Skip to main content
Log in

Sign-dependence in intertemporal choice

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Allowing for sign-dependence in discounting substantially improves the description of people’s time preferences. The deviations from constant discounting that we observed were more pronounced for losses than for gains. Our data also suggest that the discount function should be flexible enough to allow for increasing impatience. These findings challenge the current practice in modeling intertemporal choice where sign-dependence is largely ignored and only decreasing impatience is allowed. Overall, the sign-dependent model of Loewenstein and Prelec (1992) with the constant sensitivity discount function of Ebert and Prelec (2007) provided the best fit to our data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Moreover, their econometric analysis did not allow for a complete comparison between the descriptive performance of Loewenstein and Prelec’s generalized hyperbolic discount function and that of other discount functions that have been proposed as alternatives to constant discounting.

  2. For an explanation of the advantages of this definition of loss aversion over other definitions see Köbberling and Wakker (2005). For experimental evidence in favor of this definition see Abdellaoui et al. (2007).

  3. Akaike’s information criterion (AIC) is defined as −2 logL + 2 k where k is the number of parameters to be estimated. A better fit (higher likelihood) thus corresponds with a smaller value of the AIC.

  4. Drazen Prelec (personal communication) has experienced similar problems in estimating α.

  5. Baltussen et al. (2012) showed that different responses may occur in more complex tasks than those of this paper.

References

  • Abdellaoui, M., Attema, A. E., & Bleichrodt, H. (2010). Intertemporal tradeoffs for gains and losses: an experimental measurement of discounted utility. Economic Journal, 120, 845–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., l’Haridon, O., & Paraschiv, C. (2013). Is there one unifying concept of utility? an experimental comparison of utility under risk and utility over time. Management Science, 59, 2153–2169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., & Paraschiv, C. (2007). Measuring loss aversion under prospect theory: a parameter-free approach. Management Science, 53, 1659–1674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76, 583–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, L. R., & Stafford, S. L. (2009). Individual decision-making experiments with risk and intertemporal choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38, 51–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). Alternative approaches to the theory of choice in risk-taking situations. Econometrica, 19, 404–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attema, A. E., Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I. M., & Wakker, P. P. (2010). Time-tradeoff sequences for analyzing discounting and time inconsistency. Management Science, 56, 2015–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltussen, G., Post, G. T., Van den Assem, M. J., & Wakker, P. P. (2012). Random incentive systems in a dynamic choice experiment. Experimental Economics, 15, 418–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardsley, N., Cubitt, R., Loomes, G., Moffatt, P., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (2010). Experimental economics: Rethinking the rules. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baucells, M., & Heukamp, F. (2011). Probability and time tradeoff. Management Science, 58, 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69, 205–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benzion, U., Rapoport, A., & Yagil, J. (1989). Discount rates inferred from decisions: an experimental study. Management Science, 35, 270–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I. M., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 27–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bostic, R., Herrnstein, R. J., & Luce, R. D. (1990). The effect on the preference reversal of using choice indifferences. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 13, 193–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruhin, A., Fehr-Duda, H., & Epper, T. (2010). Risk and rationality: uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion. Econometrica, 78, 1372–1412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: a review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesson, H. W., & Viscusi, W. K. (2003). Commonalities in time and ambiguity aversion for long-term risks. Theory and Decision, 54, 57–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coller, M., & Williams, M. (1999). Eliciting individual discount rates. Experimental Economics, 2, 107–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Lara Resende, J. G., & Wu, G. (2010). Competence effects for choices involving gains and losses. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 40, 109–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2006). Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review, 96, 694–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickhaut, J., McCabe, K., Nagode, J. C., Rustichini, A., Smith, K., & Pardo, J. V. (2003). The impact of the certainty context on the process of choice. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 100, 3536–3541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebert, J. E. J., & Prelec, D. (2007). The fragility of time: time-insensitivity and valuation of the near and far future. Management Science, 53, 1423–1438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., Grossman, P., Johnson, C., De Oliveira, A., Rojas, C., Wilson, R. (2010). (Im) patience among adolescents: A methodological note. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1883745 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.1883745.

  • Epper, T. & Fehr-Duda, H. (2012). The missing link: Unifying risk taking and time discounting. University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper.

  • Epper, T., Fehr-Duda, H., & Bruhin, A. (2011). Viewing the future through a warped lens: why uncertainty generates hyperbolic discounting. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 43, 169–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1989). Retrospective on the utility theory of von Neumann and Morgenstern. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 2, 127–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. F., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halevy, Y. (2008). Strotz meets Allais: diminishing impatience and the certainty effect. American Economic Review, 98, 1145–1162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, C. M. (1986). Value functions for infinite period planning. Management Science, 32, 1123–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein, R. J. (1981). Self-control as response strength. In C. M. Bradshaw, E. Szabadi, & C. F. Lowe (Eds.), Quantification of steady-state operant behavior. Amsterdam: Elsevier/North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köbberling, V., & Wakker, P. P. (2005). An index of loss aversion. Journal of Economic Theory, 122, 119–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 1133–1166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 443–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J. (2007). Estimating discount functions with consumption choices over the lifecycle. Working Paper.

  • Laury, S. K., McInnes, M. M., & Swarthout, J. T. (2012). Avoiding the curves: direct elicitation of time preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 181–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F. (1987). Anticipation and the valuation of delayed consumption. Economic Journal, 97, 666–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 573–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D., & Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and decisions. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzini, P., & Mariotti, M. (2009). Choice over time. In P. Anand, P. K. Pattanaik, & C. Puppe (Eds.), The handbook of rational & social choice (pp. 239–270). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 42, 119–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paserman, M. D. (2008). Job search and hyperbolic discounting: structural estimation and policy evaluation. Economic Journal, 118, 1418–1452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E. S., & Pollak, R. A. (1968). On second-best national savings and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prelec, D., & Loewenstein, G. F. (1991). Decision making over time and under uncertainty: a common approach. Management Science, 37, 770–786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rieskamp, J., Busemeyer, J. R., & Mellers, B. A. (2006). Extending the bounds of rationality: evidence and theories of preferential choice. Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 631–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohde, K. I. M. (2010). The hyperbolic factor: a measure of time inconsistency. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41, 125–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (2003). Economics and psychology? The case of hyperbolic discounting. International Economic Review, 44, 1207–1216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1938). A note on the pure theory of consumer’s behaviour. Economica, 5(61–71), 353–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayman, S., & Öncüler, A. (2009). An investigation of time-inconsistency. Management Science, 55, 470–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2006). Discounting by intervals: a generalized model of intertemporal choice. Management Science, 52, 1424–1436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stott, H. P. (2006). Cumulative prospect theory’s functional menagerie. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 32, 101–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (2003). Reference-dependent subjective expected utility. Journal of Economic Theory, 111, 172–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeuchi, K. (2011). Non-parametric test of time consistency: present bias and future bias. Games and Economic Behavior, 71, 456–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8, 201–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: the effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36, 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tu, Q. (2004). Reference points and loss aversion in intertemporal choice. doi:10.2139/ssrn.644142.

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (2010). Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P., & Deneffe, D. (1996). Eliciting von Neumann-Morgenstern utilities when probabilities are distorted or unknown. Management Science, 42, 1131–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zank, H. (2010). On probabilities and loss aversion. Theory and Decision, 68, 243–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Thomas Epper, Peter P. Wakker, the editor W. Kip Viscusi, and an anonymous referee gave helpful comments. Arthur E. Attema and Corina Paraschiv helped to collect the data. Christina Stoddard suggested many linguistic improvements. Han Bleichrodt’s research was supported by a grant from the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Han Bleichrodt.

Appendix. Comparison of goodness of fit of the different discount functions

Appendix. Comparison of goodness of fit of the different discount functions

The following three tables show the values of the test statistics of the likelihood ratio tests (in light grey) and the Vuong tests for comparing the goodness of fit of the various discount functions. A positive value indicates that the model mentioned in the column fits better than the model mentioned in the row. A negative value means that the row model fits better than the column model. The p-values are stated in parentheses.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H. & l’Haridon, O. Sign-dependence in intertemporal choice. J Risk Uncertain 47, 225–253 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-013-9181-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-013-9181-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation