A sticky floors model of promotion, pay, and gender

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00197-0Get rights and content

Abstract

According to raw data from the British Household Panel Survey, full-time women are more likely than men to be promoted. Controlling for observed and unobserved individual heterogeneity, we find that women are promoted at roughly the same rate as men, but may receive smaller wage increases consequent upon promotion. To help explain these phenomena, we construct a new “sticky floors” model of pay and promotion. In our model, women are just as likely as men to be promoted but find themselves stuck at the bottom of the wage scale for the new grade.

Introduction

It is well established that women fare badly in the labour market relative to men. But how does the status of women change over the course of their careers? Do ‘glass ceilings’ exacerbate the male–female wage differential, or are women able to take advantage of promotions to catch up partially to male wage rates?

Recent evidence from the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS) shows that women are just as likely as men to be promoted. Over 1991–1995, full-time male workers had only a 9percent chance of receiving a promotion each year compared to 11percent for full-time female workers. However, the BHPS data also show that the wages of promoted men grow 4.7percent faster than the wages of non-promoted men, while the wages of promoted women grow only 1.3percent faster than those of non-promoted women. These stylised facts suggest that standard views of glass ceilings may not tell the full story about gender and promotions. The disadvantage women face in the promotions process may be in the salary rewards to promotion, not in the likelihood of being promoted.

To examine these issues, we develop a model of promotions, pay and gender that distinguishes between the initial pay increase upon promotion and subsequent pay increases. We assume that the initial pay increase is set by the firm to induce workers to put in additional effort to acquire specific human capital. Once the worker is promoted and paid this higher wage, however, the firm has no reason to continue to increase wages in the absence of outside offers. Women may receive fewer outside market offers than men or may be less able to take advantage of them due to family commitments. Firms may respond differently to outside offer threats from women and men owing to discrimination. On the other hand, as in Lazear and Rosen (1990), women may have better non-market opportunities than men. Our framework is sufficiently general to allow us to develop the implications of these differing assumptions for gender differences in promotions, in pay for those promoted who remain at the firm, in pay for those promoted who leave the firm to other market opportunities, and to quit rates to other firms and to non-market alternatives. We then use our theoretical framework to inform the empirical analysis of data from the first five waves of the BHPS, 1991–1995. The empirical analysis allows us to draw conclusions about the validity of the different assumptions about outside opportunities and firms’ reactions to those outside opportunities.

In our model, under the Lazear and Rosen assumptions that women have better non-market opportunities than men, they are less likely to be promoted than men but more likely to receive higher wages if promoted, although this second result depends upon assumptions about the functional form of the distribution of outside opportunities. Women are more likely to quit to non-market opportunities. However, if instead the driving assumption is that women have worse market opportunities than men, they are more likely to be promoted than men, less likely to quit to new jobs, and are likely to receive lower wage gains than men. Alternatively, if the driving assumption is that firms are less likely to match outside offers for women, men and women are equally likely to be promoted, women are likely to receive lower wage gains than men if they remain at the firm or if they leave, and are more likely to quit. We use the term ‘sticky floors’ to refer to the situation—arising either due to worse market alternatives or to less favourable firm responses to outside offers for women—where women are promoted as often as men, but receive lower wage gains consequent upon promotion. In firms with formal wage scales, women remain stuck to the lower wage points on the wage scale of their new, higher job grade.

For the purposes of this paper, a representative panel data source such as the BHPS is particularly appropriate. This is because it covers a large number of workers employed in different firms and occupations, so that the information on promotions and wages arises from a wide range of current practices in the British labour market as a whole. Moreover, the data contain a wealth of individual and work-related characteristics to be used as controls, and the panel nature of the survey allows us to test our model of pay and promotion while accounting for individual unobserved heterogeneity. In contrast, the use of personnel records of a single firm—even if the data set had sufficient individual characteristics recorded—would limit us to the behaviour of that firm, and not allow us to make inferences about average behaviour in the labour market. For example, it is possible that some firms discriminate while others do not. There may also be objective reasons for different promotion practices. These factors may explain why studies based upon single firm data show conflicting results. Cobb-Clark (1998) has recently surveyed the empirical literature, which consists predominantly of studies based upon personnel records from a single firm.1 She finds that the literature contains no clear results and, depending upon the sample, women are promoted more, less, or the same as men.

The estimates presented in our paper suggest that existing theories about gender differences in promotion need to be supplemented by the sticky floors models of promotion. We find that there is no significant difference in the promotion rates between men and women, an outcome that runs counter to the predictions of some traditional models, but is explicable under the assumptions of the sticky floors models. Using suitable controls, and correcting for unobserved heterogeneity, we also find some (albeit insignificant by conventional statistical standards) support for the sticky floors claim that women gain lower wage increases from promotion. There is, however, some support for the Lazear and Rosen model from the evidence about quits. The only significant gender differences for quits are for those out of the labour force, as that model would predict. Overall, however, it is clear that the promotions process does not systematically mitigate the general disadvantage women face in the labour market. Importantly, however, the mechanisms operating are not the simple glass ceilings ones of an unfavourable promotions rate for women, but involve lower wage returns to promotion for women.

Section snippets

The model

We develop a two-period model of specific human capital and promotion. The economy has a large spot labour market. Workers can leave this market to join a ‘career’ firm offering specific training leading to promotion. Following Landers et al. (1996), we emphasise the role of effort in determining who is promoted.2

The data

We examine the relationship between promotion, wages and gender using the first five waves of the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS). This is a nationally representative random sample survey of private households in Britain. Interviews were conducted during the autumn of 1991, and annually thereafter (see Taylor, 1996). The BHPS provides information on the timing and type of job changes made by a worker, including job changes at the same employer as well as across firms. For all jobs ended

Who gets promoted?

The sticky floors models outlined in Section 2 predict that women are at least as likely as men to be promoted. We test this hypothesis in a multivariate framework using probit regressions with a number of different specifications. Table 2 presents the estimated gender effect for these specifications, along with the estimated effect of a number of effort proxies. The estimated effects of the other variables are not particularly interesting, and are therefore not presented in the table. Full

Who gets higher wages after promotion?

We now consider the impact of promotion and gender on wages. The sticky floors models in Section 2 predict that, while promoted women may at first gain the same wage increase as promoted men, they do not continue to benefit from wage increases to the same extent as men. In contrast, the Lazear and Rosen assumptions imply that promoted women are likely to gain higher average wage increases than men. To exploit the longitudinal nature of the data, we estimated both random-effects (RE) and

Who quits after a promotion?

In Section 2, we observed that the quit rates of promoted women might provide evidence that supported one of our sticky floors approaches over the other. As seen in Section 2, the BHPS stylised facts—that women are as likely as men to be promoted, but receive lower wage gains consequent upon promotion—might arise either because women receive less favourable outside offers (or are less mobile and therefore unable to take up offers) or because their current firm does not respond to those offers

Conclusions

The use of individual panel data, such as the BHPS, provides a new perspective on previously accepted stylised facts about the gender gap in promotions and wages. Our results show that women are at least as likely as men to be promoted. They either gain the same wage increase consequent on promotion, or a smaller one. It is clear from the raw data and the estimates that the promotion process does not systematically mitigate the general disadvantage women face in the labour market. It may very

Acknowledgements

For helpful comments on an earlier draft, we thank Mary Gregory, Steve Nickell, Jan van Ours, seminar participants at the Universities of Amsterdam and Essex, the Tinbergen Institute, the Netherlands Central Planning Bureau, the 1998 CEPR Labour Workshop in Gerzensee (Switzerland), the 1998 Leverhulme Essex-Oxford Workshop at Oxford, two anonymous referees, and the Editor Steve Pischke. We are grateful to the European Commission TSER Award “Labour Demand, Education and the Dynamics of Social

References (20)

  • W. Groot et al.

    Glass ceilings or dead ends: Job promotion of men and women compared

    Economics Letters

    (1996)
  • Audas, R.P., Barmby, T., Treble, J.G., 1997. Gender and promotion in an internal labour market....
  • G. Baker et al.

    The internal economics of the firm: Evidence from personnel data

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1994)
  • G. Baker et al.

    The wage policy of a firm

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1994)
  • D. Bernhardt et al.

    Promotion, turnover, and preemptive wage offers

    American Economic Review

    (1993)
  • Booth, A.L., Francesconi, M., Frank, J., 1998. Glass ceilings or sticky floors? Centre for Economic Policy Research...
  • A.L. Booth et al.

    Seniority, earnings and unions

    Economica

    (1996)
  • T. Breusch et al.

    The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1980)
  • Cobb-Clark, D.A., 1998. Getting ahead: The determinants of and payoffs to internal promotion for young men and women....
  • M. Francesconi

    Determinants and consequences of promotions in Britain

    Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics

    (2001)
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (241)

View all citing articles on Scopus
View full text