Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations 2/2018

20.02.2018

Plaintiffs by proxy: A firm-level approach to WTO dispute resolution

verfasst von: Jeheung Ryu, Randall W. Stone

Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations | Ausgabe 2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Lobbying by multinational business firms drives the agenda of international trade politics. We match Fortune Global 500 firms to WTO disputes in which they have a stake and to their political activities using public disclosure data. The quantitative evidence reveals traces of a principal-agent relationship between major MNCs and the US Trade Representative (USTR). Firms lobby and make political contributions to induce the USTR to lodge a WTO dispute, and once a dispute begins, firms increase their political activity in order to keep USTR on track. Lobbying is overwhelmingly patriotic—the side opposing the US position is barely represented—and we see little evidence of MNCs lobbying against domestic protectionism. When the United States is targeted in a dispute, lobbying by defendant-side firms substantially delays settlement, as the affected firms pressure the government to reject concessions. Lobbying on the complainant side does not delay dispute resolution, as complainant-side firms have mixed incentives, to resolve disputes quickly as well as to hold out for better terms.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
For example, factors such as intra-industry heterogeneity in competitiveness, factor mobility, industry size, diversification, and trade dependence have been argued to determine which industries have the most influence over public policy (Gilligan 1997; McGillivray 2004; Hillman et al. 2004).
 
2
Some scholars argue that the size of the economy affects involvement in disputes (Bown 2005; Guzman and Simmons 2005; Horn and Mavroidis 2011; Sattler and Bernauer 2011), and others focus on past experience (Davis and Bermeo 2009; Conti 2010), or exchange-rate regimes (Copelovitch and Pevehouse 2011; Broz and Werfel 2014; Bown and Reynolds 2015; Betz and Kerner 2016). While some developing countries have actively initiated WTO disputes, most do not, and empirical studies show that country-level factors such as weak legal capacity, lack of resources, or fear of retaliation deter developing countries from initiating disputes (Guzman and Simmons 2005; Bown 2005; Kim 2008; Busch et al. 2009; Elsig and Stucki 2012). Other studies investigate country-level factors affecting escalation of disputes (Busch and Reinhardt 2000, 2003), and Busch and Reinhardt (2006) and Johns and Pelc (2014) study the role of third-party states during dispute resolution. Other scholarship focuses on domestic politics. Chaudoin (2014) and Pervez (2015) argue that the timing of dispute initiation is driven by elections. The working assumption of all of these studies is that states are the relevant actors.
 
3
Formally, a principal-agent relationship exists whenever one actor, the principal, attempts to induce another actor to perform or comply. The agent must have an information advantage of some sort (for example, local knowledge, expertise, hidden effort, or private information about its type) to make the problem theoretically interesting.
 
5
A lobbying report provided by Airbus (see the Online Appendix Fig. A1) indicates that Airbus lobbied regarding civil aircraft issues, and in section 16 reports that specific lobbying issues are “matters pertaining to the US and European civil aviation industries.”
 
6
A selected list of law firms involved in WTO cases is in Bown (2010).
 
7
The country-level literature, for example has examined dispute outcomes (Busch and Reinhardt 2000; Reinhardt 2001; Bown 2004; Guzman and Simmons 2005).
 
8
For further information about the dataset, see Davis (2012), 123–32.
 
9
Davis (2012) considers only nine WTO members that have the highest trade volumes with the United States. These nine are Canada, EU, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Brazil, India, Malaysia, and Singapore. Note that China is one of the major trade partners of the United States, but it is excluded because it joined the WTO only in 2001.
 
12
In addition, we analyze the effects of political contributions to the Republicans and the Democrats separately. The results are similar to those reported above, and we report them in the Online Appendix Table B2.
 
13
A description of the text analysis method used in the data collection and the list of involved firms can be found in the Online Appendix Section A.3.
 
15
Details on the methodology are available at http://​www.​opensecrets.​org/​lobby/​methodology.​php.
 
16
On the “new-new” trade theory, see Melitz (2003), Bernard et al. (2003), and Helpman et al. (2004), and Antràs and Helpman (2004).
 
17
Jensen et al. (2015) show that firms with more vertical FDI are less likely to file antidumping petitions, and we find that FDI is also associated with lower levels of lobbying during WTO disputes.
 
18
Since we consider four categories in our analyses–US is complainant, complainant-side firms; US is complainant, defendant-side firms; US is defendant, complainant-side firms; and US is defendant, defendant-side firms–we use four different TIPs variables to capture these bilateral relations.
 
19
The results are robust to other model selections (pooling and random effects). A Hausman test indicates that fixed-effect models are appropriate.
 
20
Additional results in the Online Appendix show that a model that does not control for selection effects does exhibit a significant positive effect of a different variable, political contributions, on the probability of a pro-complainant ruling (Table B5), and this result survives in models that control for selection into WTO dispute initiation (Table B4) (We use industry-level political contributions data because the unit of analysis for the selection model is an industry-level trade barrier). However, the result of firm-level lobbying on panel rulings is insignificant when we model the selection problem as survival of a dispute until the panel rules.
 
21
It would appear natural to include lobbying data in the selection stage in models (3) and (4), we cannot do so because the data are not available. Since the consultation stage only lasts a few months and the lobbying data are collected annually, we cannot specify the amount of lobbying spent in the first stage.
 
22
We update the dataset because its coverage ends in 2010. We consider both legislative and presidential elections.
 
23
These results are consistent with the magnitudes observed in some well-known cases. In US-Softwood Lumber, the United States lumber industry spent on average $1.5 million to influence the International Trade Commission (ITC), which had investigated imports of softwood lumber from Canada and determined that Canadian imports were subsidized and sold in the United States at less than fair value. The Canadian government challenged this measure by initiating a dispute on 20 December 2002 at the WTO. The dispute took almost four years before it was resolved. In a case with higher stakes, US-Zeroing, several countries lodged a complaint against the United States for its use of “zeroing” methodology in its antidumping margin calculations. The WTO panel ruled that using zeroing is inconsistent with the Antidumping Agreement, but US industries spent on average $5.9 million per year on lobbying, and US compliance with the ruling was delayed for eight years.
 
24
Japanese steel producers related to this case are Nippon Steel, NKK Corp., Kawasaki Steel Corp., Kobe Steel Ltd., Sumitomo Metal Industries Ltd., and Nisshin Steel Co.
 
25
WTO Panel report WT/DS184/R.
 
27
House hearing in the 106 Congress to discuss steel trade issues, which is available at https://​www.​gpo.​gov/​fdsys/​pkg/​CHRG-106hhrg57306/​html/​CHRG-106hhrg57306.​htm.
 
28
New York times article, “New US guards promised against steel import surges.” Source: http://​www.​nytimes.​com/​2000/​07/​26/​business/​new-us-guards-promised-against-steel-import-surges.​html
 
29
WTO Panel report WT/DS184/R.
 
30
According to the Article XXI, prompt compliance with recommendations or rulings of the DSB is required in order to ensure effective resolution of disputes for the benefit of all members.
 
31
A recent status report is WT/DS184/15/Add.171 [accessed 12 April 2017].
 
32
 
33
Compared to imports during a period before the US imposed antidumping measures in 1998 (6.07 million), steel imports from Japan decreased to only 1.93 million tons in 2000 (Keisuke 2006).
 
