Elsevier

World Development

Volume 27, Issue 12, December 1999, Pages 2021-2044
World Development

Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(99)00104-7Get rights and content

Abstract

On the basis of themes emerging in current debates on rural development in Latin America, this paper develops an analytical framework for analyzing rural livelihoods in terms of their sustainability and their implications for rural poverty. The framework argues that our analyses of rural livelihoods need to understand them in terms of: (a) people’s access to five types of capital asset; (b) the ways in which they combine and transform those assets in the building of livelihoods that as far as possible meet their material and their experiential needs; (c) the ways in which people are able to expand their asset bases through engaging with other actors through relationships governed by the logics of the state, market and civil society; and (d) the ways in which they are able to deploy and enhance their capabilities both to make living more meaningful and to change the dominant rules and relationships governing the ways in which resources are controlled, distributed and transformed in society. Particular attention is paid to the importance of social capital as an asset through which people are able to widen their access to resources and other actors.

Introduction

This paper is a response to the disappointing effects of development interventions in the high Andes and other such “marginal” environments Zoomers, 1998, Van Niekerk, 1997. It is not, though, an inquiry into why those impacts have been so limited; it is instead an effort to develop a framework that broadens our conception of rural livelihoods in such a way that may help rethink the nature, location and content of interventions so that they are more consonant with the diverse ways in which people make a living and build their worlds. As Zoomers (1998) has recently suggested for the Andes, and as Scott (1998) has argued more generally, one important reason projects fail is probably that they simply misperceive the way people get by and get things done. In particular, I want to suggest that a large part of the problem is that interventions work with ways of seeing the world that continue to crunch rural livelihoods into the category of agricultural and natural resource-based strategies. Even sophisticated frameworks aiming to analyze rural resource use emphasize access to environmental resources and ultimately convey an image of rural people making their living from natural resources (Leach, Mearns and Scoones, 1998, p. 7).1

This paper is therefore an attempt to build a framework that approaches rural livelihoods and poverty without automatically linking their analysis to agriculture or natural resources. In developing its case, the paper builds on recent writing on environmental entitlements Leach et al., 1998, Leach et al., 1998 as well as the wider literature on access to resources Africa, 1989, Bryant, 1992, Ribot, 1998. It aims to develop these frameworks further in several ways. In the remainder of this introduction let me anticipate these different elaborations.

First, I argue that it is important to have a wide conception of the resources that people need to access in the process of composing a livelihood, perhaps especially in a context where peoples’ livelihoods shift from being directly based on natural resources, to livelihoods based on a range of assets, income sources and product and labor markets.2 This leads me to consider livelihoods in terms of access to five types of “capital” asset3—produced, human, natural, social and cultural capital (cf. Bebbington et al., 1997, Bebbington, 1997, Scoones, 1998, Carney, 1998). This conceptualization has a related benefit, perhaps more potential than so far real, of conceiving livelihood sustainability within a framework that could also be used for thinking of regional and national sustainability (cf. World Bank, 1996, World Bank, 1997), thus suggesting elements of a framework that could link levels of analysis in research and practice addressing the relationship between environment, society and development (cf. Blaikie, 1989, Blaikie, 1985).

Second, the paper suggests that we need a framework that bridges the more materialist (cf. World Bank, 1990) and the more hermeneutic and actor-centered (cf. Chambers, 1987, Scoones and Thompson, 1994) notions of poverty and livelihood.4 We therefore require a notion of access to resources that helps us not only understand the way in which people deal with poverty in a material sense (by making a living), but also the ways in which: their perceptions of well-being and poverty are related to their livelihood choices and strategies; and the capacities that they possess both to add to their quality of life and also enhance their capabilities to confront the social conditions that produce poverty. In the framework advanced here, then:

  • (a) peoples’ assets are not merely means through which they make a living: they also give meaning to the person’s world. This is not to fall into the trap of voluntarism, for of course a person’s assets are in large part determined by the structures and logics at work in economic and political spheres (see below). They are, however, also—to some extent—both reflections and components of the meaning the person has tried to create through their livelihood strategies. This meaning will then be one of several influences in subsequent decisions people make about their livelihood strategies;

  • (b) assets—or what I call capitals in this framework—are not simply resources that people use in building livelihoods: they are assets that give them the capability to be and to act. Sen (1997) has noted that the possession of human capital not only means people produce more, and more efficiently; it also gives them the capability to engage more fruitfully and meaningfully with the world, and most importantly the capability to change the world. The same is also true, in other ways, for the other types of capital. The framework thus understands these assets not only as things that allow survival, adaptation and poverty alleviation: they are also the basis of agents’ power to act and to reproduce, challenge or change the rules that govern the control, use and transformation of resources (cf. Giddens, 1979).

In some sense, this framework thus sees assets as vehicles for instrumental action (making a living), hermeneutic action (making living meaningful) and emancipatory action (challenging the structures under which one makes a living) (cf. Habermas, 1971).

Third, and critically, to conceive of livelihoods as partly dependent upon households’ social capital offers a more integrated framework for thinking about access to resources. Indeed, seen this way, the distinction between access and resources breaks down,5 because access becomes perhaps the most critical resource of all if people are to build sustainable, poverty alleviating rural livelihoods.

Fourth, it is important that a framework understanding poverty in terms of assets also incorporates an analysis of the economic, social and political relationships that create poverty and wealth, but in such a way that (i) understands these relationships as potentially contingent and subject to re-negotiation, and (ii) links this contingency to the capabilities that people have as a result of the assets at their disposal. Assets are thus as much implicated in empowerment and change, as they are in survival and “getting by.”6 It is in this sense that access and social capital are central elements to the framework. They are the concepts for analyzing the relationships and transactions between the members of a rural household and other actors—relationships mediated by the logics of the state, the market and civil society. As rural people try and access resources they do so through engaging in relationships with other actors who are both present but more often than not usually absent from the day-to-day activities of rural people. Indeed access to other actors is conceptually prior to access to material resources in the determination of livelihood strategies, for such relationships become almost sine qua non mechanisms through which resources are distributed and claimed, and through which the broader social, political and market logics governing the control, use and transformation of resources are either reproduced or changed.

The social capital debate helps develop this aspect of the framework, for it helps us understand how actors engage with other actors in the spheres of market, state and civil society in order to gain access to resources, to influence the de jure rules of access in a society, or to turn their assets into commodity bundles (cf. Sen, 1981, Evans, 1996). Building on this debate, the paper also argues that we ought not automatically link the access question to the notion of “conflict over access” (Bryant, 1992, pp. 21–24)—not for reasons of linguistic tone, but rather for reasons of empirical balance, for indeed, there may be as much initiative and collaboration in widening access as there is conflict in the process of securing it. It is therefore important to develop frameworks that capture all these dimensions of access, and not only the conflictual—they must capture both the dynamics of conflict emphasized by Leach, Mearns and Scoones (1998), and those of cooperation emphasized more by authors such as Evans (1996) and Tendler (1997).

Most of the paper elaborates these different aspects of the framework. In developing its arguments, the geographic focus of much of the discussion and many of the examples is the Andean region. The themes are, though, of far wider relevance for thinking about sustainable rural livelihoods and economies. First, the paper reviews the changing ways in which rural livelihoods and poverty have been debated and analyzed. The debates on rural livelihoods have—perhaps more implicitly than explicitly—come to demonstrate how the resolution of access to resources and institutional spheres is critical in determining the relative viability and sustainability of livelihoods, thus justifying a conception of livelihoods rooted in a notion of access. Second, I present the basic elements of the capitals framework, and then suggest several ways in which this framework could usefully be developed. The final section focuses on one of the five capitals in particular, suggesting ways in which the concept of social capital might help us elaborate the relationship between access, institutions and livelihood.

Section snippets

Why access to resources? debating peasants and livelihoods in the andes

Access to resources has been a constant theme in debates on peasant (or campesino)7 economy and livelihoods in the Andean region. While some authors have laid far greater emphasis on the constraints on peasant access to resources, others have either been more optimistic about the possibility that this access might be widened, or about the chances of increasing the returns to the resources that households control. This section

Widening the lens: sustainability and capital assets

In a short paper Serageldin and Steer (1994) suggested that we could think of sustainable development in terms of patterns in the accumulation of and substitution among four different types of capital (see also World Bank, 1996). They argued that for a long while, dominant notions (in the World Bank, but also beyond) had equated development with economic growth; hence the only indicator of interest to development planners (and Banks) had been expansion of produced capital.14

Livelihoods, regional economy and national accounts: assets, scale and justice

While Serageldin and Steer apparently cast their framework at the level of the macroeconomy, it can equally be applied to regional economies. Indeed, if it were then possible to develop a suite of indicators for each of the different assets at these different scales, it might be possible to suggest not only the tradeoffs between different types of capital at a macro level, but also the different forms that these tradeoffs take across regions. This might allow a framework for linking

Accessing, defending and transforming: capitals, capabilities and spheres

Along with the notion of the five capitals, the second element of the framework suggested here is the familiar trinity of state, market and civil society (Figure 2): or more precisely the relationships between rural people and other actors who operate within these spheres. It is through such relationships that people (and their organizations) aim to reassert or renegotiate the rules (as defined within each of the spheres) governing access to resources in society: for each sphere has its own

Conclusion

Though useful, because hard-headed, the discussion of campesino viability in the Andes makes three errors I wish to emphasize here. First, it tends to conflate agrarian with rural livelihoods, thus deflecting attention from the myriad transitions that have occurred in the ways through which people make a living, and the diverse assets they draw upon in the process. Second, it implies (even if this is not the intent) that rural people assess livelihood options (and thus their poverty status)

References (98)

  • Africa (1989) Special issue on Access to Resources in Africa. Africa...
  • Barbier, E. (1994) Natural capital and the economics of environment and development. In Investing in Natural Capital:...
  • Baulch, R. (1996) Neglected trade-offs in poverty measurement. IDS Bulletin 27,...
  • Bebbington, A. (1997) Social capital and rural intensification: Local organizations and islands of sustainability in...
  • Bebbington, A. (1996) Organizations and intensifications: Small farmer federations, rural livelihoods and agricultural...
  • Bebbington, A. (1993) Sustainable livelihood development in the Andes? Local institutions and regional resource use in...
  • Bebbington, A., Kopp, A. and Rubinoff, D. (1997) From chaos to strength? Social capital, rural peoples’ organisations...
  • Bebbington, A. J. and Perreault, T. (1999) Social capital, development and access to resources in highland Ecuador....
  • Bebbington, D. (1999) Turning social capital into financial capital: Women's village banking in Ayacucho and Norte...
  • Berdegué, J. (1990) NGOs and Farmers Organizations in Research and Extension in Chile. Agricultural Administration...
  • Berdegué, J et al. (1998) Evaluación del Programa de Transferencia de Tecnologı́a del Instituto de Desarrollo...
  • Bernstein, H. (1979) African peasantries: A theoretical framework. Journal of Peasant Studies 6(4),...
  • Berry, S. (1989) Social institutions and access to resources. Africa 59(1),...
  • Blaikie, P. (1989) Environment and access to resources in Africa. Africa 59(1),...
  • Blaikie, P. (1985) The Political Economy of Soil Erosion in Developing Countries. Longmans, Harlow,...
  • Bromley, R. (1979) The Urban Informal Sector. Pergamon Press,...
  • Brush, S. and Turner, B. L. (1987) The nature of farming systems and views of their change. pp. 11–48 in B. L. Turner...
  • Bryant, R. (1992) Political ecology. An emerging research agenda in Third World Studies. Political Geography 11(1),...
  • Carney, D. ed. (1998) Sustainable Rural Livelihooods. What Contribution Can We Make? Department for International...
  • Chambers, R. (1987) Sustainable Livelihoods, Environment and Development. Putting Poor Rural People First. Discussion...
  • Chambers, R. and Conway, G. (1992) Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: Practical Concepts for the 21st Century. IDS...
  • de Janvry, A. (1981) Land Reform and the Agrarian Question in Latin America. Johns Hopkins University Press,...
  • Deere, C. D. and de Janvry, A. (1979) A conceptual framework for the empirical analysis of peasants. American Journal...
  • Durham, W. (1995) Political ecology and environmental destruction in Latin America. In The Social Causes of Tropical...
  • Durston, J. (1998) Building social capital in rural communities (where it does not exist). Paper prepared for the Latin...
  • Ellis, F. (1998) Survey article: Household strategies and rural livelihood diversification. The Journal of Development...
  • Enriquez, L. (1998) Structural adjustment and the Nicaraguan peasantry: Its varying impact and farmers’ reactions to...
  • Evans, P. (1995) Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton University Press, Princeton,...
  • Evans, P., ed. (1996) State-Society Synergy: Government and Social Capital in Development. Institute for International...
  • FAO (1998) Rural Development Strategy as the Focus Towards the Reduction of Extreme Poverty in the Region. Paper...
  • Figueroa, A. (1990) La via campesina en América Latina....
  • Fox, J., ed. (1990) The Challenge of Rural Democratisation: Perspectives from Latin America and the Philippines. Frank...
  • Fox, J. (1996) How does civil society thicken? The political construction of social capital in Mexico. World...
  • Gellner, B. J. (1982) Colta entrepreneurship in Ecuador: A study of highland indian peddlers and the use of...
  • Giddens, A. (1979) Contemporary Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social Analysis....
  • Grootaert, C. (1997) Social capital, the missing link? Social Development Department, World Bank, Washington,...
  • Grootaert, C., Kanbur, R. and Oh, G. T. (1997) The dynamics of welfare gains and losses: An African case study. Journal...
  • Gwynne, R., ed. (1997) Agrarian change and the democratic transition in Chile. Bulletin for Latin American Research...
  • Habermas, J. (1971) Knowledge and Human Interests. Beacon Press,...
  • Harriss, J. and De Renzio, P. (1997) “Missing link” or analytically missing?: The concept of social capital: An...
  • Hindess, B. and Hirst, P. (1975) Precapitalist Modes of Production. Routledge and Kegan Paul,...
  • Hinojosa, L. (1998) Personal Communication. Cusco,...
  • Hyden, G. (1997) Civil society, social capital and development: Dissection of a complex discourse. Studies in...
  • IDB (1996) Bolivia: desarrollo diferente para un pais de cambios. Salir del circulo vicioso de la riqueza...
  • Jokisch, B. (1998) Ecuadorian emigration and agricultural change: The persistence of small-holder agriculture in Lower...
  • Katz, E. (forthcoming) Social capital and natural capital: A comparative analysis of land tenure and natural resource...
  • Kay, C. (1997) Globalization, peasant agriculture and reconversión. Bulletin for Latin American Research 16(1),...
  • Kay, C. (1995) Rural development and agrarian issues in contemporary Latin America. In Structural Adjustment and the...
  • Kleymeyer, C., ed. (1993) Cultural Expression and Grassroots Development: cases from Latin America and the Caribbean....
  • Cited by (1362)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text