \({\hbox{W}_{\rm i} (\hbox{c}^{\rm N})-\hbox{W}_{\rm i} \left( \hbox{c} \right) > 0}\) and λi = 1, then \({\hbox{t}_{\rm i} (\hbox{c}) > \sum\nolimits_{{\rm i}\in {\rm S}} {\left[ {\hbox{W}_{\rm i}\left( \hbox{c} \right)-\hbox{W}_{\rm i}(\hbox{c}^{\rm N})} \right]} }\).

  10. The γ-core also assumes a best reply after player I has left coalition S but \({\hbox{S}\backslash \{\hbox{i}\}}\) breaks apart implying lower abatement by these players and hence harsher punishment. See endnote 7.

References

  • Barrett, S. (1994). Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 804–878.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (1997) Heterogeneous international environmental agreements. In C. Carraro (Ed.), International environmental negotiations: Strategic policy issues (pp. 9–25). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2001). International cooperation for sale. European Economic Review, 45, 1835–1850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F. (1997). Non-cooperative models of coalition formation in games with spillovers. In C. Carraro, & D. Siniscalco (Eds.), New directions in the economic theory of the environment (ch. 10, pp. 311–352). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Böhringer, C., & Vogt, C. (2004). The dismantling of a breakthrough: The Kyoto protocol as symbolic policy. European Journal of Political Economy, 20, 597–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosello, F., Buchner, B., & Carraro, C. (2003). Equity, development, and climate change control. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1, 601–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botteon, M., & Carraro, C. (1997). Burden-sharing and coalition stability in environmental negotiations with asymmetric countries. In C. Carraro (Ed.), International environmental negotiations: Strategic policy issues (ch. 3, pp. 26–55). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

  • Carraro C. (2000). Roads towards international environmental agreements. In H. Siebert (Ed.), The economics of international environmental problems (pp. 169–202). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carraro, C., & Siniscalco, D. (1993). Strategies for the international protection of the environment. Journal of Public Economics, 52, 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chander, P., & Tulkens, H. (1997). The core of an economy with multilateral environmental externalities. International Journal of Game Theory, 26, 379–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

  • d’Aspremont, C., Jacquemin, A., Gabszewicz, J. J., & Weymark, J. A. (1983). On the stability of collusive price leadership. Canadian Journal of Economics, 16, 17–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Endres, A. (1997). Negotiating a climate convention – the role of prices and quantities. International Review of Law and Economics, 17, 147–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyckmans, J., & Tulkens, H. (2003). Simulating coalitionally stable burden sharing agreements for the climate change problem. Resource and Energy Economics, 25, 299–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finus, M. (2003). Stability and design of international environmental agreements: The case of transboundary pollution. In H. Folmer, & T. Tietenberg (Eds.), International yearbook of environmental and resource economics (2003/4, ch. 3, pp. 82–158). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

  • Finus, M., & Rundshagen, B. (2003). Endogenous coalition formation in global pollution control. A partition function approach. In C. Carraro (Ed.), Endogenous formation of economic coalitions (ch. 6, pp. 199–241). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

  • Finus, M., & Rundshagen, B. (2006). A micro-foundation of core-stability in positive externality coalition games. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 162, 329–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finus, M., & Tjøtta, S. (2003). The Oslo protocol on sulfur reduction: The great leap forward? Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2031–2048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Germain, M., Toint, P. L., & Tulkens, H. (1998). Financial transfers to ensure cooperative international optimality in stock pollutant abatement. In S. Faucheux, J. Gowdy, & I. Nicolaï (Eds.), Sustainability and firms: Technological change and the changing regulatory environment (ch. 11, pp. 205–219). Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar.

  • Hoel, M. (1992). International environment conventions: The case of uniform reductions of emissions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 2, 141–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoel, M., & Schneider, K. (1997). Incentives to participate in an international environmental agreement. Environmental and Resource Economics, 9, 153–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2001). Climate change 2001: Mitigation (Contribution of working group III to the third assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Joos, F., Müller-Fürstenberger, G., & Stephan, G. (1999). Correcting the carbon cycle representation: How important is it for the economics of climate change? Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 4, 133–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, R. K. (1997). Assessing the DICE model: Uncertainty associated with the emission and retention of greenhouse gases. Climatic Change, 35, 435–448.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Kemfert, C., & Tol, R. (2002). Equity, international trade and climate policy. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 2, 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller-Fürstenberger, G., & Stephan, G. (1997). Environmental policy and cooperation beyond the nation state: An introduction and overview. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 8, 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (1997a). Voluntary cutbacks and pretreaty behavior: The Helsinki protocol and sulfur emissions. Public Finance Review, 25, 139–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (1997b). The voluntary provision of a pure public good: The case of reduced CFC emissions and the Montreal protocol. Journal of Public Economics, 63, 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W., & Yang, Z. (1996). A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies. American Economic Review, 86, 741–765.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., Cline, W. R., Achanta, A. N., Fankhauser, S., Pachauri, R. K., Tol, R. S. J., & Vellinga, P. (1996). The social costs of climate change: greenhouse damage and the benefits of control. In J. P. Bruce, H. Lee, & E. F. Haites (Eds.), Climate change 1995: Economic and social dimensions—contribution of working group III to the second assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change (pp. 179–224). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A., & Stevens, B. (1998). A dynamic analysis of fairness in global warming policies: Kyoto, Buenos Aires, and Beyond. Journal of Applied Economics, 1, 329–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A., Stevens, B., Edmonds, J., & Wise, M. (1998). International equity and differentiation in global warming policy. Environmental and Resource Economics, 12, 25–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, B., & Rose, A. (2002). A dynamic analysis of the marketable permits approach to global warming policy: A comparison of spatial and temporal flexibility. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44, 45–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol, R. (2005). The marginal damage costs of carbon dioxide emissions: an assessment of the uncertainties. Energy Policy, 33, 2064–2074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tulkens, H. (1998). Cooperation versus free-riding in international environmental affairs: Two approaches. In N. Hanley & H. Folmer (Eds.), Game theory and the environment (ch. 2, pp. 30–44). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

  • Weikard, H.-P., Finus, M., & Altamirano-Cabrera, J.-C. (2006). The impact of surplus sharing on the stability of international climate agreements. Oxford Economic Papers, 58, 209–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. L. (2001). Gamma discounting. American Economic Review, 91, 260–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weyant J., & Hill, J. N. (1999). Introduction and overview. Energy Journal Special Issue: The costs of the Kyoto protocol: A multi-model evaluation, vii–xliv.

  • Yi, S.-S. (1997). Stable coalition structures with externalities. Games and Economic Behavior, 20, 201–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This paper has been written while M. Finus was a visiting scholar at the Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Centrum voor Economische Studiën (Leuven, Belgium) and at Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, FEEM (Venice, Italy). He acknowledges the financial support by the CLIMNEG 2 project funded by the Belgian Federal Science Policy Office and the kind hospitality of FEEM. Both authors acknowledge research assistance by Carmen Dunsche.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Finus.

Appendix

Appendix

The CLIMNEG World Simulation Model comprises the following equations:

$$ \begin{aligned} \hbox{Y}_{\rm i,t} &=\hbox{Z}_{\rm i,t} +\hbox{I}_{\rm i,t} +\hbox{Y}_{\rm i,t} \hbox{C}_{\rm i} (\mu_{\rm i,t} )+\hbox{Y}_{\rm i,t} \hbox{D}_{\rm i} (\Delta \hbox{T}_{\rm t} )\\ \hbox{Y}_{\rm i,t} &=\hbox{a}_{\rm i,t} \hbox{K}_{\rm i,t}^\gamma \hbox{L}_{\rm i,t}^{1-\gamma }\\ \hbox{C}_{\rm i}(\mu_{\rm i,t} )&=\hbox{b}_{\rm i,1} \mu_{\rm i,t}^{{\rm b}_{\rm i,2} }\\ \hbox{D}_{\rm i} (\Delta \hbox{T}_{\rm t} )&=\theta _{\rm i,1} \Delta \hbox{T}_{\rm t}^{\theta _{\rm i,2}}\\ \hbox{K}_{\rm i,t+1} &=\left[ {1-\delta _{\rm K} } \right]\hbox{K}_{\rm i,t} +\hbox{I}_{\rm i,t} \quad\quad\;\;\;\hbox{K}_{\rm i,0}\;\;\hbox{given}\\ \hbox{E}_{\rm i,t}&=\alpha_{\rm i,t}\left[{1-\mu_{\rm i,t} } \right]\hbox{Y}_{\rm i,t}\\ \hbox{M}_{\rm t+1} &=\left[ {1-\delta _{\rm M}} \right]\hbox{M}_{\rm t} +\beta \sum\limits_{{\rm i}\in {\rm N}}{\hbox{E}_{\rm i,t} \quad\hbox{M}_{0}\,\;\hbox{given}}\\ \hbox{F}_{\rm t} &=\frac{4.1\,\ln(\hbox{M}_{\rm t})}{\ln (2)}+\hbox{F}_{\rm t}^{\rm x}\\ \hbox{T}_{\rm t}^0 &=\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^0 +\tau _3 \left[ {\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^{\rm a} -\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^0 } \right]\\ \hbox{T}_{\rm t}^{\rm a} &=\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^{\rm a}+\tau_1 \left[ {\hbox{F}_{\rm t}-\lambda \hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^{\rm a} } \right]-\tau _2 \left[ {\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^{\rm a} -\hbox{T}_{\rm t-1}^0 }\right]\\ \Delta\hbox{T}_{\rm t}&=\frac{\hbox{T}_{\rm t}^{\rm a}}{2.50}\\ \end{aligned} $$
Table 4 List of variables
Table 5 Global parameter values
Table 6 Regional parameter values
Table 7 Variables in 1990 (reference year)a

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Eyckmans, J., Finus, M. Measures to enhance the success of global climate treaties. Int Environ Agreements 7, 73–97 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-006-9030-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-006-9030-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation