Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Who benefits from job placement services? A two-sided analysis

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In light of additional information market agents would achieve better outcomes, for example, a lower ask price for the buyer and a higher offer price for the seller. I examine this notion in a labor market, where employers and employees do not possess perfect information about wages, and address the question of who benefits from the information provided by job placement services? The empirical strategy considers the two-sided nature of the labor market. Estimates of employee and employer incomplete information are contrasted between users and non-users of placement services provided by Job Corps, America’s largest and most important job training program for youths. Findings suggest that employees that use placement services don’t have more information about better offer wages, relative to non-users. Interestingly, firms that employed users of placement services are better informed about reservation wages relative to firms that employed non-users.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The labor market search and matching literature is extremely vast. For a review, see Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) and Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001).

  2. An alternative branch of the search equilibrium literature is based on the so-called matching function, which is employed in a myriad of modern macroeconomics studies. This literature introduces two-sided frictions in the process of matching trading partners, where agents on both sides of a market make investments in overcoming them (for a review see Petrongolo and Pissarides 2001). Although my study is empirical and micro in nature, the idea of less than complete information in both sides of the market is taken into account.

  3. In a typical labor market, the observed equilibrium wage is derived after equating the quantity of labor demand and supply. A formal derivation yielding the observed equilibrium as depicted in (3) can be found in Polachek and Yoon (1987). Consistently, in my simplified illustration above, I add u and subtract w from the equality W pu = W o = W r + w, which yields W pw = W o + u − w = W r + u. The expression W o + u − w represents a full information labor market price, which is equal to the function W(X s , X b ) + v. It follows that under incomplete information then W o = W(X s , X b ) + v − u + w. In a reduced form version, models based on bargaining and search (see Mortensen 1986) would yield a similar wage specification as in (3) after allowing for interactions between supply and demand. The latter, for example, was used by Kumbhakar and Parmeter (2009).

  4. Hofler and Polachek (1985) and Polachek and Robst (1998) estimated a model of employee ignorance based on Eq. (4) with w i  = 0 (i.e., employers have perfect information) by using the conventional stochastic frontier analysis in Aigner et al. (1977). Polachek and Robst (1998) further extended their one-sided analysis by using the technique in Jondrow et al. (1982), to estimate individual specific measures of employee incomplete information.

  5. Note that the illustration in the preceding section suggests that u and w are not independent on each other, however, identification is only possible if one employs this assumption. As pointed out by one anonymous referee, in general this is an inherent identification problem of the 2TSF formulation.

  6. An earlier version of the current paper considered a two-stage residual inclusion technique, which is a consistent instrumental variable-based approach for correcting endogeneity in non-linear models estimated via non-linear least squares (Terza et al. 2008).

  7. Other approaches for dealing with sample selection in a stochastic frontier model includes Kumbhakar et al. (2009) and Lai (2015). The former approach is similar to the one proposed by Greene (2010), the difference is that the selection equation is also affected by inefficiency. Lai (2015) extends the model in Greene (2010) by replacing the half-normal distribution for a truncated normal and also considers endogenous switching. While these could be potentially extended and employed in the present context, extending the model in Greene (2010) for the 2TSF is the more straightforward approach. For a recent review of sample selection in stochastic frontier models see Parmeter and Kumbhakar (2014).

  8. Greene (2010) used the same type of test in the context of a single tiered stochastic frontier model.

  9. This question is not to be confused with questions about the overall effect of program participation on the probability of employment, which has been reported to be positive, with a magnitude of 4 percentage points (Schochet et al. 2001).

  10. Eligibility is based on several criteria, including age, legal US residency, economically disadvantage status, living in a disruptive environment, and in need of additional education or training, among others (see Schochet et al. 2001). From a randomly selected research sample of 15,386 first time eligible applicants, approximately 61 percent were assigned to the treatment group (9409) and 39 percent to the control group (5977).

  11. Another option is including control group individuals categorized as non-users, however, one has to be cautious since it is not possible to learn from the data whether they used job placement services outside of JC.

  12. Ideally, this two-sided analysis would benefit from including actual local economic condition indicators, which are important demand side determinants (Hoynes 2000). However, such measures are not available.

  13. The negative coefficient on education of users becomes positive in regression without the square term for education, however it would still be insignificant.

  14. Most of the estimated parameters in the deterministic portion of the frontier are qualitatively similar to the OLS results reported in Table 2. It is worth noting that one striking difference, relative to the regression results, is that the estimated coefficient on education is now positive for users, however it remained statistically insignificant.

  15. Confidence intervals for the difference were calculated with a bias-corrected bootstrap technique (see Efron 1982; Kim et al. 2007). For an alternative, where confidence intervals are obtained based on the estimated conditional distributions in (7) and (8), see Horrace and Schmidt (1996).

  16. Previously reported levels of employees’ information range from 70 to 85 percent (Polachek and Yoon 1987, 1996; Groot and Oosterbeek 1994; Sharif and Dar 2007; Kumbhakar and Parmeter 2009). In general, the populations studied in these papers are comprised of more educated, older and experienced workers, hence relatively more informed than the population of JC participants.

  17. Other recent studies within this literature finding similar results include: Autor and Houseman (2010) and Autor et al. (2012). Both analyzed the effect of Detroit’s welfare-to-work job placement on earnings and employment, and concluded that job placements with “direct-hire” employers raise earnings due to a single and continuous job spell. They also find evidence indicating that “temporary-help” job placements do not improve earnings.

  18. Other studies not focusing on labor markets report similar mean effects of buyers’ incomplete information on prices, for example, Kumbhakar and Parmeter (2010) report that real estate buyers pay, on average, 30 percent more relative to a perfectly informed buyer.

References

  • Aigner D, Lovell C, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production models. J Econom 6:21–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong M (2006) Competition in two-sided markets. RAND J Econ 37(3):668–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor D, Houseman S (2010) Do temporary-help jobs improve labor market outcomes for low-skilled workers? Evidence from “work first”. Am Econ J: Appl Econ 2:96–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Autor D, Houseman S, and Kerr S (2012) The effect of work first job placements on the distribution of earnings: an instrumental variables quantile regression approach. NBER Working Paper.

  • Black D, Smith J, Berger M, Noel B (2003) Is the threat of reemployment services more effective than services themselves? Evidence from random assignment in the UI system. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1313–1327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch F, Ryder H (2000) Two-sided search, marriages, and matchmakers. Int Econ Rev 41(1):93–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradford D, Kleit A, Krousel-Wood M, Re R (2000) Stochastic frontier estimation of cost models within the hospital. Rev Econ Stat 83(2):302–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butters G (1977) Equilibrium distributions of sales and advertising prices. Rev Econ Stud 44(3):465–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chawla M (2002) Estimating the extent of patient ignorance of the health care market. In: Devarajan S, and Roger F (eds), World bank economists forum, World Bank Publications, Washington DC, Vol 2: pp 3–24.

  • Efron B (1982) The Jackknife, the Bootstrap and other resampling plans. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ferona A, Tsionas E (2012) Measurements of excess bidding in auctions. Econ Lett 116:377–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaynor M, Polachek S (1994) Measuring information in the market: an application to physician services. South Econ J 60(4):815–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene W (2010) A stochastic frontier model with correction for sample selection. J Prod Anal 34:15–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene W (2011) Econometric analysis. 7th edn. Pearson, New Jersey.

  • Gourieroux C, Monfort A (1996) Simulation-based econometric methods. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Groot W, Oosterbeek H (1994) Stochastic reservation and offer wages. Labour Econ 1(3):383–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1976) Discrete, qualitative and limited dependent variables. Ann Econ Soc Measurement 4(5):475–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofler R, Polachek S (1985) A new approach for measuring wage ignorance in the labor market. J Econ Bus 37(3):267–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horrace W, Schmidt P (1996) Confidence statements for efficiency estimates from stochastic frontier models. J Prod Anal 7(2):257–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoynes H (2000) Local labor market and welfare spells: do demand conditions matter?. Rev Econ Stat 82(3):351–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jondrow J, Lovell C, Materov I, Schmidt P (1982) On the estimation of technical inefficiency in the stochastic frontier production function model. J Econom 19:233–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim M, Kim Y, Schmidt P (2007) On the accuracy of bootstrap confidence intervals for efficiency levels in stochastic frontier models with panel data. J Prod Anal 28(3):165–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar S, Lovell CA (2003) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

  • Kumbhakar S, Parmeter C (2009) The effects of match uncertainty and bargaining on labor market outcomes: evidence from firm and worker specific estimates. J Prod Anal 31(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar S, Parmeter C (2010) Estimation of hedonic price functions with incomplete information. Empir Econ 39(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar S, Tsionas M, Sipiläinen T (2009) Joint estimation of technology choice and technical efficiency: an application to organic and conventional dairy farming. J Prod Anal 31(3):151–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai H (2015) Maximum likelihood estimation of the stochastic frontier model with endogenous switching or sample selection. J Prod Anal 43(1):105–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levit S, Syverson C (2008) Market distortions when agents are better informed: the value of information in real state transactions. Rev Econ Stat 90(4):599–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippman S, McCall J (1976) The economics of job search: a survey. Econ Inq 14:113–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masters A (1999) Wage posting in two-sided search and the minimum wage. Int Econ Rev 40(4):809–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen D (1986) Job search and labor market analysis. In: Ashenfelter O, Layard R (eds) Handbook of labor economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 849–919

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen D, Pissarides C (1994) Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Rev Econ Stud 61:397–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen D, Pissarides C (1999) New developments in models of search in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 2567–2627

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy K, Topel R (2002) Estimation and inference two-step econometric models. J Bus Econ Stat 20:88–97

  • Olsen R (1978) A note on the uniqueness of the maximum likelihood estimator of the tobit model. Econometrica 46:1211–1215

  • Papadopoulos A (2014) The half-normal specification for the two-tier stochastic frontier model. J Prod Anal: 43:1–6.

  • Parmeter C, Kumbhakar S (2014) Efficiency analysis: A primer on recent advances. Foundations and Trends in Econometrics 7:191–385

  • Petrongolo B, Pissarides C (2001) Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function. J Econ Lit 39:390–431

  • Polachek S, Robst J (1998) Employee labor market information: comparing direct world of work measures of workers’ knowledge to stochastic frontier estimates. Labour Econ 5:231–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polachek S, Yoon B (1987) A two-tiered earnings frontier estimation of employer and employee information in the labor market. Rev Econ Stat 69(2):296–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polachek S, Yoon B (1996) Panel estimates of a two-tiered earnings frontier. J Appl Econom 11:169–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pries M (2004) Persistence of employment fluctuations: a model of recurring job loss. Rev Econ Stud 71:193–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild M (1973) Models of market organization with imperfect information: a survey. J Polit Econ 81(6):1283–1308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford R, Springer T, Yavas A (2005) Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from residential brokerage. J Financ Econ 76:627–665

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schochet P, Bellotti J, Cao R, Glazerman S, Grady A, Gritz M, McConnell S, Johnson T, Burghardt J (2003) National Job Corps study: data documentation and public use files. Mathematica Policy Research, Inc., Princeton, NJ, Vol 1

    Google Scholar 

  • Schochet P, Burghardt J, Glazerman S (2001) National Job Corps study: the impacts of Job Corps on participants’ employment and related outcomes. Mathematica Policy Research, Inc., Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Schochet P, Burghardt J, McConnell S (2008) Does Job Corps work? Impact findings from the national Job Corps study. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1864–1886

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharif N, Dar A (2007) An empirical investigation of the impact of imperfect information on wages in Canada. Rev App Econ 3:137–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Sianesi B (2004) An evaluation of the Swedish system of active labor market programs in the 1990s. Rev Econ Stat 86(1):133–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sipiläinen T and Oude Lansink A (2005) Learning in switching to organic farming. Nordic Association of Agricultural Scientists, NJF Report, Vol 1

  • Stigler G (1961) The economics of information. J Polit Econ 69(3):213–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler G (1962) Information in the labor market. J Polit Econ 70(5):94–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Terza J, Basu A, Rathouz P (2008) Two-stage residual inclusion estimation: addressing endogeneity in helath econometric modeling. J Health Econ 27:531–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomini S, Groot W, Pavlova M (2012) Paying informally in the albanian health care sector: a two-tiered stochastic frontier model. Eur J Health Econ 13:777–788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train KE (2003) Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • US Department of Labor (2012) Job Corps. http://www.dol.gov/dol/topic/training/jobcorps.htm#doltopics

  • Winterhager H, Heinze A, Spermann A (2006) Deregulating job placement in Europe: a microeconometric evaluation of an innovative voucher scheme in Germany. Labour Econ 13:505–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank useful comments by Alfonso Flores-Lagunes, Solomon Polachek, Subal Kumbhakar, and the Binghamton University’s Labor Group. In addition, I thank the conference participants at the 2013 Midwest Economics Association meetings.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to German Blanco.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Blanco, G. Who benefits from job placement services? A two-sided analysis. J Prod Anal 47, 33–47 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0489-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0489-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation