Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Private investment and government protection

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Hurricane Katrina did massive damage because New Orleans and the Gulf Coast were not appropriately protected. Wherever natural disasters threaten, the government—in its traditional role as public goods provider—must decide what level of protection to provide to an area. It does so by purchasing protective capital, such as levees for a low-lying city. (“Protection” also consists of prohibiting projects that raise risk levels, such as draining swamps.)

We show that if private capital is more likely to locate in better-protected areas, as would be expected, then the marginal social value of protection will increase with the level of protection provided. That is, the benefit function is convex, contrary to the normal assumption of concavity. When the government protects and the private sector invests, there may be multiple Nash equilibria due to the ill-behaved nature of the benefit function. Policy makers must compare them, rather than merely follow local optimality conditions, to find the equilibrium offering the highest social welfare.

There is usually considerable uncertainty about the amount of private investment that will accompany any level of protection, further complicating the government’s choice problem. We show that when deciding on the level of protection to provide now, the government must take account of the option value of increasing the level of protection in the future. We briefly examine but dismiss the value of rules of thumb, such as building for 1000-year floods or other rules that ignore benefits and costs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abel, Andrew B. et al. (1996). “Options, the Value of Capital, and Investment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics August: 753–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, Kenneth and Mordecai Kurz. (1970). Public Investment, the Rate of Return, and Optimal Fiscal Policy. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V. (1992). “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(3), 797–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, Robert J. (1990). “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 98(5), S103–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, Kit. (2005). Bond Celebrates Riverside Levee Completion: New Levee to Protect Kansas City from Flood & Boost Economic Growth. Retrieved March 15, 2006 from http://bond.senate.gov/press_section/ record.cfm?id$=$238023.

  • Buchanan, James M. (1975). The Samaritan’s Dilemma, Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory. E. Phelps. New York: Russell Sage, 71–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, N. T. (2005). Flood Risk Management: Federal Role in Infrastructure. CRS Report for Congress. Washington, D.C., Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress.

  • Carter, N. T. and B. A. Cody. (2005). CRS Report for Congress, The Civil Works Program of the Army Corps of Engineers: A Primer. Washington, D.C., Congressional Research Service, The Library of Congress.

  • Feinstein, Dianne. (2005). Floor Statement by Senator Dianne Feinstein. Retrieved March 15, 2006 from http://feinstein.senate.gov/05releases/r-energy1114.htm.

  • Gerritsen, Herman. (2005). “What happened in 1953? The Big Flood in the Netherlands in Retrospect,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 363, 1271–1291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, Edward L. and Jesse M. Shapiro. (2002). “Cities and Warfare: The Impact of Terrorism on Urban Form,” Journal of Urban Economics 51: 205–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallstrom, Daniel G. and Kerry V. Smith. (2005). “Market Responses to Hurricanes,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 50(3): 541–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heisler, Eric. (2003). Investment of $400 Million Flows into Chesterfield Valley. St. Louis Post-Dispatch. St. Louis, July 7.

  • Kahn, Matthew E. (2005). “The Death Toll from Natural Disasters: The Role of Income, Geography, and Institutions,” Review of Economics and Statistics 87(2), 271–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, Matthew E. (2000). “Smog Reductions Impact on California County Growth,” Journal of Regional Science 40(3), 565–582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky, Eds. (2000). Choice, Values, and Frames. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, Paul Slovic and Amos Tversky, Eds. (1982). Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky. (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaizuka, K. (1965). “Public Goods and the Decentralization of Production,” Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 118–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, Roger G. (2006). Wildfire and Americans: How to Save Lives, Property, and Your Tax Dollars. New York: Hill and Wang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klick, J. and A. Tabarrok. (2005). “Using Terror Alert Levels to Estimate the Effect of Police on Crime,” The Journal of Law and Economics 48, 267–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, Howard and Geoffrey Heal. (2003). “Interdependent Security,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 26(2/3), 231–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, Howard, et al. (2002). “High Stakes Decision Making: Normative, Descriptive and Prescriptive Considerations,” Marketing Letters 13(3), 259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, Howard and Adam Rose, Eds. (2004). The Economics of Natural Hazards. Northamption, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, Timur and Cass R. Sunstein. (1999). “Availability Cascades and Risk Regulation,” Stanford Law Review April.

  • Lehrer, Eli. (2000). “Crime Fighting and Urban Renewal,” The Public Interest 141(Fall), 91–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, Steven D. (1997). “Using Electoral Cycles in Police Hiring to Estimate the Effect of Police on Crime,” American Economic Review 87(3).

  • Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny. (1989). “Industrialization and the Big Push,” Journal of Political Economy 97(5), 1003–1026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Research Council Committee on Assessing and Valuing the Services of Aquatic and Related Terrestrial Ecosystems (2004). Valuing Ecosystem Services: Toward Better Environmental Decision-Making. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persky, Joseph. (2001). “Retrospectives: Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Classical Creed,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4), 199–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck, Robert S. (2000). “Irreversibilities and the Timing of Environmental Policy,” Resource and Energy Economics 22(3), 233–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinter, Nicholas. (2005). “One Step Forward, Two Steps Back on U.S. Floodplains,” Science 308(8 April), 207–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roback, Jennifer. (1982). “Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life,” Journal of Political Economy 90(6), 1257–1278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, Dani and Richard Zeckhauser. (1988). “The Dilemma of Government Responsiveness,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 7(4), 601–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, Sherwin. (2002). “Markets and Diversity,” American Economic Review 92(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sparks, Richard E. (2006). “Rethinking, Then Rebuilding New Orleans,” Issues in Science and Technology Winter.

  • The Royal Netherlands Embassy. (2005). Dutch Ambassador Visits New Orleans. Retrieved February 20, 2006 from http://www.netherlands-embassy.org/article.asp?articleref$=$AR00001808EN.

  • Tiebout, Charles M. (1956). “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures,” Journal of Political Economy 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (1995). America’s Wetlands: Our Vital Link Between Land and Water, EPA843-K-95-001. Washington, DC: Office of Water, Office of Wetlands, Oceans and Watersheds.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. Kip and Joseph E. Aldy. (2003). “The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27(1), 5–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeckhauser, Richard. (1996). “The Economics of Catastrophes,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 12, 113–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erzo F. P. Luttmer.

Additional information

JEL Classification D81 · D92 · H41 · H54 · Q54 · R10

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kousky, C., Luttmer, E.F.P. & Zeckhauser, R.J. Private investment and government protection. J Risk Uncertainty 33, 73–100 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-006-0172-y

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-006-0172-y

Keywords

Navigation