34
Japanese steel producers also spend on lobbying, but the amount is relatively small. Sumitomo Metal Industries Ltd spent a mere $40,000 in 1999 and this amount decreased to $20,000 in 2002.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Antràs, P., & Helpman, E. (2004). Global sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 112(3), 552–580.CrossRef Antràs, P., & Helpman, E. (2004). Global sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 112(3), 552–580.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D. (1993). Information and influence: Lobbying for agendas and votes. American Journal of Political Science, 37(3), 799–833.CrossRef Austen-Smith, D. (1993). Information and influence: Lobbying for agendas and votes. American Journal of Political Science, 37(3), 799–833.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernard, A.B. et al. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. The American Economic Review, 93(4), 1268–1290.CrossRef Bernard, A.B. et al. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. The American Economic Review, 93(4), 1268–1290.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Betz, T., & Kerner, A. (2016). Real exchange rate overvaluation and WTO dispute initiation in developing countries. International Organization, 70(4), 797.CrossRef Betz, T., & Kerner, A. (2016). Real exchange rate overvaluation and WTO dispute initiation in developing countries. International Organization, 70(4), 797.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bliss, H., & Russett, B. (1998). Democratic trading partners: The liberal connection, 1962–1989. The Journal of Politics, 60(4), 1126–1147.CrossRef Bliss, H., & Russett, B. (1998). Democratic trading partners: The liberal connection, 1962–1989. The Journal of Politics, 60(4), 1126–1147.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bombardini, M. (2008). Firm heterogeneity and lobby participation. Journal of International Economics, 75(2), 329–348.CrossRef Bombardini, M. (2008). Firm heterogeneity and lobby participation. Journal of International Economics, 75(2), 329–348.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bormann, N.-C., & Golder, M. (2013). Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2011. Electoral Studies, 32(2), 360–369.CrossRef Bormann, N.-C., & Golder, M. (2013). Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2011. Electoral Studies, 32(2), 360–369.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C.P. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.CrossRef Bown, C.P. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C.P. (2005). Participation in WTO dispute settlement: Complainants, interested parties, and free riders. The World Bank Economic Review, 19(2), 287–310.CrossRef Bown, C.P. (2005). Participation in WTO dispute settlement: Complainants, interested parties, and free riders. The World Bank Economic Review, 19(2), 287–310.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C.P. (2010). Self-enforcing trade: Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington: Brookings Institution. Bown, C.P. (2010). Self-enforcing trade: Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington: Brookings Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C.P., & Reynolds, K.M. (2015). Trade flows and trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 10(2), 145–177.CrossRef Bown, C.P., & Reynolds, K.M. (2015). Trade flows and trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 10(2), 145–177.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Broz, J.L., & Werfel, S.H. (2014). Exchange rates and industry demands for trade protection. International Organization, 68(02), 393–416.CrossRef Broz, J.L., & Werfel, S.H. (2014). Exchange rates and industry demands for trade protection. International Organization, 68(02), 393–416.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brutger, R. (2017). Litigation for sale: Private firms and WTO dispute escalation. Working paper. Brutger, R. (2017). Litigation for sale: Private firms and WTO dispute escalation. Working paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (1999). Industrial location and protection: The political and economic geography of U.S. nontariff barriers. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 1028– 1050.CrossRef Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (1999). Industrial location and protection: The political and economic geography of U.S. nontariff barriers. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 1028– 1050.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: Early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24, 158. Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: Early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24, 158.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Developing countries and general agreement on tariffs and trade/world trade organization dispute settlement. Journal of World Trade, 37(4), 719–735. Busch, M.L., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Developing countries and general agreement on tariffs and trade/world trade organization dispute settlement. Journal of World Trade, 37(4), 719–735.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2006). Three’s a crowd: Third parties and WTO dispute settlement. World Politics, 58(03), 446–477.CrossRef Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2006). Three’s a crowd: Third parties and WTO dispute settlement. World Politics, 58(03), 446–477.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2007). Developing countries and GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In Berman, G., & Mavroidis, P. (Eds.) WTO law and developing countries (pp. 195–212). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Busch, M., & Reinhardt, E. (2007). Developing countries and GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In Berman, G., & Mavroidis, P. (Eds.) WTO law and developing countries (pp. 195–212). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M.L., Reinhardt, E., Shaffer, G. (2009). Does legal capacity matter? A survey of WTO members. World Trade Review, 8(04), 559–577.CrossRef Busch, M.L., Reinhardt, E., Shaffer, G. (2009). Does legal capacity matter? A survey of WTO members. World Trade Review, 8(04), 559–577.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chalmers, A.W. (2013). Trading information for access: Informational lobbying strategies and interest group access to the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy, 20(1), 39–58.CrossRef Chalmers, A.W. (2013). Trading information for access: Informational lobbying strategies and interest group access to the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy, 20(1), 39–58.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chaudoin, S. (2014). Audience features and the strategic timing of trade disputes. International Organization, 68(04), 877–911.CrossRef Chaudoin, S. (2014). Audience features and the strategic timing of trade disputes. International Organization, 68(04), 877–911.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Conti, J.A. (2010). Learning to dispute: Repeat participation, expertise, and reputation at the world trade organization. Law & Social Inquiry, 35(3), 625–662.CrossRef Conti, J.A. (2010). Learning to dispute: Repeat participation, expertise, and reputation at the world trade organization. Law & Social Inquiry, 35(3), 625–662.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Copelovitch, M.S., & Pevehouse, J.C. (2011). Currency wars by other means? Exchange rates and WTO dispute initiation. In IPES conference. Copelovitch, M.S., & Pevehouse, J.C. (2011). Currency wars by other means? Exchange rates and WTO dispute initiation. In IPES conference.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, C.L. (2012). Why adjudicate?: Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Davis, C.L. (2012). Why adjudicate?: Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, C.L., & Bermeo, S.B. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. The Journal of Politics, 71(03), 1033–1049.CrossRef Davis, C.L., & Bermeo, S.B. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. The Journal of Politics, 71(03), 1033–1049.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, C.L., & Shirato, Y. (2007). Firms, governments, and WTO adjudication: Japan’s selection of WTO disputes. World Politics, 59(02), 274–313.CrossRef Davis, C.L., & Shirato, Y. (2007). Firms, governments, and WTO adjudication: Japan’s selection of WTO disputes. World Politics, 59(02), 274–313.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Bièvre, D. et al. (2016). International institutions and interest mobilization: The WTO and lobbying in EU and US trade policy. Journal of World Trade, 50(2), 289–312. De Bièvre, D. et al. (2016). International institutions and interest mobilization: The WTO and lobbying in EU and US trade policy. Journal of World Trade, 50(2), 289–312.
Zurück zum Zitat Eckhardt, J. (2011). Firm lobbying and EU trade policymaking: Reflections on the anti-dumping case against chinese and vietnamese shoes (2005–2011). J World Trade, 45, 965. Eckhardt, J. (2011). Firm lobbying and EU trade policymaking: Reflections on the anti-dumping case against chinese and vietnamese shoes (2005–2011). J World Trade, 45, 965.
Zurück zum Zitat Eckhardt, J., & De Bievre, D. (2015). Boomerangs over Lac L?eman: Transnational lobbying and foreign venue shopping in WTO dispute settlement. World Trade Review, 14(3), 507–530.CrossRef Eckhardt, J., & De Bievre, D. (2015). Boomerangs over Lac L?eman: Transnational lobbying and foreign venue shopping in WTO dispute settlement. World Trade Review, 14(3), 507–530.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M., & Pollack, M.A. (2014). Agents, trustees, and international courts: The politics of judicial appointment at the world trade organization. European Journal of International Relations, 20(2), 391–415.CrossRef Elsig, M., & Pollack, M.A. (2014). Agents, trustees, and international courts: The politics of judicial appointment at the world trade organization. European Journal of International Relations, 20(2), 391–415.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elsig, M., & Stucki, P. (2012). Low-income developing countries and WTO litigation: Why wake up the sleeping dog? Review of International Political Economy, 19(2), 292–316.CrossRef Elsig, M., & Stucki, P. (2012). Low-income developing countries and WTO litigation: Why wake up the sleeping dog? Review of International Political Economy, 19(2), 292–316.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gawande, K., Hoekman, B., Cui, Y. (2015). Global supply chains and trade policy responses to the 2008 crisis. The World Bank Economic Review, 29(1), 102–128.CrossRef Gawande, K., Hoekman, B., Cui, Y. (2015). Global supply chains and trade policy responses to the 2008 crisis. The World Bank Economic Review, 29(1), 102–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gilligan, M.J. (1997). Empowering exporters: Reciprocity, delegation, and collective action in american trade policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Gilligan, M.J. (1997). Empowering exporters: Reciprocity, delegation, and collective action in american trade policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein, J.L., & Steinberg, R.H. (2008). Negotiate or litigate? Effects of WTO judicial delegation on us trade politics. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71(1), 257–282. Goldstein, J.L., & Steinberg, R.H. (2008). Negotiate or litigate? Effects of WTO judicial delegation on us trade politics. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71(1), 257–282.
Zurück zum Zitat Grier, K.B., Munger, M.C., Roberts, B.E. (1994). The determinants of industry political activity, 1978?-1986. American Political Science Review, 88(04), 911–926.CrossRef Grier, K.B., Munger, M.C., Roberts, B.E. (1994). The determinants of industry political activity, 1978?-1986. American Political Science Review, 88(04), 911–926.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Interest groups and trade policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Interest groups and trade policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Guzman, A.T., & Simmons, B.A. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the world trade organization. The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S1), S205–S235.CrossRef Guzman, A.T., & Simmons, B.A. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the world trade organization. The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S1), S205–S235.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guzman, A.T., & Simmons, B.A. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: The selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. The Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef Guzman, A.T., & Simmons, B.A. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: The selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. The Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hall, R.L., & Deardorff, A.V. (2006). Lobbying as legislative subsidy. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 69–84.CrossRef Hall, R.L., & Deardorff, A.V. (2006). Lobbying as legislative subsidy. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 69–84.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hanegraaff, M., Beyers, J., Braun, C. (2011). Open the door to more of the same? The development of interest group representation at the WTO. World Trade Review, 10(4), 447–472.CrossRef Hanegraaff, M., Beyers, J., Braun, C. (2011). Open the door to more of the same? The development of interest group representation at the WTO. World Trade Review, 10(4), 447–472.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Helpman, E., Melitz, J.M., Yeaple, R.S. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.CrossRef Helpman, E., Melitz, J.M., Yeaple, R.S. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Henisz, W.J. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics & Politics, 12(1), 1–31.CrossRef Henisz, W.J. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics & Politics, 12(1), 1–31.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A.J., Keim, G.D., Schuler, D. (2004). Corporate political activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6), 837–857.CrossRef Hillman, A.J., Keim, G.D., Schuler, D. (2004). Corporate political activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6), 837–857.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hiscox, M.J. (2002). International trade and political conflict: Commerce, coalitions, and mobility. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hiscox, M.J. (2002). International trade and political conflict: Commerce, coalitions, and mobility. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P.C. (2011). TheWTO dispute settlement data set, 1995–2011. In Data available at the World Bank data archive. Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P.C. (2011). TheWTO dispute settlement data set, 1995–2011. In Data available at the World Bank data archive.
Zurück zum Zitat Horn, H., Mavroidis, P.C., Nordström, H., et al. (1999). Is the use of the WTO dispute settlement system biased? Vol. 2340. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Horn, H., Mavroidis, P.C., Nordström, H., et al. (1999). Is the use of the WTO dispute settlement system biased? Vol. 2340. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Zurück zum Zitat Hudec, R.E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers. Hudec, R.E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Keisuke, I. (2006). Legalization and Japan: The politics of WTO dispute settlement. Cameron May. Keisuke, I. (2006). Legalization and Japan: The politics of WTO dispute settlement. Cameron May.
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen, J.B., Quinn, D.P., Weymouth, S. (2015). The influence of firm global supply chains and foreign currency undervaluations on US trade disputes. International Organization, 69(04), 913– 947.CrossRef Jensen, J.B., Quinn, D.P., Weymouth, S. (2015). The influence of firm global supply chains and foreign currency undervaluations on US trade disputes. International Organization, 69(04), 913– 947.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johns, L., & Pelc, K.J. (2014). Who gets to be in the room? Manipulating participation in WTO disputes. International Organization, 68(03), 663–699.CrossRef Johns, L., & Pelc, K.J. (2014). Who gets to be in the room? Manipulating participation in WTO disputes. International Organization, 68(03), 663–699.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: Divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: Divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, M. (2016). Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 11(3), 283–310. Kim, M. (2016). Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 11(3), 283–310.
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, I.S. (2017). Political cleavages within industry: Firm-level lobbying for trade liberalization. American Political Science Review, 111(1), 1–20.CrossRef Kim, I.S. (2017). Political cleavages within industry: Firm-level lobbying for trade liberalization. American Political Science Review, 111(1), 1–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kreps, D.M., & Wilson, R. (1982). Reputation and imperfect information. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 253–279.CrossRef Kreps, D.M., & Wilson, R. (1982). Reputation and imperfect information. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 253–279.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E.D., & Bronson, R. (1997). Alliances, preferential trading arrangements, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 91(1), 94–107.CrossRef Mansfield, E.D., & Bronson, R. (1997). Alliances, preferential trading arrangements, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 91(1), 94–107.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E.D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: The effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57(4), 829–862.CrossRef Mansfield, E.D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: The effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57(4), 829–862.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., Rosendorff, B.P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94(02), 305–321.CrossRef Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., Rosendorff, B.P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94(02), 305–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry: The comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry: The comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Melitz, M.J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.CrossRef Melitz, M.J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H.V. (1988). Resisting protectionism: Global industries and the politics of international trade. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Milner, H.V. (1988). Resisting protectionism: Global industries and the politics of international trade. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H.V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Milner, H.V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H.V., & Yoffie, D.B. (1989). Between free trade and protectionism: Strategic trade policy and a theory of corporate trade demands. International Organization, 43(02), 239–272.CrossRef Milner, H.V., & Yoffie, D.B. (1989). Between free trade and protectionism: Strategic trade policy and a theory of corporate trade demands. International Organization, 43(02), 239–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R.M., Tabares, T.E. (1998). The political determinants of international trade: The major powers, 1907–1990. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 649–661.CrossRef Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R.M., Tabares, T.E. (1998). The political determinants of international trade: The major powers, 1907–1990. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 649–661.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat O’Halloran, S. (1994). Politics, process, and american trade policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef O’Halloran, S. (1994). Politics, process, and american trade policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pauwelyn, J. (2000). Enforcement and countermeasures in the WTO: Rules are rules-toward a more collective approach. American Journal of International Law, 94(2), 335–347.CrossRef Pauwelyn, J. (2000). Enforcement and countermeasures in the WTO: Rules are rules-toward a more collective approach. American Journal of International Law, 94(2), 335–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pelc, K.J. (2014). The politics of precedent in international law: A social network application. American Political Science Review, 108(3), 547–564.CrossRef Pelc, K.J. (2014). The politics of precedent in international law: A social network application. American Political Science Review, 108(3), 547–564.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pervez, F. (2015). Waiting for election season: The timing of international trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 10(2), 265–303.CrossRef Pervez, F. (2015). Waiting for election season: The timing of international trade disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 10(2), 265–303.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Poletti, A., De Bièvre, D., Hanegraaff, M. (2016). WTO judicial politics and EU trade policy: Business associations as vessels of special interest? The British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 18(1), 196–215.CrossRef Poletti, A., De Bièvre, D., Hanegraaff, M. (2016). WTO judicial politics and EU trade policy: Business associations as vessels of special interest? The British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 18(1), 196–215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reinhardt, E. (2001). Adjudication without enforcement in GATT disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(2), 174–195.CrossRef Reinhardt, E. (2001). Adjudication without enforcement in GATT disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(2), 174–195.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rosendorff, B.P. (2005). Stability and rigidity: Politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(03), 389–400.CrossRef Rosendorff, B.P. (2005). Stability and rigidity: Politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(03), 389–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sattler, T., & Bernauer, T. (2011). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the world trade organisation. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 143–167.CrossRef Sattler, T., & Bernauer, T. (2011). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the world trade organisation. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 143–167.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schnakenberg, K.E. (2017). Informational lobbying and legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science, 61(1), 129–145.CrossRef Schnakenberg, K.E. (2017). Informational lobbying and legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science, 61(1), 129–145.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shaffer, G. (2003). Defending interests: Public-private partnerships in WTO litigation. Washington: Brookings Institution. Shaffer, G. (2003). Defending interests: Public-private partnerships in WTO litigation. Washington: Brookings Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Shaffer, G. (2006). What’s new in EU trade dispute settlement? Judicialization, public–private networks and the WTO legal order. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(6), 832–850.CrossRef Shaffer, G. (2006). What’s new in EU trade dispute settlement? Judicialization, public–private networks and the WTO legal order. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(6), 832–850.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, R.W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Stone, R.W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weymouth, S. (2012). Firm lobbying and influence in developing countries: A multilevel approach. Business and Politics, 14(4), 1–26.CrossRef Weymouth, S. (2012). Firm lobbying and influence in developing countries: A multilevel approach. Business and Politics, 14(4), 1–26.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Woll, C., & Artigas, A. (2007). When trade liberalization turns into regulatory reform: The impact on business?government relations in international trade politics. Regulation & Governance, 1(2), 121–138.CrossRef Woll, C., & Artigas, A. (2007). When trade liberalization turns into regulatory reform: The impact on business?government relations in international trade politics. Regulation & Governance, 1(2), 121–138.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yildirim, A.B., Chatagnier, J.T., Poletti, A., Bièvre D.D. (2018). The internationalization of production and the politics of compliance in WTO disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 13(1), 49–75.CrossRef Yildirim, A.B., Chatagnier, J.T., Poletti, A., Bièvre D.D. (2018). The internationalization of production and the politics of compliance in WTO disputes. The Review of International Organizations, 13(1), 49–75.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zangl, B. (2008). Judicialization matters! A comparison of dispute settlement under GATT and the WTO. International Studies Quarterly, 52(4), 825–854.CrossRef Zangl, B. (2008). Judicialization matters! A comparison of dispute settlement under GATT and the WTO. International Studies Quarterly, 52(4), 825–854.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Plaintiffs by proxy: A firm-level approach to WTO dispute resolution
verfasst von
Jeheung Ryu
Randall W. Stone
Publikationsdatum
20.02.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
The Review of International Organizations / Ausgabe 2/2018
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Elektronische ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9304-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2018

The Review of International Organizations 2/2018 Zur Ausgabe