Skip to main content
Log in

Regional convergence in Italy, 1891–2001: testing human and social capital

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The article aims to present and discuss estimates of levels of human and social capital in Italy’s regions over the long term, i.e., roughly from the second half of the nineteenth century up to the present day. The results are linked to newly available evidence for regional value added in order to begin to form an explanatory hypothesis of long-term regional inequality in Italy: convergence in value added per capita is tested in light of the neoclassical exogenous growth approach, which incorporates human capital and social capital as conditioning variables into a long-term production function. In contrast with conventional wisdom (e.g. Putnam 1993), we find that social capital was not a significant predictor of economic growth in post-Unification Italy: It grew in importance only in the last decades. Conversely, human capital was more important in the first half of the twentieth century. Results suggest that there was not one single conditioning variable over the long run, thus supporting the view that, in different periods, conditioning variables can be determined by technological regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Thus, partly confirming the previous (and somehow pioneering) industrial estimates by Fenoaltea (2003). See also Daniele and Malanima (2007) who have produced yearly 1861–1951 series by juxtaposing the national cycles to the regional benchmarks estimated by Fenoaltea (2003) for industry (in 1871, 1881, 1901, and 1911), by Federico (2003) for agriculture (in 1891, 1911, 1938, and 1951), and by Felice (2005a, 2005b) for services (in 1891, 1911, 1938, and 1951) and for industry (in 1938, 1951).

  2. Direct accounting figures are available only from the 1970s onwards, whereas for the previous benchmark years (1891, 1911, 1938 and 1951), regional value added has been reconstructed by allocating the most recent estimates of national value added, at a very high sectoral breakdown, through a number of different sources, mainly regional data on employment, wages and horsepower. See Felice (2011) for further details.

  3. It was stronger in industry, as confirmed by Ciccarelli et al. (2010) with the avail of time-series evidence on construction movements. For liberal Italy, the benchmarks here presented incorporate all the available 1861–1913 regional time-series by Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea (see Felice 2011, p. 933).

  4. This finding is not new: see Iona et al. (2008).

  5. The test statistic (12.75) is higher than a Chi-squared at the 0.01 level of confidence (1 df, 1% = 6.63), and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.0004. For the model including population growth, the level of confidence is only 0.05 (test statistic 8.99 and Prob > Chi-squared 0.0112; Chi-squared 2 df, 5% = 5.99; Chi-squared 2 df, 1% = 9.21).

  6. Among these models, the Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE), which makes use of the classical ordinary least-squares (OLS) estimation, is probably the most appealing and popular technique (see Sala-i-Martin et al. 2004).

  7. As shown by Prados de La Escosura and Rosés (2010) with reference to Spain, the alternative income-based approach can be preferable, especially for the last decades. Concerning the Italian regions, however, we lack data for computing human capital through the skill premium. Not least because of the availability of sources, historical estimates following the education-based approach are by far the most internationally used: for a recent application, a part from the cited references about Germany and US, see Ljungberg and Nilsson (2009) for Sweden.

  8. In principle at least, our human capital indicator should be a measure of “flow”, not of “stock”. The choice in favour of a flow measure is a matter of necessity (the availability of sources), but above all of opportunity: Flow measures are well suited to convergence models and are used for example by Mankiw et al. (1992). For an excellent survey on the debate about the human capital indicator in growth studies, see Sianesi and Van Reenen (2003, pp. 167–169 and 177–180). Although there are some reasons to believe that stock measures can also be suitable for being computed in growth accounting (Schulze and Fernandes 2009), these are more difficult to implement from a historical perspective and, in the case of Italy, cannot be reconstructed for the years previous 1951, at least not according to the attainment census method (Felice 2007a); for a review of the approaches to estimating average years of schooling, see Wößmann (2003). Neither the available sources allow for alternative weighting schemes, based on earnings or occupational wage data (cfr. Psacharopoulos 1994; Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2002).

  9. When dealing with education capabilities in advanced countries, the shift from compulsory to tertiary and higher education is also recommended by most of the literature on development economics (e.g. Costantini and Monni 2005, with an application to the European regions). Of course, this shift does not rule out the possibility of decreasing returns to human capital in any (or some) specific period (Bils and Klenow 2000).

