Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How does the age structure of worker flows affect firm performance?

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a method for decomposing firm performance to impacts coming from the inflows and outflows of workers and apply it to study whether older workers are costly to firms. Our estimation equations are derived from a variant of the decomposition methods frequently used for measuring micro-level sources of industry productivity growth. By using comprehensive linked employer–employee data, we study the productivity and wage effects, and hence the profitability effects, of the hiring and separation of younger and older workers. The evidence shows that the separations of older workers are profitable to firms, especially in the manufacturing ICT-industries. To account for the correlation of the worker flows and productivity shocks we first estimate the shocks from a production function using materials as a proxy variable. In the second step the estimated shock is used as a control variable in our productivity, wage, and profitability equations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There is a field of literature where the determinants of hiring and employing older workers are analyzed (e.g. Hutchens 1986, 1988; Aubert et al. 2006; Daniel and Heywood 2007; Ilmakunnas and Ilmakunnas 2015).

  2. One dictionary definition of the adjective dysfunctional is “characterized by a breakdown of normal or beneficial relationships between members of the group” (http://www.collinsdictionary.com).

  3. The positive influences of turnover have been emphasized more formally in models where the search and matching process allocates workers to their best uses in firms (e.g. Jovanovic 1979). Worker flows and the matching process may be particularly important for productivity when technological change is rapid (see e.g. Aghion and Howitt 1996).

  4. Vandenberghe (2010) has adopted our decomposition approach.

  5. Often the labor input is disaggregated by using parameters that measure the relative productivities of the worker types (e.g. Hellerstein, Neumark and Troske 1999). In this case, the production function is Y = f(θ 1 L 1 + ··· + θ M L M ) and the productivity terms are \( g_{j} = \left. {\theta_{j} f^{\prime}_{j} } \right|_{{X^{0} }} \).

  6. The decomposition is related to those used commonly in firm or plant-level productivity analysis (e.g. J. Haltiwanger 1997), but is closer to those used by Maliranta (1997), Vainiomäki (1999), Maliranta and Ilmakunnas (2005) as well as Diewert and Fox (2009) in different contexts.

  7. Our profit variable, the ratio of revenues and costs, is related to profitability measures used in productivity analysis (e.g. Balk 2010; Althin et al. 1996), where it is sometimes called “return to the dollar”. If we consider only value added and assume capital fixed in the short run, our measure is the ratio of net revenue (value added Y) and variable costs. It can also be interpreted as a mark-up. Assume that firms set price equal to unit labor cost multiplied by a mark-up 1 + m, so that we have revenue Y = (1 + m)W(1 + a). The operating margin can be written as OPM = Y − W(1 + a= (1 + m)W(1 + a) − W(1 + a) = mW(1 + a), and the profit variable equals Π = 1 + m.

  8. The decomposition model is based on the assumption of constant returns to scale, but deviations from constant returns would show up as heteroscedasticity.

  9. We leave out the period 1990–1994, because our company data are substantially less comprehensive before the year 1995.

  10. These dummies also account for changes in the payroll taxes a, which were assumed fixed in the derivation of the formulas in Sect. 3.

  11. There is some measurement error because temporary agency workers or those with an atypical employment relationship, like service contract, are not included in the employment of the firms. According to the Finnish Private Employment Agencies Association, their employees accounted for only 1 % of total employment in 2010, which is below the European average. This share has been increasing in recent years, but it was still low in the period of our analysis. This kind of employment is more common in services. This is one reason why we estimate the models also by sector (industry and services). In principle, owner-managers can also cause measurement error. For small firms where the owner is working, he is included in the number of employees only if he takes at least half of his income as salary (as opposed to capital income). In any case, the restrictions we use (i.e., leaving out firms with less than ten employees and firms with missing employer-firm link) mean that this measurement error should not be large. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out these issues to us.

  12. The proxy variable approach is based on the assumption that capital is inherited from the previous period, and the proxy variable (materials) and labor choices happen after the shock is realized. Therefore, the latter variables are endogenous, but capital stock itself is not.

  13. Some of the firms operate in more than one region. The region of a firm refers to the one where the employment share is the highest.

  14. The number of observations drops because of the reasons discussed in the text.

  15. Note that these figures underestimate actual turnover among the employees, since e.g. hiring of an employee after the start of a period and subsequent separation of the same employee before the end of the period is not included in the turnover rates.

  16. There are two main reasons why we prefer using employment weighted estimation. Firstly, we are ultimately concerned of productivity differences between different employment groups. Unfortunately we are unable to measure productivity at the level individuals but only at the level of firms so that in a sense we are using aggregated data. In order to give an equal weight for each individual in our analysis, we should give a larger weight to large firms than to smaller firms. Second, weighted estimation provides us with a more efficient procedure in the presence of heteroscedasticity.

  17. In the Finnish pension system the pension was until 1996 based on the last four years’ pay and until 2004 on the last ten year’s pay in each employment relationship, which gave incentives for obtaining a high pay at the end of the career. This combination of backloaded wage and a fixed retirement age is consistent with the deferred payment model of Lazear (1979), although it is a result of a quite different institutional setting. The system has been based on a mix of centralized negotiations between labor unions, employer organizations and the government, and firm-level wage setting. Lazear’s argument is somewhat difficult to use in the connection of labor flows, as it is an equilibrium model where the raising wage profile and unprofitability of the older employees is part of the “package”. However, even in this case unexpected increases in the costs of older employees or an increase in the share of older employees through aging may make the system unsustainable and give raise to incentives for separations.

  18. The probability of exit was modelled as a function of firm size, industry, employee characteristics (average tenure and education years, share of women), capital-labor ratio, productivity shock, and an indicator for growing firms. All of these variables were measured in the year prior to exit.

  19. In addition to the unemployment pension system, also disability pension gives incentives for laying off older employees. The larger firms are responsible for paying (part of) the disability pension until the normal retirement age. This can be avoided, if the worker goes to the unemployment pension tunnel before possible disability.

  20. See discussion in Daveri (2004). The results obtained by using the broad definition of ICT are available on request. It should be noted that “Financial intermediation” (ISIC 65–67) industries are excluded from our estimation sample.

  21. Also the econometric framework could be extended. We have used the proxy variable approach indirectly by estimating the shock from a level form and then using it in our difference form model. It remains an open issue how the approach could be directly applied to our model in one step. Also extensions to for example stochastic frontier models would be interesting.

References

  • Abowd JM, Kramarz F (1999) The analysis of labor markets using matched employer–employee data. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3b. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 2629–2710

    Google Scholar 

  • Ackerberg D, Benkard CL, Berry S, Pakes A (2007) Econometric tools for analyzing market outcomes. In: Heckman JJ, Leamer EE (eds) Handbook of econometrics, vol 6. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 4171–4276

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1996) The observational implications of Schumpeterian growth theory. Empir Econ 21:13–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Althin R, Färe R, Grosskopf S (1996) Profitability and productivity changes: an application to Swedish pharmacies. Ann Oper Res 66:219–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert P, Crépon B (2003) La productivité des salariés âgés: une tentative d’estimation. Écon Stat 368:95–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert P, Caroli E, Roger M (2006) New technologies, organisations and age: firm-level evidence. Econ J 116:73–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balk BM (2010) Measuring productivity change without neoclassical assumptions: a conceptual analysis. In: Diewert WE, Balk BM, Fixler D, Fox KJ, Nakamura A (eds) Price and productivity measurement, vol 6., Index Number TheoryTrafford Press, Victoria, pp 133–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Balk BM (2016) The dynamics of productivity change: a review of the bottom-up approach. In: Greene WH, Khalaf LC, Sickles, R, Veall M, Voia MC (eds) Productivity and Efficiency Analysis, Springer Proceedings in Business and Economics, pp 15–49

  • Balsvik R (2011) Is labor mobility a channel for spillovers from multinationals? Evidence from Norwegian manufacturing. Rev Econ Stat 93:285–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bingley P, Westergaard-Nielsen N (2004) Personnel policy and profit. J Bus Res 57:557–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R, Eriksson R, Lindgren U (2009) How does labour mobility affect the performance of plants? The importance of relatedness and geographical proximity. J Econ Geogr 9:169–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cataldi A, Kampelmann S, Rycx F (2011) Productivity-wage gaps among age groups: does the ICT environment matter? De Economist 159:193–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton DR, Todor WD, Krackhardt DM (1982) Turnover overstated: the functional taxonomy. Acad Manag Rev 7:117–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniel K, Heywood JS (2007) The determinants of hiring older workers: UK evidence. Labour Econ 14:35–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daveri F (2004) Delayed IT usage: is it really the drag on Europe’s productivity. CESifo Econ Stud 50:397–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daveri F, Maliranta M (2007) Age, seniority and labour costs: lessons from Finnish IT revolution. Econ Policy 22:117–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Fox KA (2009) On measuring the contribution of entering and exiting firms to aggregate productivity growth. In: Diewert WE, Balk BM, Fixler D, Fox KJ, Nakamura A (eds) Price and productivity measurement, vol 6., Index number theoryTrafford Press, Victoria, pp 41–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Krizan CJ (2001) Aggregate productivity growth: lessons from microeconomic evidence. In: Hulten CR, Dean ER, Harper MJ (eds) New developments in productivity analysis. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 303–363

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Foster L, Haltiwanger J, Syverson C (2008) Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: selection on productivity or profitability? Am Econ Rev 98:394–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Göbel C, Zwick T (2012) Age and productivity: sector differences. De Economist 160:35–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Göbel C, Zwick T (2013) Are personnel measures effective in increasing productivity of old workers? Labour Econ 22:80–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Mairesse J (1998) Production functions: the search for identification. In: Strøm R (ed) Econometrics and economic theory in the twentieth century: the Ragnar Frisch Centennial symposium. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 169–203

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hadi AS (1992) Identifying multiple outliers in multivariate data. J R Stat Soc B 54:761–771

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadi AS (1994) A modification of a method for the detection of outliers in multivariate samples. J R Stat Soc B 56:393–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakola T, Uusitalo R (2005) Not so voluntary retirement decisions? Evidence from a pension reform. J Public Econ 89:2121–2136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger J (1997) Measuring and analyzing aggregate fluctuations: the importance of building from microeconomic evidence. Fed Reserve Bank St. Louis Econ Rev 79:55–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger JC, Lane JI, Spletzer JR (1999) Productivity differences across employers: the roles of employer size, age, and human capital. Am Econ Rev 89:94–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger JC, Lane JI, Spletzer JR (2007) Wages, productivity, and the dynamic interaction of businesses and workers. Labour Econ 14:575–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein JK, Neumark D (2007) Production function and wage equation estimation with heterogeneous labor: Evidence from a new matched employer–employee data set. In: Berndt ER, Hulten CM (eds) Hard to measure goods and services: essays in honor of Zvi Griliches. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 31–71

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein JK, Neumark D, Troske KR (1999) Wages, productivity, and worker characteristics: evidence from plant-level production functions and wage equations. J Labor Econ 17:409–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchens R (1986) Delayed payment contracts and a firm’s propensity to hire older workers. J Labor Econ 4:439–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchens R (1988) Do job opportunities decline with age? Ind Labor Relat Rev 42:89–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, Ilmakunnas S (2015) Hiring older employees: do the age limits of early retirement and the contribution rates of firms matter? Scand J Econ 117:164–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, Maliranta M (2005) Technology, labour characteristics and wage-productivity gaps. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67:623–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, Maliranta M, Vainiomäki J (2004) The roles of employer and employee characteristics for plant productivity. J Prod Anal 21:249–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, Maliranta M, Vainiomäki J (2005) Worker turnover and productivity growth. Appl Econ Lett 12:395–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas P, van Ours J, Skirbekk V, Weiss M (2010) Age and productivity. In: Garibaldi P, Martins JO, van Ours J (eds) Ageing, health, and productivity: the economics of increased life expectancy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 133–240

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1979) Job matching and the theory of turnover. J Polit Econ 87:972–990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser U, Kongsted HC, Rønde T (2015) Does the mobility of R&D labor increase innovation? J Econ Behav Organ 110:91–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kronenberg K, Carree M (2010) The effects of workforce composition, labor turnover, and the qualities of entering and exiting workers on productivity growth. Maastrict University, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Kyyrä T, Wilke RA (2007) Reduction in the long-term unemployment of the elderly: a success story from Finland. J Eur Econ Assoc 5:154–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear EP (1979) Why is there mandatory retirement? J Polit Econ 87:1261–1284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70:317–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahlberg B, Freund I, Crespo Cuaresma J, Prskawetz A (2013a) Ageing, productivity and wages in Austria. Labour Econ 22:5–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahlberg B, Freund I, Crespo Cuaresma J, Prskawetz A (2013b) The age-productivity pattern: do location and sector affiliation matter? J Econ Ageing 1–2:72–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maliranta M (1997) Plant-level explanations for the catch-up process in Finnish manufacturing: A decomposition of aggregate labour productivity growth. In: Laaksonen S (ed) The evolution of firms and industries. International perspectives. Stat Finl, Helsinki, pp 352–369

    Google Scholar 

  • Maliranta M, Ilmakunnas P (2005) Decomposing productivity and wage effects of intra-establishment labor restructuring. ETLA Discussion Papers No. 993, Helsinki

  • Maliranta M, Mohnen P, Rouvinen P (2009) Is inter-firm labor mobility a channel of knowledge spillovers? Evidence form a linked employer–employee panel. Ind Corp Change 18:1161–1191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munnell AH, Sass SA (2008) Working longer. The solution to the retirement income challenge. Brookings Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Phelps ES (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 56:69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Olley GS, Pakes A (1996) The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica 64:1263–1297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parrotta P, Pozzoli D (2012) The effect of learning by hiring on productivity. RAND J Econ 43:167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siebert WS, Zubanov N (2009) Searching for the optimal level of employee turnover: a study of a large U.K. retail organization. Acad Manag J 52:294–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skirbekk V (2008) Age and productivity potential: a new approach based on ability levels and industry-wide task demand. Pop Dev Rev 34(Supplement):191–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoyanov A, Zubanov N (2012) Productivity spillovers across firms through worker mobility. Am Econ J Appl Econ 4:168–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Towers Perrin (2005) The business case for workers age 50+. AARP, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Vainiomäki J (1999) Technology and skill upgrading: results from linked worker-plant data for Finnish manufacturing. In: Haltiwanger J, Lane J, Spletzer JR, Theuwes JM, Troske KR (eds) The creation and analysis of employer–employee matched data. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 115–145

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • van Ark B, Inklaar R, McGuckin R (2003) ICT and productivity in Europe and the United States. Where do the differences come from? CESifo Econ Stud 49:295–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Dalen HP, Henkens K, Schippers J (2010) Productivity of older workers: perceptions of employers and employees. Popul Dev Rev 36:309–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Ours JC, Stoeldraijer L (2011) Age, wage and productivity in Dutch manufacturing. De Economist 159:113–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandenberghe V (2010) Shed the oldies … it’s profitable. Universite Catholique de Louvain, Mimeo

  • Vandenberghe V (2013) Are firms willing to employ a greying and feminizing workforce? Labour Econ 22:30–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandenberghe V, Waltenberg F, Rigo M (2013) Ageing and employability. Evidence from Belgian firm-level data. J Prod Anal 40:111–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are thankful to many individuals at Statistics Finland, and especially to Satu Nurmi and Elias Einiö for their guidance regarding the properties of the data. The data set is publicly available for research purposes, subject to terms and conditions of confidentiality, at the Research Services unit of Statistics Finland; contact tutkijapalvelut@stat.fi, for access to these data. We have benefited from the comments of Roope Uusitalo and seminar participants at the VATT Institute for Economic Research (Helsinki), Nordic Summer Institute in Labor Economics in Uppsala, EEA Congress in Vienna, CAED Conference in Chicago, Annual Meeting of the Finnish Society for Economic Research in Helsinki, World Aging and Generations Congress in StGallen, and Workshop on Labor Turnover and Firm Performance, Helsinki. We thank the referees and associate editor for useful comments. Financial support from the Yrjö Jahnsson Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. The SAS and Stata codes used in this study are available from the authors upon request.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pekka Ilmakunnas.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 7.

Table 7 The number of observations in the estimation sample by branches

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ilmakunnas, P., Maliranta, M. How does the age structure of worker flows affect firm performance?. J Prod Anal 46, 43–62 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0471-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0471-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation