Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Theory and Decision 3/2018

12.07.2017

Lottery- and survey-based risk attitudes linked through a multichoice elicitation task

verfasst von: Giuseppe Attanasi, Nikolaos Georgantzís, Valentina Rotondi, Daria Vigani

Erschienen in: Theory and Decision | Ausgabe 3/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We analyze the results from three different risk attitude elicitation methods. First, the broadly used test by Holt and Laury (2002), HL, second, the lottery-panel task by Sabater-Grande and Georgantzis (2002), SG, and third, responses to a survey question on self-assessment of general attitude towards risk (Dohmen et al. 2011). The first and the second task are implemented with real monetary incentives, while the third concerns all domains in life in general. Like in previous studies, the correlation of decisions across tasks is low and usually statistically non-significant. However, when we consider only subjects whose behavior across the panels of the SG task is compatible with constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), the correlation between HL and self-assessed risk attitude becomes significant. Furthermore, the correlation between HL and SG also increases for CRRA-compatible subjects, although it remains statistically non-significant.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Weber et al. (2002) developed a psychometric scale that assesses risk taking in five different domains: financial decisions (separately for investing vs. gambling) and health/safety, recreational, ethical, and social decisions. Nevertheless, their elicitation method is unidimensional and is the same across domains, except that the framing of the question used to elicit self-assessed risk attitude is different for each specific domain.
 
2
For a recent example of five elicitation methods and reference to such results, see Crosetto and Filippin (2016). As in previous experimental studies on the topic, they also find that the estimated risk aversion parameters vary greatly across tasks.
 
3
For example, regression to the mean has been found to affect repeated choices in the same task by García-Gallego et al. (2011). Moreover, Lévy-Garboua et al. (2012) found a significantly higher elicited risk aversion in sequential than in simultaneous treatment, in decreasing and random than in increasing treatment, in high than in low-payoff condition. Their findings suggest that subjects use available information that has no value for normative theories. Cox et al. (2014) have rationalized some of these findings by showing the role of the payment mechanism in these distortions. Indeed, they find that random-lottery incentive mechanisms—as those usually employed in risk-elicitation tasks—may decrease the proportion of risky choices in the population, compared to a one-task design. This could explain why significantly more risk aversion emerges under multiple-task than under one-task elicitation methods.
 
4
See Butler and Loomes (2007) and Cubitt et al. (2015).
 
5
See Harrison et al. (2005) and Holt and Laury (2005): the former demonstrated and the latter confirmed the possibility of order effects in HL’s original design. Indeed, the order effect (participating in a low-payment choice before making a high-payment choice) magnifies the scale effect (scaling up real payments by 10 or 20 times).
 
6
A number of studies have shown that this assumption is questionable [see Wakker (2010) for a review], although other models (e.g., prospect theory) do not seem to have significantly higher explanatory power than the expected utility (Harrison and Rutström 2009).
 
7
Notice that this problem would emerge also in the absence of enforced monotonicity. In fact, in Holt and Laury (2002) a subject who switches from one lottery to the other more than once, as the probability of the best outcome increases, is still considered as if he/she has made just one switch. This is done by assigning as switch line from one lottery to the other the one corresponding to the number of safe choices the subject has made.
 
8
See Sect. 5.3 of Attanasi et al. (2014) for a discussion on the participants’ higher trust in physical rather than computerized instruments when facing random processes in laboratory experiments. Indeed, when implementing random processes in our experiment, we mainly relied on physical rather than computerized instruments. However, the subject’s relevant choice for the final payment was selected among all those made in the task (i.e., 1 over the 19 lines of the battery of lotteries) through a computerized random draw. This was made to limit the length of the experiment and to allow sufficient heterogeneity in subjects’ final payment, especially to avoid “collective winner effects” due to emotions documented in Zeelenberg and Pieters (2004). The same motivations hold for the computerized random draw of the relevant panel of lotteries in task 2 (SG).
 
9
In Sabater-Grande and Georgantzis (2002), the payoffs are expressed in pesetas, since the experimental sessions were run in Spain before the introduction of the euro as official currency in the European Union. In the cited follow-up studies, still run in Spain, the payoffs are equivalently expressed in euros.
 
10
In contrast to the claims of Diecidue and Ven (2008), while prior works have shown that typical reference points are individuals’ own current wealth or endowment (Kahneman and Tversky 1979), recent research has included aspiration levels in the literature on risky choice as reference points (Brown et al. 2012; Hoffmann et al. 2013).
 
11
Diecidue et al. (2015) report results from two experiments without finding support for an aspiration level at zero outcome, neither for simple lotteries nor for complex lotteries.
 
12
A numerical example is available upon request.
 
13
Principal component analysis uses an orthogonal transformation to convert a set of observations of possibly correlated variables into a set of values of linearly uncorrelated variables called principal components. This transformation is defined in such a way that the first principal component has the largest possible variance (i.e., it accounts for as much of the variability in the data as possible) and each succeeding component in turn has the highest variance possible under the constraint that it is orthogonal to the preceding components. The resulting vectors are an uncorrelated orthogonal basis set.
 
14
To account for the ordered nature of our dependent variable, we have also estimated an ordered logit model: the results are qualitatively unchanged and available upon request.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2006). Elicitation using multiple price list formats. Experimental Economics, 9, 383–405.CrossRef Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2006). Elicitation using multiple price list formats. Experimental Economics, 9, 383–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasi, G., Casoria, F., Centorrino, S., & Urso, G. (2013). Cultural investment, local development and instantaneous social capital: a case study of a gathering festival in the South of Italy. Journal of Socio-Economics, 47, 228–247.CrossRef Attanasi, G., Casoria, F., Centorrino, S., & Urso, G. (2013). Cultural investment, local development and instantaneous social capital: a case study of a gathering festival in the South of Italy. Journal of Socio-Economics, 47, 228–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasi, G., Corazzini, L., Georgantzís, N., & Passarelli, F. (2014a). Risk aversion, overconfidence and private information as determinants of majority thresholds. Pacific Economic Review, 19, 355–386.CrossRef Attanasi, G., Corazzini, L., Georgantzís, N., & Passarelli, F. (2014a). Risk aversion, overconfidence and private information as determinants of majority thresholds. Pacific Economic Review, 19, 355–386.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasi, G., Gollier, C., Montesano, A., & Pace, N. (2014b). Eliciting ambiguity aversion in unknown and in compound lotteries: a smooth ambiguity model experimental study. Theory and Decision, 77, 485–530.CrossRef Attanasi, G., Gollier, C., Montesano, A., & Pace, N. (2014b). Eliciting ambiguity aversion in unknown and in compound lotteries: a smooth ambiguity model experimental study. Theory and Decision, 77, 485–530.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernasconi, M., Corazzini, L., & Seri, R. (2014). Reference dependent preferences, hedonic adaptation and tax evasion: does the tax burden matter? Journal of Economic Psychology, 40, 103–118.CrossRef Bernasconi, M., Corazzini, L., & Seri, R. (2014). Reference dependent preferences, hedonic adaptation and tax evasion: does the tax burden matter? Journal of Economic Psychology, 40, 103–118.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brañas-Garza, P., Guillen, P., & del Paso, R. L. (2008). Math skills and risk attitudes. Economics Letters, 99, 332–336.CrossRef Brañas-Garza, P., Guillen, P., & del Paso, R. L. (2008). Math skills and risk attitudes. Economics Letters, 99, 332–336.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brown, D. B., Giorgi, E. D., & Sim, M. (2012). Aspirational preferences and their representation by risk measures. Management Science, 58, 2095–2113.CrossRef Brown, D. B., Giorgi, E. D., & Sim, M. (2012). Aspirational preferences and their representation by risk measures. Management Science, 58, 2095–2113.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Butler, D. J., & Loomes, G. C. (2007). Imprecision as an account of the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review, 97, 277–297.CrossRef Butler, D. J., & Loomes, G. C. (2007). Imprecision as an account of the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review, 97, 277–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. (1997). Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: one day at a time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 407–441.CrossRef Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. (1997). Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: one day at a time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 407–441.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2010). Portfolio choice and risk attitudes: an experiment. Economic Inquiry, 48, 133–146.CrossRef Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2010). Portfolio choice and risk attitudes: an experiment. Economic Inquiry, 48, 133–146.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Imas, A. (2013). Experimental methods: eliciting risk preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 87, 43–51.CrossRef Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Imas, A. (2013). Experimental methods: eliciting risk preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 87, 43–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., & Viceisza, A. (2016). Three risk-elicitation methods in the field: evidence from rural senegal. Review of Behavioral Economics, 3, 145–171.CrossRef Charness, G., & Viceisza, A. (2016). Three risk-elicitation methods in the field: evidence from rural senegal. Review of Behavioral Economics, 3, 145–171.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., & Harrison, G. W. (2008). Risk aversion in experiments. Emerald: Research in Experimental Economics. Cox, J. C., & Harrison, G. W. (2008). Risk aversion in experiments. Emerald: Research in Experimental Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., Sadiraj, V., & Schmidt, U. (2014). Paradoxes and mechanisms for choice under risk. Experimental Economics, 18, 215–250.CrossRef Cox, J. C., Sadiraj, V., & Schmidt, U. (2014). Paradoxes and mechanisms for choice under risk. Experimental Economics, 18, 215–250.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crosetto, P., & Filippin, A. (2013). The “bomb” risk elicitation task. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47, 31–65.CrossRef Crosetto, P., & Filippin, A. (2013). The “bomb” risk elicitation task. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47, 31–65.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crosetto, P., & Filippin, A. (2016). A theoretical and experimental appraisal of five risk elicitation methods. Experimental Economics, 19, 613–641.CrossRef Crosetto, P., & Filippin, A. (2016). A theoretical and experimental appraisal of five risk elicitation methods. Experimental Economics, 19, 613–641.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cubitt, R. P., Navarro-Martinez, D., & Starmer, C. (2015). On preference imprecision. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50, 1–34.CrossRef Cubitt, R. P., Navarro-Martinez, D., & Starmer, C. (2015). On preference imprecision. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50, 1–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dave, C., Eckel, C. C., Johnson, C. A., & Rojas, C. (2010). Eliciting risk preferences: when is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41, 219–243.CrossRef Dave, C., Eckel, C. C., Johnson, C. A., & Rojas, C. (2010). Eliciting risk preferences: when is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41, 219–243.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diecidue, E., Levy, M., & van de Ven, J. (2015). No aspiration to win? an experimental test of the aspiration level model. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 51, 245–266.CrossRef Diecidue, E., Levy, M., & van de Ven, J. (2015). No aspiration to win? an experimental test of the aspiration level model. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 51, 245–266.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diecidue, E., & Van De Ven, J. (2008). Aspiration level, probability of success and failure, and expected utility. International Economic Review, 49, 683–700.CrossRef Diecidue, E., & Van De Ven, J. (2008). Aspiration level, probability of success and failure, and expected utility. International Economic Review, 49, 683–700.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 522–550.CrossRef Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes: measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 522–550.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). Forecasting risk attitudes: an experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68, 1–17.CrossRef Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). Forecasting risk attitudes: an experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68, 1–17.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.CrossRef Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat García-Gallego, A., Georgantzis, N., Jaramillo-Gutiérrez, A., & Parravano, M. (2012). The lottery-panel task for bi-dimensional parameter-free elicitation of risk attitudes. Revista Internacional de Sociologia, 70, 53–72.CrossRef García-Gallego, A., Georgantzis, N., Jaramillo-Gutiérrez, A., & Parravano, M. (2012). The lottery-panel task for bi-dimensional parameter-free elicitation of risk attitudes. Revista Internacional de Sociologia, 70, 53–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat García-Gallego, A., Georgantzís, N., Navarro-Martínez, D., & Sabater-Grande, G. (2011). The stochastic component in choice and regression to the mean. Theory and Decision, 71, 251–267.CrossRef García-Gallego, A., Georgantzís, N., Navarro-Martínez, D., & Sabater-Grande, G. (2011). The stochastic component in choice and regression to the mean. Theory and Decision, 71, 251–267.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Georgantzís, N., & Navarro-Martínez, D. (2010). Understanding the WTA-WTP gap: attitudes, feelings, uncertainty and personality. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31, 895–907.CrossRef Georgantzís, N., & Navarro-Martínez, D. (2010). Understanding the WTA-WTP gap: attitudes, feelings, uncertainty and personality. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31, 895–907.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., Johnson, E., McInnes, M. M., & Rutström, E. E. (2005). Risk aversion and incentive effects: comment. American Economic Review, 95, 897–901.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., Johnson, E., McInnes, M. M., & Rutström, E. E. (2005). Risk aversion and incentive effects: comment. American Economic Review, 95, 897–901.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2009). Expected utility theory and prospect theory: one wedding and a decent funeral. Experimental Economics, 12, 133–158.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2009). Expected utility theory and prospect theory: one wedding and a decent funeral. Experimental Economics, 12, 133–158.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat He, P., Veronesi, M., and Engel, S. (2016). Consistency of risk preference measures and the role of ambiguity: An artefactual field experiment from China. Working Paper Series, Department of Economics, University of Verona. He, P., Veronesi, M., and Engel, S. (2016). Consistency of risk preference measures and the role of ambiguity: An artefactual field experiment from China. Working Paper Series, Department of Economics, University of Verona.
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffmann, A. O., Henry, S. F., & Kalogeras, N. (2013). Aspirations as reference points: an experimental investigation of risk behavior over time. Theory and Decision, 75, 193–210.CrossRef Hoffmann, A. O., Henry, S. F., & Kalogeras, N. (2013). Aspirations as reference points: an experimental investigation of risk behavior over time. Theory and Decision, 75, 193–210.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 1644–1655.CrossRef Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 1644–1655.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2005). Risk aversion and incentive effects: new data without order effects. American Economic Review, 95, 902–904.CrossRef Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2005). Risk aversion and incentive effects: new data without order effects. American Economic Review, 95, 902–904.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isaac, R. M., & James, D. (2000). Just who are you calling risk averse? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20, 177–187.CrossRef Isaac, R. M., & James, D. (2000). Just who are you calling risk averse? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20, 177–187.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.CrossRef Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lejuez, C. W., Read, J. P., Kahler, C. W., Richards, J. B., Ramsey, S. E., Stuart, G. L., et al. (2002). Evaluation of a behavioral measure of risk taking: the balloon analogue risk task (bart). Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 8, 75–84. Lejuez, C. W., Read, J. P., Kahler, C. W., Richards, J. B., Ramsey, S. E., Stuart, G. L., et al. (2002). Evaluation of a behavioral measure of risk taking: the balloon analogue risk task (bart). Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 8, 75–84.
Zurück zum Zitat Levy, H., & Levy, M. (2009). The safety first expected utility model: experimental evidence and economic implications. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 1494–1506.CrossRef Levy, H., & Levy, M. (2009). The safety first expected utility model: experimental evidence and economic implications. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 1494–1506.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lévy-Garboua, L., Maafi, H., Masclet, D., & Terracol, A. (2012). Risk aversion and framing effects. Experimental Economics, 15, 128–144.CrossRef Lévy-Garboua, L., Maafi, H., Masclet, D., & Terracol, A. (2012). Risk aversion and framing effects. Experimental Economics, 15, 128–144.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lönnqvist, J.-E., Verkasalo, M., Walkowitz, G., & Wichardt, P. C. (2015). Measuring individual risk attitudes in the lab: task or ask? An empirical comparison. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 119, 254–266.CrossRef Lönnqvist, J.-E., Verkasalo, M., Walkowitz, G., & Wichardt, P. C. (2015). Measuring individual risk attitudes in the lab: task or ask? An empirical comparison. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 119, 254–266.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lopes, L. L. (1987). Between hope and fear: the psychology of risk. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 20, 255–295.CrossRef Lopes, L. L. (1987). Between hope and fear: the psychology of risk. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 20, 255–295.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller, L., Meyer, D. E., & Lanzetta, J. T. (1969). Choice among equal expected value alternatives: sequential effects of winning probability level on risk preferences. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 79, 419–423.CrossRef Miller, L., Meyer, D. E., & Lanzetta, J. T. (1969). Choice among equal expected value alternatives: sequential effects of winning probability level on risk preferences. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 79, 419–423.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Payne, J. W., Laughhunn, D. J., & Crum, R. (1980). Translation of gambles and aspiration level effects in risky choice behavior. Management Science, 26, 1039–1060.CrossRef Payne, J. W., Laughhunn, D. J., & Crum, R. (1980). Translation of gambles and aspiration level effects in risky choice behavior. Management Science, 26, 1039–1060.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roth, A. E., & Malouf, M. W. (1979). Game-theoretic models and the role of information in bargaining. Psychological Review, 86, 574–594.CrossRef Roth, A. E., & Malouf, M. W. (1979). Game-theoretic models and the role of information in bargaining. Psychological Review, 86, 574–594.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sabater-Grande, G., & Georgantzis, N. (2002). Accounting for risk aversion in repeated prisoners’ dilemma games: an experimental test. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 48, 37–50.CrossRef Sabater-Grande, G., & Georgantzis, N. (2002). Accounting for risk aversion in repeated prisoners’ dilemma games: an experimental test. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 48, 37–50.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118. Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.
Zurück zum Zitat Vieider, F. M., Lefebvre, M., Bouchouicha, R., Chmura, T., Hakimov, R., Krawczyk, M., et al. (2015). Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: evidence from 30 countries. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13, 421–452.CrossRef Vieider, F. M., Lefebvre, M., Bouchouicha, R., Chmura, T., Hakimov, R., Krawczyk, M., et al. (2015). Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: evidence from 30 countries. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13, 421–452.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wakker, P. P. (2010). Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity. Cambridge University Press. Wakker, P. P. (2010). Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity. Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Weber, E. U., Blais, A.-R., & Betz, N. E. (2002). A domain-specific risk-attitude scale: measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 263–290.CrossRef Weber, E. U., Blais, A.-R., & Betz, N. E. (2002). A domain-specific risk-attitude scale: measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 263–290.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zeelenberg, M., & Pieters, R. (2004). Consequences of regret aversion in real life: the case of the Dutch postcode lottery. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 93, 155–168.CrossRef Zeelenberg, M., & Pieters, R. (2004). Consequences of regret aversion in real life: the case of the Dutch postcode lottery. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 93, 155–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zuckerman, M. (1994). Behavioral expressions and biosocial bases of sensation seeking. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Zuckerman, M. (1994). Behavioral expressions and biosocial bases of sensation seeking. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Metadaten
Titel
Lottery- and survey-based risk attitudes linked through a multichoice elicitation task
verfasst von
Giuseppe Attanasi
Nikolaos Georgantzís
Valentina Rotondi
Daria Vigani
Publikationsdatum
12.07.2017
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Theory and Decision / Ausgabe 3/2018
Print ISSN: 0040-5833
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7187
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-017-9613-0

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2018

Theory and Decision 3/2018 Zur Ausgabe