  10. For further details about the separate components and for a brief discussion of the results, see the “Appendix”.

  11. For the latest analysis of the Italian economic growth over the long run, which also presents the most updated Gdp series, see Brunetti et al. (2011).

  12. For a critical assessment of the early legislation about compulsory education, see Vasta (1996, 1999, pp. 220–222), Felice (2007b, pp. 155–157), and A’Hearn et al. (2011, pp. 163–169).

  13. Zamagni (1993) found evidence of a positive role for human capital in the 1951–1987 years, but the different results may be explained by the choice of a greater time interval and the use of different (and now outdated) GDP estimates for 1951.

  14. The test statistic (9.96) is above the Chi-squared (2 df, 1% = 9.21), and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.007. However, it is worth noting that after including human capital, the choice in favour of the fixed-effects model is a bit less indisputable than in the case of unconditional convergence.

  15. The test statistic (7.03) is below the Chi-squared (3 df, 5% = 7.82), and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.0709.

  16. In the models without population growth, when running the gross enrolment ratio, the fixed-effects model is preferable at a lower level of confidence (0.05 instead of 0.01): The test statistic (6.23) is in between the two Chi-squared (2 df, 5% = 5.99; 2 df, 1% = 9.21) and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.0444. The same can be said for the model including literacy: The test statistic (6.76) is in between the two Chi-squared (2 df, 5% = 5.99; 2 df, 1% = 9.21), and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.0341. In all the models with population growth, the random-effects model results preferable at a level of confidence even higher than is the case with the composite indicator: For the gross enrolment ratio, the test statistic (4.84) is below the Chi-squared (3 df, 5% = 7.82; 3 df, 1% = 6.25), and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.1839; for literacy, the test statistic is 4.82 and Prob > Chi-squared is 0.1855.

  17. For an overview of the studies with reference to economic growth, see Durlauf et al. (2005).

  18. See also Helliwell and Putnam (1995); see Felice (2007b, pp. 54–64) for elaborations on institutions and social capital from Putnam data.

  19. Most remarkably, Sabatini (2008) has proposed a measure of social capital which overcomes some shortcomings of Putnam’s definition and indicators. From theoretical grounds, Sabatini draws a distinction between bonding social capital on one hand, shaped by strong family ties and with a negative impact on economic growth and bridging and linking social capital on the other, shaped by weak ties among friends, neighbours and members of voluntary organizations, and with a positive impact on economic growth. With a few exceptions, those Italian regions rich in the former were deemed poor in the latter, and vice versa. On empirical grounds, the main innovation by Sabatini is the attention towards measures directly linked to social capital components, i.e., the attempt to distinguish between social capital and its outcomes. For the Italian regions, Sabatini’s estimates are limited to very recent years (from 1998 onwards), while requiring a huge amount of data unavailable for previous periods: It is impossible to replicate them for other benchmarks, and thus for our purposes, they are unusable. However, Sabatini’s estimates by and large confirm Nuzzo’s regional rankings: For 2001, the Pearson correlation between Nuzzo’s and Sabatini’s estimates is 0.923 (significant at the 0.01 level). Other available estimates, also limited to recent years, have been produced by Cartocci (2007), but they are less correlated with both Sabatini (0.902) and Nuzzo (0.792; in both cases, correlation is significant at 0.01).

  20. Arguably, social capital can alternatively be viewed as an exogenous, fixed factor (like climate) that permanently affects the level of value added per capita, while not affecting the growth rate, or even as a factor indirectly affecting the rate of investment in physical capital. Both these arguments are plausible, but the implications are obviously different and, as we are going to see, in the case of an exogenous, fixed factor less in line with the interpretative findings of this article.

  21. The author found a rank correlation of 0.81 between social capital and regional per capita output in 1911 (Putnam 1993, p. 237); A’Hearn (2000, p. 70) has revised this datum to 0.87. Our rank (Spearman) correlation for 1911 is lower, 0.68 (all data are significant at the 0.01 level). Both Putnam’s and A’Hearn’s calculations were based on now outdated output figures. Most recently, the detailed survey by Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea on industrial output at a provincial level in liberal Italy has implicitly questioned the role of social capital for that period, given that in the North, many provinces with high levels of social capital did not undergo industrialization (Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea 2010, p. 10).

  22. The test statistic is higher than in the case of human capital (12.78 vs. 7.63), and higher than the critical value of a Chi-squared also at the 0.01 level of confidence (Chi-squared 2 df, 1% = 9.21), and the Prob > Chi-squared results considerably small (0.0017).

  23. The test statistic is 10.29 and the Prob > Chi-squared results 0.0163.

  24. In cross-section regressions, social capital is the redundant variable in the first two decades (1891–1911), human capital in the last two (1981–2001). The results from panel regressions suggest that in the random-effects model, both human capital and social capital are positive and significant, and that in the fixed-effects model, both are insignificant (and these results do not change when including population growth, which is always negative and significant). In the panel without population growth, the fixed-effects model is again preferable after the Hausman test, with far less confidence than in the models with social capital as the only conditioning variable, and just slightly less confidence than in the models with human capital [the test statistic (9.18) is higher than the critical value of a Chi-squared at the 0.05 level of confidence (Chi-squared 3 df, 5% = 7.81), lower at 0.01 level (Chi-squared 3 df, 1% = 11.34), with a Prob > Chi-squared of 0.023]. In the panel with population growth, the random-effects model is preferable (test statistic 5.06, Prob > Chi-squared 0.272).

  25. Results for literacy and the gross enrolment ratio are omitted for reasons of space, but they are in line with what emerges from the human capital composite indicator.

  26. Given that for the years 1951–1971, both human capital and social capital are insignificant, results do not change when also running social capital for 1951, and thus human capital only up to 1938.

  27. The coefficients of the fixed-effects model (with robust option) are the following; without population growth: constant 0.0170 (***), B1 (per capita value added) −0.0209 (***), B2 (mixed human capital and social capital) 0.0028 (**); R 2 is 0.061. With population growth: constant 0.0383 (**), B1 (per capita value added) −0.0112 (***), B2 (mixed human capital and social capital) 0.0047 (***); B3 (population growth) −0.0327 (**); R 2 is 0.241. ** Significant at the 0.05 level. *** Significant at the 0.01 level.

  28. In the model without population growth, the test statistic (6.78) is higher than the critical value of a Chi-squared at the 0.05 level of confidence (Chi-squared 2 df, 5% = 5.99), lower at 0.01 level Chi-squared (2 df, 1% = 9.21), with a Prob > Chi-squared of 0.035. In the model with population growth, the test statistic is 4.02 and the Prob > Chi-squared equals 0.255.

  29. The coefficients of the random-effects model (with robust option) are the following. Without population growth: constant 0.0028, B1 −0.0091 (***), B2 0.0059 (***); R 2 is 0.153. With population growth: constant 0.0280 (***), B1 −0.0057 (**), B2 0.0061 (***), B3 −0.0290 (***); R 2 is 0.288.

  30. It would be possible to estimate attendance rates of compulsory orders only for a few benchmarks: 1881–1882, 1891–1892 (Maic 1882, 1883, 1892), for the 1930s (Istat 1931, 1938), and for 2001 (Istat 2005).

  31. By 2001, they were truly negligible (Istat 2005).

  32. For 1901, the correlation between the number of members of friendly societies and Nuzzo’s index of social participation is unsurprisingly very high (Pearson coefficient 0.892 and significant at the 0.001 level).

  33. In this case, the Pearson correlation between the number of local newspapers in 1901 and Nuzzo’s index of political participation is low (coefficient 0.219 significant at the 0.05 level, excluding the outlier Sardinia), but it is worth noting that this discrepancy is mitigated by the use of the same ratio between observed and unobserved variables (see Table 10).

  34. Unsurprisingly, for 1901 the new benchmark is highly correlated with Nuzzo’s index of trust (Pearson coefficient 0.845, significant at the 0.001 level, excluding the outlier Marches).

  35. Without the outliers in social capital (Trentino-Alto Adige and Aosta Valley), the Pearson correlations between the two equal −0.511 in 1891, −0.560 in 1911, −0.890 in 1938, −0.875 in 1951, −0.817 in 1971, −0.775 in 1981 and −0.675 in 2001 (all significant at the 0.01 level, with the exception of 1891 and 1911 significant at the 0.05 level).

References

  • A’Hearn B (1998) Institutions, externalities, and economic growth in Southern Italy: evidence from the cotton textile industry, 1861–1914. Econ Hist Rev 51(4):734–762

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • A’Hearn B (2000) Could Southern Italians cooperate? Banche Popolari in the Mezzogiorno. J Econ His 60(1):67–93

    Google Scholar 

  • A’Hearn B, Auria C, Vecchi G (2011) Istruzione. In: Vecchi G (ed) In ricchezza e in povertà. Il benessere degli italiani dall’Unità a oggi. Il Mulino, Bologna, 159–206

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2005) Institutions as a fundamental cause of long run growth. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 385–472

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Banfield E (1958) The moral basis of a backward society. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ (1991) Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q J Econ 106(2):407–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1991) Convergence across states and regions. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:107–182

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Convergence. J Pol Econ 100:223–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1962) Investment in human capital: a theoretical analysis. J Pol Econ 70(5):9–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1964) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education. NBER, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker SO, Woessmann L (2009) Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. Q J Econ 124(2):531–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker SO, Hornung E, Woessmann L (2011) Education and catch-up in the industrial revolution. Am Econ J Macroecon 3(3):92–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bils M, Klenow PJ (2000) Does schooling cause growth? Am Econ Rev 90(5):1160–1183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti A, Felice E, Vecchi G (2011) Reddito. In: Vecchi G (ed) In ricchezza e in povertà. Il benessere degli italiani dall’Unità a oggi. Il Mulino, Bologna, pp 209–234

  • Cafagna L (1965) Intorno alle origini del dualismo economico in Italia. In: Caracciolo A (ed) Problemi storici dell’industrializzazione e dello sviluppo. Argalia, Urbino, pp 103–150

  • Cafagna L (1989) Dualismo e sviluppo nella storia d’Italia. Marsilio, Venice

    Google Scholar 

  • Cartocci R (2007) Mappe del tesoro. Atlante del capitale sociale in Italia. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccarelli C, Fenoaltea S (2010) Through the magnifying glass: provincial aspects of industrial growth in post-Unification Italy. Quaderni di Storia Economica 4. Bank of Italy, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccarelli C, Fenoaltea S, Proietti T (2010) The effects of unification: markets, policy, and cyclical convergence in Italy, 1861–1913. Cliometrica 4(3):269–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla CM (1969) Literacy and development in the West. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman J (1988) Social capital in the creation of human capital. Am J Sociol 94:S95–S121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costantini V, Monni S (2005) Sustainable Human Development for European Countries. J Human Dev 6(3):329–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotula F, Raganelli T, Sannucci V (eds) (1996) I bilanci delle aziende di credito: 1890–1936. Laterza, Rome-Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts NFR (1996) The first industrial revolution: a guided tour for growth economists. Am Econ Rev 86(2):197–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniele V, Malanima P (2007) Il prodotto delle regioni e il divario Nord-Sud in Italia (1861–2004). Rivista di Politica Economica 67(3–4):267–315

    Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JRW (2005) Growth econometrics. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 555–677

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin RA (1981) Why isn’t the whole world developed? J Econ His 61(1):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federico G (2003) Le nuove stime della produzione agricola italiana, 1860–1910: primi risultati e implicazioni. Rivista di Storia Economica 19(3):359–381

  • Felice E (2005a) Il valore aggiunto regionale. Una stima per il 1891 e per il 1911 e alcune elaborazioni di lungo periodo (1891–1971). Rivista di Storia Economica 21(3):83–124

  • Felice E (2005b) Il reddito delle regioni italiane nel 1938 e nel 1951. Una stima basata sul costo del lavoro. Rivista di Storia Economica 21(1):3–30

  • Felice E (2007a) I divari regionali in Italia sulla base degli indicatori sociali (1871–2001). Rivista di Politica Economica 67(3–4):359–405

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice E (2007b) Divari regionali e intervento pubblico. Per una rilettura dello sviluppo in Italia. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice E (2008) The correlation between human capital and economic performance. Historical evidence and some hypotheses for the Italian regions (1871–2001). Il Risparmio 56(2):55–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice E (2010) Regional development: reviewing the Italian mosaic. J Mod Italian Studies 15(1):64–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felice E (2011) Regional value added in Italy, 1891–2001, and the foundation of a long-term picture. Econ Hist Rev 64(3):929–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenoaltea S (2003) Peeking backward: regional aspects of industrial growth in post-unification Italy. J Econ His 63(4):1059–1102

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenoaltea S (2006) L’economia italiana dall’Unità alla Grande guerra. Laterza, Rome-Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Franklin R (2003) Italian fertility, 1864 to 1961: an analysis of regional trends. Mimeo 2003, downloadable at http://www-sre.wu-wien.ac.at/ersa/ersaconfs/ersa03/cdrom/papers/542.pdf. Last access on Dec 2010

  • Goldin C, Katz L (2008) The race between education and technology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2008a) Social capital as good culture. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(2–3):295–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2008b) Long-term persistence. NBER working paper no. 14278, downloadable at http://www.nber.org/papers/w14278.pdf. Last access on July 2011

  • Helliwell JF, Putnam R (1995) Economic growth and social capital in Italy. East Econ J 21(3):295–307

    Google Scholar 

  • Iona A, Leonida L, Sobbrio G (2008) ‘O convergence where art thou?’ Regional growth and industrialization in Italy. J Mod Italian Stud 13(3):366–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1931) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1931. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1938) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1938. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1939) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1939. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1941) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1941. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1954) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1953. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1972) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1972. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1974) 11 Censimento generale della popolazione. 24 ottobre 1971, vol V, Sesso, età, stato civile. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1982) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1982. Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (1985) 12 Censimento generale della popolazione. 25 ottobre 1981, vol VII. Dati sulle caratteristiche strutturali della popolazione e delle abitazioni, Rome

  • Istat, Istituto Centrale di Statistica (2005) 14° Censimento generale della popolazione e delle abitazioni (http://dawinci.istat.it/MD/). Last access on July 2011

  • Leonardi R (1995) Convergence, cohesion and integration in the European Union. Macmillan, Houndmills

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Leonardi R (2005) Cohesion policy in the European Union. The building of Europe. Macmillan, Houndmills

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Livi-Bacci M (1977) A history of italian fertility during the last two centuries. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Ljungberg J, Nilsson A (2009) Human capital and economic growth: Sweden 1870–2000. Cliometrica 3(1):71–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1878) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1878. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1881) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1881. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1882) Statistica dell’istruzione elementare. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1883) Statistica dell’istruzione elementare. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1892) Statistica dell’istruzione elementare. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1893) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1892. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1900) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1900. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1908) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1905–07. Rome

  • Maic, Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio (1914) Annuario Statistico Italiano, 1913. Rome

  • Mankiw G, Romer D, Weil D (1992) A contribution to the Empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 102(2):402–437

    Google Scholar 

  • Nardi E (2001) Il progetto nazionale Ocse-Pisa 2000. Downloadable at http://www.scribd.com/doc/17681430/Il-progetto-OCSEPisa-2000. Last access on July 2011

  • Nuñez CE (1990) Literacy and economic growth in Spain 1860–1977. In: Tortella G (ed) Education and economic development since the industrial revolution. Generalitat Valenciana, Valencia, pp 29–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Nuzzo G (2006) Un secolo di statistiche sociali: persistenza o convergenza tra le regioni italiane? Quaderni dell’Ufficio Ricerche Storiche 11. Bank of Italy, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Prados de la Escosura L, Rosés JR (2010) Human capital and economic growth in Spain, 1850–2000. Explor Econ Hist 47(4):520–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1994) Returns to investment in education: a global update. World Dev 22(9):1325–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G, Patrison HA (2002) Returns to investment in education. A further update. The world bank policy research working paper

  • Putnam RD (1993) Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton University Press, Princeton (With Leonardi R and Nanetti RY)

  • Ram R (1990) Educational expansion and schooling inequality: international evidence and some implications. Rev Econ Stat 72(2):266–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ram R (1991) Education and the convergence hypothesis: additional cross-country evidence. Economia Internazionale 44:244–253

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long run growth. J Pol Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sabatini F (2008) Social capital and the quality of economic development. Kyklos 61(3):466–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin X, Doppelhofer G, Miller RI (2004) Determinants of long term growth: a Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. Am Econ Rev 94(4):813–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz T (1960) Capital formation by education. J Pol Econ 68(6):571–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz T (1961) Investment in human capital. Am Econ Rev 51(1):1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulze MS, Fernandes FT (2009) Human capital formation in Austria-Hungary and Germany: time series estimates of educational attainment, 1860–1910. In: Halmos K et al. (eds). A felhalmozás Míve. Történeti Tanulmányok Kövér György Tiszteletére. Századvég Kiadó, Budapest pp 275–289

  • Sianesi B, Van Reenen J (2003) The returns to education: macroeconomics. J Econ Surveys 17(2):157–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70(1):65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swan T (1956) Economic growth and capital accumulation. Econ Rec 32(4):334–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini G (2005) Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe. Igier working paper 292

  • Vasta M (1996) Innovative capabilities in the Italian take-off: the electrical and chemical industries (1880–1914). University of Oxford, D. Phil thesis

  • Vasta M (1999) Innovazione tecnologica e capitale umano in Italia (1880–1914). Le traiettorie della seconda rivoluzione industriale. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson J (1965) Regional inequality and the process of national development: a description of the pattern. Econ Dev Cult Change 13(4):3–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wößmann L (2003) Specifying human capital. J Econ Surveys 17(3):239–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni V (1978) Istruzione e sviluppo economico. Il caso italiano 1861–1913. In: Toniolo G (ed) L’economia italiana 1861–1940. Laterza, Bari, pp 137–178

  • Zamagni V (1993) L’offerta di istruzione in Italia 1861–1987: un fattore guida dello sviluppo o un ostacolo? Working paper of the economics Department of the University of Cassino 4

Download references

Acknowledgments

The ideas leading to this paper have been discussed among associates and friends on several occasions, and helpful suggestions have come, sometimes accidentally, from Brian A’Hearn, Carlo D’Ippoliti, Rui Pedro Esteves, Giovanni Federico, Stefano Fenoalta, Renato Giannetti, Ferdinando Giugliano, Paolo Malanima, Salvatore Monni, Luke Samy, Max-Stephan Schulze, Daniel Tirado, Michelangelo Vasta, and Vera Zamagni. The usual disclaimers apply. The author gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministry for Science and Innovation, project HAR2010-20684-C02-01.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Emanuele Felice.

Appendix: regional estimates of human capital, social capital and fertility: sources and methods

Appendix: regional estimates of human capital, social capital and fertility: sources and methods

1.1 Human capital

The weighting scheme of the human capital composite indicator has been illustrated in Sect. 3. It was devised with the aim of reducing arbitrariness when choosing between the different components of the index, while allowing for the shift in importance from primary to advanced education which took place over the long run. As can be seen from Tables 8, 9, for Liberal Italy, the index of human capital is composed of literacy, with a weight decreasing from 70% in 1871 to 38% in 1911, and primary and secondary enrolment rate, with a weight growing from 30% in 1871 to 58% in 1911; the shares assigned to tertiary and higher education still are negligible. These latter began to grow significantly in the interwar period, touching one-fifth by 1951; in this year, primary and secondary enrolment rate has the lion share of the indicator, almost 70%, whereas to literacy is left a mere 13%. As around the mid of the twentieth century, the overwhelming percentage of the Italian population had become literate, these changes follow the assumption—which seems only reasonable—that differences in a minority of illiterate people no longer affected economic growth in any significant way. During the post–Second World War economic boom, compulsory education extended throughout the country and regional differences became less and less important (see again Tables 8, 9). Furthermore, as the industrialization spread and technological regimes changed, the characteristics of human capital as a factor of production arguably changed too: i.e., what mattered rather more was tertiary (non-compulsory) education attended from age 14 to 19 and later higher education, from age 19 to 24 and above. This change is captured by the human capital indicator: from 1971 to 2001, about one-third of the indicator is made up of tertiary education enrolment rate, and the share of higher education enrolment rate has grown from 10 to 22%. By 2001, when combined, these two indices total almost 60% of the human capital indicator; primary and secondary enrolment rate is around 40%, and literacy has fallen to a negligible share.

Table 8 A composite and dynamic index of human capital for Italy’s regions: components and weights (part 1)
Table 9 A composite and dynamic index of human capital for Italy’s regions: components and weights (part 2)

A serious problem arises when dealing with regional figures for university enrolment: as evident in Tables 8, 9, these tend to seriously underestimate small regions (Aosta Valley, Trentino-Alto Adige, Lucania), which did not host a university or higher education institute for most of the twentieth century. University students from small regions temporarily emigrated to the cities of the larger regions, often returning to their homes after gaining their degrees—this interregional mobility increased markedly during recent decades. However, mobility between the three macro-regions (North-West, Centre/North-East, South and islands) was much lower and, even when the flows were remarkable, namely in the mobility from the South to the North, the return rates were considerably lower, so much so that, by and large, emigrating students could be considered as effectively acquired by the host regions. For these reasons, I calculate and use a new index of university attendance, which is based on macro-regional scores and on the regional enrolment ratios of tertiary education, according to the formula: newUr = Tr/Tm*Um, where U is university attendance, T is tertiary education, r is the region and m the macro-region. In other words, I assume that each region follows the university attendance of its macro-region, proportional to its rate of tertiary education enrolment (due to lack of space, the new index is omitted, but it can be easily derived from the figures in Tables 8, 9).

It is worth stressing that we always refer to the gross enrolment ratio, i.e., the total number of students enrolled (including repeaters and other students above/below the respective age brackets) as a percentage of the official population for a given level of education. Of course, the net enrolment ratio (the students enrolled of the official age group for a given level of education, as a percentage of the corresponding population) and even more attendance rates (the number of people attending a given level of education, as a percentage of the corresponding population), which in turn can be gross or net, would be preferable; but the available sources are not suitable for any long-term and consistent quantification of these variables (cfr. A’Hearn et al. 2011, pp. 180–181),Footnote 30 as with most of the countries around the world. As far as we can tell, however, North–South differentials in attendance, and more in general differences between enrolment and attendance, were in the liberal age higher than later (A’Hearn et al. pp. 187–193): i.e., they decreased over the course of the twentieth century.Footnote 31 As a consequence, a possible revised human capital indicator, which would allow for regional changes in attendance over the long run, would probably show even higher convergence than the human capital indicator here presented.

The problem of the quality of education is maybe different, regional inequality probably persisted, but the solution (or lack of it) here proposed is analogous. Out of necessity: today PISA (Programme for International Student Assessment) data, which measure the knowledge and skills of 15-year-old students for many countries including Italy, show some North–South differences, but they are available only from 2000 onwards (Nardi 2001).

In general, the use of a composite indicator tends to increase regional (North–South) differences in human capital in the last decades, as compared to alternative unvarying measures of human capital such as literacy or the total enrolment rate: It does not come as a surprise that, as illustrated in Sect. 3, the use of alternative (and arguably less questionable) measures does not invalidate the overall result of the article, i.e., that human capital became less important in the last decades (For cross-section estimates confirming this result, see also Felice 2008). The same can be said for out-of-reach more accurate measures, such as attendance rates. These are good reasons to believe that the view taken by the present article is by and large correct. However, Tables 8, 9 are intended to provide any interested reader with full information about the individual components of the index and their trends, in order to make the methodology proposed entirely transparent, and amendable.

1.2 Social capital

In this article, new estimates of social capital at the regional level are presented for two benchmark years, 1871 and 1891, whereas for other benchmarks (from 1901 onwards) the available figures by Giorgio Nuzzo are employed. In order to achieve a comprehensive and coherent long-term picture, the new benchmarks have been reconstructed through a methodology explicitly linked to Nuzzo’s. However, when compared with the benchmarks from 1901 onwards, for 1871 and 1891 there were less indicators available and thus, in order to come to consistent figures, the hypothesis had to be introduced that, for each dimension of social capital, the ratio between the observed variables and the unobserved ones in 1891 was the same as in 1901, and in 1871 the same as in 1891.

As mentioned, Nuzzo’s indicator is a simple mean of social participation, political participation and trust. Social participation is measured by an average of different non-profit institutions, i.e., those which, according to the author, effectively generated social capital (significantly, unions were excluded). For the second half of the nineteenth century, we can rely upon friendly societies, which were also used by Nuzzo for 1901: In both cases, the indicator is the number of members of such friendly societies, as a ratio to the total population. As a first step, data for 1904, 1895 and 1873 (the years for which data were available) have been extrapolated backwards in order to create the 1871, 1891 and 1901 benchmarks, via linear interpolation with the continuous compounding yearly rate. As a second step, in 1891, social participation has been estimated from the member of friendly societies in 1891 and by maintaining, for every region, the 1901 ratio of social participation/members of friendly societies, as in the equation:

$$ R_{sp} 1891 = Rmf1891\times\left( {Rsp1901/Rmf1901} \right) $$
(4)

where R is the region, sp is social participation, and mf is the number of members of friendly societies.Footnote 32 Finally, this procedure has been replicated for 1871, using the 1891 estimate of social participation in place of Nuzzo’s figure for 1901. The number of friendly societies and the total amount of deposits of the banche popolari have been tested too, alone or in combination (to also include the number of members), but they turned out to be weakly correlated with Nuzzo’s figures.

Nuzzo’s indicator of political participation is an average of the densities of political non-profit institutions, of the share of voters out of the total population at different elections and of an informal indicator based on polls taken from 1993 to 2003 concerning political engagement. For 1901, the author relied only on the density of political non-profit institutions. For the second half of the nineteenth century, we lack this information, but we can avail ourselves of the use of statistics on local newspapers, an indicator in line with Putnam’s approach, where the readers of newspapers are used as a proxy of political participation. In our case, we have data about the number of local newspapers published in 1880 (1454), 1891 (1779), 1895 (1901) and 1905 (3120), which, via linear interpolation with the continuous compounding yearly rate, have been used to create 1871, 1891 and 1901 regional benchmarks; as can be seen from the figures in brackets, the numbers are relatively high, which partly comforts about the reliability of the proxy used. The rest of the procedure is analogous to the one outlined for calculating social participation, with the difference that in this case, regional data on local newspapers are linked to Nuzzo’s index of political participation.Footnote 33

Nuzzo’s indicator of trust is measured by the inverse of an average of estimates of violent criminality and of court proceedings, as well as of the share of perceived criminality as determined by polls conducted in 1995 and 2003. For the second half of the nineteenth century, we can make use of almost the same data as those used by Nuzzo for 1901. More in particular, trust is approximated through the inverse of an average of criminal and civil court proceedings in 1901–1904, 1891 and (here only criminal court proceedings) 1871.Footnote 34 Here too, at this point, the procedure is analogous to the one outlined for the other two dimensions, in this case the data being correlated with Nuzzo’s index of trust. For 1871, since only criminal statistics were available, these were in turn correlated with criminal statistics in 1891 and with the index of trust in 1891.

For each component, the regional data of the two-step procedure are shown in Table 10. By construction, the results are in line with Nuzzo’s benchmarks.

Table 10 The components of social capital in 1871, 1891 and 1901 (Italy = 1)

1.3 Fertility and population growth

Figures of fertility and population growth are shown in Table 11. As can be observed also by the naked eye, usually differences in fertility rates do not automatically equal differences in population growth; in fact, in all the panel models (random and fixed effects), fertility is not significant as a predictor of population growth, although it certainly has a positive effect. More specifically, Southern Italy scored fertility rates above the Italian average throughout the period, but a population growth below the average up to the 1970s, with the exception of the years 1938–1951. Although differences in mortality rates were important to some extent, the main reason for this was migration, both interregional and international, which depopulated Southern Italy through most of the period (but it came almost to a halt in the 1930s, only to resume again in the 1950s). From the 1970s, migration from the south played a much diminished role, and thus for the first time, not having reduced their gap in fertility rates, the Southern regions experienced a population growth higher than the Italian average. This difference is apparently more important than the one in social capital, when it comes to explaining the decline in the south in recent decades. It could be, however, that differences in social capital also determined differences in fertility rates, at least to some extent and perhaps until very recently. In any event, the two variables appear to be highly correlated in the last decades: Their correlation grows from 1911 to 1938 and remains significantly high at least until the 1980s.Footnote 35 Needless to say, this is another topic that deserves thorough consideration in further research.

Table 11 Fertility rates and population growth for Italy’s regions (Italy = 1)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Felice, E. Regional convergence in Italy, 1891–2001: testing human and social capital. Cliometrica 6, 267–306 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-011-0076-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-011-0076-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation