Skip to main content
Log in

The Impact of Legislative Tenure and Seniority on General Election Success: Econometric Evidence from U.S. House Races

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The last four election-cycles in the U.S. House of Representatives (2004–2010) witnessed two shifts in political party control of that legislative body—from the Republicans to the Democrats in 2006 and then back to the Republicans in 2010. Nevertheless, U.S. House incumbents of both parties running for re-election tended to enjoy a sizeable advantage over their general-election challengers during the period. The advantage is even greater for incumbents who are members of the leadership, key committees, or have lengthy tenure. Our results show that, ceteris paribus, membership in the House leadership is worth on average 6.8 percentage points towards the incumbent’s expected vote-share, and that membership in either of the two top committees is worth an additional 1.3 such percentage points. A ten-term incumbent can expect another 2.0 percentage points of vote share. Lastly, our results also indicate the existence of a wave effect favoring Democratic incumbents in 2006, and a slightly smaller wave effect favoring Republican incumbents in 2010.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Mayhew (1974) found that the mail-flow curve in the United States House of Representatives closely tracked the incumbency advantage curve. In terms of redistricting, results in Mixon and Upadhyaya (1997) suggest that the 1982 amendments to the Voting Rights Act of 1965 reduced turnover in the U.S. House of Representatives by 10.3 percentage points (for 1988) in states that created minority-majority districts. However, empirical work examining the impact of redistricting efforts is mixed, given the empirical evidence in Friedman and Holden (2009), which indicates that, ceteris paribus, changes in redistricting have reduced the probability of incumbent re-election in the modern era. Some of the incongruence here could be due to differences in the types of redistricting, and/or whether the redistricting is accomplished by legislators or commissions, boards or other less-partisan bodies (Cottrill 2012).

  2. Lott (2009) found that the choice of voting technologies made by politicians affects the incidence of ballot fatigue, a process wherein voters fail to participate in down-ballot elections, and that such fatigue rates differ by the race of the voter. Mixon and King (2002) extended Lott’s findings by showing that political support for federal legislation providing funds to integrate newer voting technologies depended on the racial composition of the electorate.

  3. Kimenyi and Tollison (1995) argued that the amount of government spending will be larger in bills that are long and complex (e.g., omnibus appropriations), and that complex legislation will emerge from longer sessions.

  4. Legislative television did not emerge in the U.S. Congress until the 1980s.

  5. The longest-tenured U.S. House incumbent during that period was Representative John Dingell, a Democrat from Michigan, who sought (and won) re-election to a 29th term in 2010.

  6. Formidable, but not impossibly so: of 212 U.S. House incumbents who ran for re-election between 2004 and 2010 after 11 or more terms of service, 12 were defeated.

  7. In 2004, Representative Bernard Sanders, an Independent from Vermont, was re-elected to an eighth term. Two years later, Representative Sanders won election to the state’s U.S. Senate seat vacated by the retirement of James Jeffords (who, like Sanders, was also an Independent who caucused with the Democrats).

  8. The second of these studies finds that a candidate’s probability of winning an open-seat election to the U.S. House rises by 0.243 (0.130) if one’s campaign spending advantage rises from $0.5 million ($0.25 million) to $1 million ($0.5 million).

  9. Fair (2007) examined macro-data on Democratic Party returns. This methodology employs a small time series (n = 23).

  10. The variable did not include incumbents whose challengers had previously been appointed to office but had not held elective office. From a candidate-quality standpoint, there is a difference between having been appointed to office and having been elected to office on one’s own.

  11. Following equation (1), the test statistic is, \( t=\frac{{\left( {{{\widehat{\beta}}_2}-{{\widehat{\beta}}_3}} \right)}}{{\sqrt{{\operatorname{var}\left( {{{\widehat{\beta}}_2}} \right)+\operatorname{var}\left( {{{\widehat{\beta}}_3}} \right)-2\operatorname{cov}\left( {{{\widehat{\beta}}_2},{{\widehat{\beta}}_3}} \right)}}}} \) (see Gujurati 1988). Other tests of the equality of parameters that appear later in this study follow a similar construct.

  12. As noted earlier, membership in the party leadership improves an incumbent’s vote share by 6.8 percentage points. However, in this case the difference between the absolute values of the parameter estimates, 0.9 percentage points, is not statistically significant.

  13. The 2010 elections saw a Republican net gain of 63 U.S. House seats; Democrats gained 31 U.S. House seats as a result of the 2006 elections.

  14. As measured by the GDP implicit price deflator, the aggregate price level rose 8.1 % from 2006Q1 to 2010Q1.

  15. Another 11 U.S. House incumbents seeking re-election between 2004 and 2010 were defeated in primary contests: 1 in 2004, 2 in 2006, and 4 each in 2008 and 2010.

  16. In the 2010 elections, Republicans won 66 seats that had been occupied by Democrats, while Democrats won 3 seats that had been occupied by Republicans. Another 25 seats, with 19 new Republicans and 6 new Democrats, did not change political parties.

References

  • Alvarez, R. M., & Saving, J. L. (1997). Congressional committees and the political economy of federal outlays. Public Choice, 92, 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barone, M., & Cohen, R. E. (2006). The almanac of American politics 2006. Chicago: National Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barone, M., & Cohen, R. E. (2008). The almanac of American politics 2008. Chicago: National Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barone, M., & Cohen, R. E. (2010). The almanac of American politics 2010. Chicago: National Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barone, M., & McCutcheon, C. (2012). The almanac of American politics 2012. Chicago: National Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beviá, C., & Llavador, H. (2009). The informational value of incumbency. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 11, 773–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Born, R. (1977). House incumbents and inter-election vote change. Journal of Politics, 39, 1,008–1,034.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butler, D. M. (2009). A regression discontinuity design analysis of the incumbency advantage and tenure in the U.S. house. Electoral Studies, 28, 123–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coker, D. C., & Crain, W. M. (1994). Legislative committees as loyalty-generating institutions. Public Choice, 81, 195–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cottrill, J. B. (2012). The effects of non-legislative approaches to redistricting on competition in congressional elections. Polity, 44, 32–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Goff, B. L. (1988). Televised legislatures: Political information technology and public choice. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • DeBacker, J. (2011). The price of pork: the seniority trap in the U.S. house. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 63–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doyle, J. (2006). Inverse tactical voting and senate elections. Unpublished Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duquette, C. M., Caudill, S. B., & Mixon, F. G., Jr. (2008). The impact of money on elections: evidence from open seat races in the United States house of representatives, 1990–2004. Economics Bulletin, 4, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duquette, C. M., Caudill, S. B., & Mixon, F. G., Jr. (2009). The impact of campaign spending on winning open-seat elections to the U.S. house of representatives. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 27, 171–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fair, R. C. (2007). Presidential and congressional vote-share equations. Unpublished Manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J. N., & Holden, R. T. (2009). The rising incumbent reelection rate: what’s gerrymandering got to do with it? Journal of Politics, 71, 593–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukumoto, K. (2005a). Decreasing electoral risk and strategic retirement to avoid losing election: Survival analysis of legislators’ (political) life at systematically dependent competing risks. Unpublished Manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukumoto, K. (2005b). The effect of position on re-election and promotion of legislators. Unpublished Manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grier, K. B., & Munger, M. C. (1991). Committee assignments, constituent preferences, and campaign contributions. Economic Inquiry, 24, 24–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T., & Stewart, C., III. (1998). The value of committee seats in the house, 1947–1991. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 453–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gujurati, D. N. (1988). Basic econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. M., Jr. (2009). Using multimember district elections to estimate the sources of the incumbency advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 53, 292–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimenyi, M. S., & Tollison, R. D. (1995). The length of legislative sessions and the growth of government. Rationality and Society, 7, 151–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroszner, R. S., & Stratmann, T. (1998). Interest-group competition and organization of congress: theory and evidence from financial services political action committees. American Economic Review, 88, 1,163–1,187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., Jr. (1991). Does additional campaign spending really hurt incumbents? The theoretical importance of past investments in political brand names. Public Choice, 72, 87–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., Jr. (2009). Non-voted ballots, the cost of voting, and race. Public Choice, 138, 171–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D. (1974). Congressional elections: the case of the vanishing marginals. Polity, 6, 295–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLaughlin, M. (2006). The effect of presidential coattails on congressional incumbents: Evidence from the 2000 election. Unpublished Manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr. (2002). Does legislative television alter the relationship between politicians and voters? Rationality and Society, 14, 109–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr., & King, E. W. (2002). Helping hispanic America vote? Ballot technology, voter fatigue and HAVA 2002. Applied Economics, 44, 785–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr., & Upadhyaya, K. P. (1997). Gerrymandering and The Voting Rights Act of 1982: a public choice analysis of turnover in the U.S. house of representatives. Public Choice, 93, 357–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr., & Upadhyaya, K. P. (2002). Legislative television as an institutional entry barrier: the impact of C-SPAN2 on turnover in the U.S. senate, 1946–1998. Public Choice, 112, 433–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr., & Upadhyaya, K. P. (2003). Legislative television as political advertising: A public choice approach. New York: iUniverse, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G., Jr., Gibson, M. T., & Upadhyaya, K. P. (2003). Has legislative television changed legislator behavior? C-SPAN2 and the frequency of senate filibustering. Public Choice, 115, 139–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prior, M. (2006). The incumbent in the living room: the rise of television and the incumbency advantage in U.S. house elections. Journal of Politics, 68, 657–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regens, J. L., Elliott, E., & Gaddie, R. K. (1991). Regulatory costs, committee jurisdictions, and corporate PAC contributions. Social Science Quarterly, 72, 751–760.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S. S., & Deering, C. J. (1990). Committees in congress. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uppal, Y. (2010). Estimating incumbency effects in U.S. state legislatures: a quasi-experimental study. Economics and Politics, 22, 180–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Will, G. F. (1992). Restoration: Congress, term limits, and the recovery of deliberative democracy. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zudenkova, G. (2011). A political agency model of coattail voting. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1,652–1,660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard J. Cebula.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Duquette, C.M., Mixon, F.G. & Cebula, R.J. The Impact of Legislative Tenure and Seniority on General Election Success: Econometric Evidence from U.S. House Races. Atl Econ J 41, 161–172 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-012-9355-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-012-9355-x

Keywords

JEL

Navigation