Skip to main content
Log in

Entrepreneurship and country-level innovation: investigating the role of entrepreneurial opportunities

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Since the work of Schumpeter, entrepreneurship has been regarded as a concept that is in close relation to innovation. However, recent country level investigations show that technology innovation and new business creation can be regarded as two separate phenomena. In this paper we provide an explanation for the above contradiction through the distinguishing between two types of entrepreneurship, necessity and opportunity entrepreneurship. Building on opportunity theory and rational choice theory, we investigate the influence of both types of entrepreneurship on country-level innovation, and furthermore, pay particular attention to the interaction between opportunity entrepreneurship and the amount of opportunities available. We find that necessity entrepreneurship is inversely related to country-level innovation, whereas opportunity entrepreneurship is positively linked to technological progress. The positive effect of opportunity entrepreneurship, however, diminishes with an increased amount of entrepreneurial opportunities. This interaction indicates that opportunity availability is an important element of a country’s entrepreneurship environment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is foremost true for the earlier works of Joseph Schumpeter which are sometimes referred to as Schumpeter mark I. The authors are aware that in his later works Schumpeter increasingly acknowledged the meaning of large and established companies for innovation. As this paper is focused on entrepreneurship it is taking the Schumpeter mark I perspective in order to differentiate Schumpeterian entrepreneurship characterized by innovation from non-innovative types of entrepreneurship (e.g. Kirznerian). Thus, Schumpeter mark II is not taken into consideration. This, however, should not be regarded as conflictive as in both perspectives “entrepreneurial activities play an active role in understanding the dynamics of innovation…” (Hagedoorn 1996, p. 883).

  2. It is worth noting that GEM surveys allow for choosing a different motivation than opportunity and necessity (Reynolds et al. 2002). Therefore, necessity and opportunity entrepreneurship indeed catch the vast majority of entrepreneurship activities in a country but cannot mirror the whole entrepreneurship landscape (Reynolds et al. 2002). Due to the circumstance that in some countries significant shares of entrepreneurs indicated neither necessity nor opportunity entrepreneurship as the main motivation, we do not treat the two dimensions as exclusive but investigate both of them in order to get a clearer picture of a country’s entrepreneurship structure.

  3. Using the absolute value of necessity/opportunity entrepreneurship might lead to biased results. Research has shown that opportunities vary in their quality as they encompass both imitative/arbitrage and innovative opportunities (Shane 2009; Anokhin and Wincent 2012). Thereby, in countries with traditionally low shares of opportunity entrepreneurship (e.g. least developed and developing countries), opportunities are expected to be of an inferior quality (Acemoglu et al. 2006; Anokhin et al. 2011; Anokhin and Wincent 2012) as entrepreneurs come with simple businesses in the form of arbitrage opportunities rather than innovative opportunities. The relatively low meaning of high quality opportunity entrepreneurship in those countries, however, is diluted by multiplying it with the total entrepreneurial activity which is traditionally high in least developed countries. To give a more realistic picture of the opportunity entrepreneurship landscape we take into account the relative prevalence of necessity/opportunity entrepreneurship instead of the absolute value.

  4. World Bank reports data for the years 2012 and 2013. In case data were available for both years the average figure is taken.

  5. E.g. the higher the quality of the institutional business framework, the higher the ranking position of a country and thus the smaller the measure used. For example, the country with the lowest ranking position in the analyzed period is Angola, which ranked 151st in 2012 and 153rd in 2013 (average: 152). The country with the highest ranking is Singapore which ranked 1st in 2012 and 2013.

  6. Controlling for the lagged values of Y.

  7. Controlling for the lagged values of X.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., & Zilibotti, F. (2006). Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1), 37–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z., Autio, E., & Szerb, L. (2014). National systems of entrepreneurship: Measurement issues and policy implications. Research Policy, 43(3), 476–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aidis, R., Estrin, S., & Mickiewicz, T. (2012). Size matters: Entrepreneurial entry and government. Small Business Economics, 39, 119–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, S., & Barney, J. (2007). Discovery and creation: Alternative theories of entrepreneurial action. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 1(1–2), 11–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anokhin, S., & Schulze, W. (2009). Entrepreneurship, innovation and corruption. Journal of Business Venturing, 24, 465–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anokhin, S., & Wincent, J. (2012). Start-up rates and innovation: A cross-country investigation. Journal of International Business Studies, 43, 41–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anokhin, S., Wincent, J., & Autio, E. (2011). Operationalizing opportunities in entrepreneurship research: Use of data envelopment analysis. Small Business Economics, 37, 39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colantone, I., & Sleuwaegen, L. (2010). International trade, exit and entry: A cross-country and industry analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(7), 1240–1257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drucker, P. (1985). Innovation and entrepreneurship: Practice and principles. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckhardt, J., & Shane, S. (2003). Opportunities and entrepreneurship. Journal of Management, 29(3), 333–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, L., & Yli-Renko, H. (2010). The Impact of environment and entrepreneurial perceptions on venture-creation efforts: Bridging the discovery and creation views of entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 34(5), 833–856.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furman, J. L., Porter, M. E., & Stern, S. (2002). The determinants of national innovative capacity. Research Policy, 31, 899–933.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. (1969). Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods. Econometrica, 37, 424–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregoire, D., & Shepherd, D. (2012). Technology-market combinations and the identification of entrepreneurial opportunities: An investigation of the opportunity-individual nexus. Academy of Management Journal, 55(4), 753–785.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, M., MacMillan, I., & Thompson, J. (2008). Look before you leap: Market opportunity identification in emerging technology firms. Management Science, 54(9), 1652–1665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagedoorn, J. (1996). Innovation and entrepreneurship: Schumpeter revisited. Industrial and Corporate Change, 5(3), 883–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hair, J., Black, W., Babin, B., Andersen, R., & Tatham, R. (2006). Multivariate data analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2003). The origins of entrepreneurial opportunities. The Review of Austrian Economics, 16(1), 25–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javorcik, B., & Spatareanu, M. (2008). To share or not to share: Does local participation matter for spillovers from foreign direct investment? Journal of Development Economics, 85(1–2), 194–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelley, D., Bosma, N., & Amoros, J. (2011). Global entrepreneurship monitor: 2010 Global report. Boston, MA: Global Entrepreneurship Research Association, Babson College.

  • Kirzner, I. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1997). Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 60–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Augustus Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koellinger, P. (2008). Why are some entrepreneurs more innovative than others? Small Business Economics, 31, 21–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, N. (2000). The cognitive infrastructure of opportunity emergence. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 24(3), 5–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 508–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. (2007). Law and the economics of entrepreneurship. Comparative Labor Law and Policy Journal, 28, 695–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, P., Camp, M., Bygrave, W., Autio, E., & Hay, M. (2002). Global entrepreneurship monitor 2001 executive report. Boston, MA: Global Entrepreneurship Research Association, Babson College.

  • Sarason, Y., Dean, T., & Dillard, J. (2005). Entrepreneurship as the nexus of individual and opportunity: A structuration view. Journal of Business Venturing, 21, 286–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarasvathy, S. (2001). Causation and effectuation: Toward a theoretical shift from economic inevitability to entrepreneurial contingency. Academy of Management Review, 26(2), 243–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital credit, interest, and the business cycle. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. (2003). A general theory of entrepreneurship. Glos, Northampton: US Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. (2009). Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business Economics, 33(2), 141–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S., & Eckhardt, J. (2005). The individual-opportunity nexus. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurial research: An interdisciplinary survey and introduction. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review, 25(1), 217–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thurik, R., Carree, M., Van Stel, A., & Audretsch, D. (2008). Does self-employment reduce unemployment? Journal of Business Venturing, 23, 673–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaghely, I., & Julien, P. (2010). Are opportunities recognized or constructed? An information perspective on entrepreneurial opportunity identification. Journal of Business Venturing, 25, 73–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Stel, A., Carree, M., & Thurik, R. (2005). The effect of entrepreneurial activity on national economic growth. Small Business Economics, 24(3), 311–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venkataraman, S. (1997). The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research. In J. Katz & R. Brockhaus (Eds.), Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence and growth, 3. Greenwich: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wennekers, S., van Stel, A., Thurik, R., & Reynolds, P. (2005). Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic development. Small Business Economics, 24, 293–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong, P., Ho, Y., & Autio, E. (2005). Entrepreneurship, innovation and economic growth: Evidence from GEM data. Small Business Economics, 24, 335–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthias Mrożewski.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Year-to-year correlations of GCI Innovation measures for the years 2006/2007–2013/2014

 

GCI2006/2007

GCI2007/2008

GCI2008/2009

GCI2009/2010

GCI2010/2011

GCI2011/2012

GCI2012/2013

GCI2013/2014

GCI2006/2007

1

       

GCI2007/2008

.992**

1

      

GCI2008/2009

.985**

.992**

1

     

GCI2009/2010

.978**

.977**

.991**

1

    

GCI2010/2011

.977**

.972**

.981**

.992**

1

   

GCI2011/2012

.969**

.965**

.971**

.978**

.990**

1

  

GCI2012/2013

.952**

.952**

.958**

.962**

.971**

.986**

1

 

GCI2013/2014

.940**

.936**

.937**

.947**

.956**

.974**

.990**

1

  1. ** Significant at 0.1 %

Appendix 2: Entrepreneurial opportunity availability across countries

Measured by the GEM indicator “Perceived opportunities”: percentage of the working age population (18–64 years) who see good opportunities to start a firm in the area where they live, averages 2001–2012.

figure a

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mrożewski, M., Kratzer, J. Entrepreneurship and country-level innovation: investigating the role of entrepreneurial opportunities. J Technol Transf 42, 1125–1142 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-016-9479-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-016-9479-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation