Decision Aiding
Incorporating wealth information into a multiple criteria decision making model

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(02)00468-XGet rights and content

Abstract

We describe how a multiple criteria decision making (MCDM) modelling framework can be extended to account for one of the behavioral ramifications of a decision making activity, namely, the decision maker’s (DM’s) perception of his/her current wealth status, referred to as decisional wealth. Within the MCDM framework, decisional wealth reflects the relative achievements of each of the objectives in a given efficient solution. It is our argument that a DM’s preferences and the importance of his/her objectives, vary depending on the decisional wealth. Therefore, we use the wealth information and trade-off analysis to guide the search for preferred outcomes. We identify efficient solutions that satisfy a DM’s wealth-dependent preferences, and we illustrate the proposed modelling framework with an example.

Introduction

The purpose of this paper is to present a methodological framework that incorporates information about the relative wealth of a decision maker (DM) into a multiple criteria decision making (MCDM) model, and guides the DM in the decision making process by considering his/her wealth-dependent attitudes. The issues we consider can be illustrated with the following example. Imagine a person who has spent an afternoon at the race track and has already lost $140. Would such a person bet $10 on a 15:1 long shot in the last race? There may be two ways to frame this decision. One may view the status quo as the reference point, and frame the outcomes as a chance to further increase a loss to $150. Thus, one may not be willing to take the bet. On the other hand, one may view the present state as a loss of $140 for the betting day, and frame the last bet as a chance to recover it and return to the starting point. The latter frame produces more willingness to take the bet (Tversky and Kahneman, 1981).

This example illustrates how the framing of outcomes changes depending on the current perception of the reference points. It shows that the outcomes of a decision can be perceived either as gains or losses relative to the status quo, or as asset positions incorporating initial wealth.

Kahneman and Tversky (1983) argue that prior outcomes can influence the reference points, and a change of reference point alters the framing of the decisions and the preferences of the DM.

Thaler and Johnson (1990) investigate the influences of prior outcomes (gains or losses) on the choices of the DM. They argue that prior losses can increase the DM’s willingness to accept outcomes that offer the opportunity to break-even. Viewing the last race in the context of earlier losses is an example of such a situation. Similarly, the evidence supports an observation that bets on long shots are more popular on the last race of the day (Tversky and Kahneman, 1981).

In this paper we attempt to model a situation where the DM’s choices depend on the wealth of a DM that is reflected by the outcomes associated with a current decision (and that it can be measured through the values of the objective functions in the MCDM model). Such a wealth status clearly has an impact on the DM’s perception of gains and losses and his/her framing of a reference point. Following the recommendations of behavioral research, such information should be incorporated into the MCDM framework where the search for a preferred outcome is conducted in an interactive manner (see Steuer, 1986 for information about interactive MCDM approaches). We propose to frame the search process within the MCDM model in terms of the achieved wealth (level of the objective functions) relative to the maximum attainable wealth (ideal values). This helps us to capture changes in the DM’s preferences depending on the currently achieved outcomes. We propose to measure the DM’s wealth with a new index, which we call decisional wealth index. This index captures the relative wealth position of a DM in terms of the current levels of outcomes, and it is used as a proxy measure for the DM’s choice attitudes. There were attempts to describe efficient solutions of the MCDM models with additional measures (see Xanthopulos et al., 2000), but they were not used in a proactive way to guide the DM’s decision making process and generate potentially better solutions that reflect the wealth-dependent preferences of the DM.

As argued by Vincke et al. (1992), the MCDM models should provide support to the DM and aim at guiding his/her search for improved outcomes. Despite the obvious implications of the decisional wealth on the DM’s search attitude, to our knowledge there are no methodological approaches that incorporate this behavioral notion into an MCDM modelling framework.

The organization of the paper is as follows: In Section 2, we provide a background for our study. In Section 3, we define the MCDM problem addressed in this paper, and define the notions of decisional wealth and trade-offs. In Section 4, we illustrate how the notion of decisional wealth should be incorporated into an MCDM framework. In Section 5, we give the theoretical foundations of the proposed framework. The paper concludes with a discussion.

Section snippets

Background

Decision problems considered in the MCDM literature have their foundations in the classical economic analysis of choice operationalized by Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944). According to such considerations, a DM is perceived as a pure utility maximizer who makes choices that maximize an explicitly unknown but implicitly assumed utility function. This is a prevailing assumption in the MCDM literature despite behavioral evidence that utility maximization is not always a guiding force of the

Problem definition and basic notions

In this section, we define the MCDM problem, the decisional wealth and the trade-offs. We also describe how we capture the DM’s wealth-dependent preferences using the concept of decisional wealth and trade-off information.

The framework

The proposed framework incorporating decisional wealth and the DM’s wealth-dependent preferences in the MCDM models can be summarized as follows.

The DM’s preferences and the importance of his/her objectives vary depending on the decisional wealth (i.e., the DM’s willingness to improve values of the objectives may decrease whenever their wealth indices exceed certain threshold). Thus, for each current outcome, the decisional wealth indices of the objectives are calculated to determine the

Theoretical foundations

This section gives the necessary theory behind the proposed modeling framework.

Conclusion

As originated in prospect theory, the DM’s preferences can change depending on his/her current wealth. In MCDM models wealth might be reflected by the current values of the objective functions. In this paper, we incorporate this behavioral observation into an MCDM model by using a wealth index, trade-off bounds and a new notion of joint global trade-offs. We present a new framework that relaxes the strict assumption about the convexity/concavity of the DM’s utility function, and thus we allow

Acknowledgements

Research presented in this paper was supported by grant from the NATO Science Fellowship Programme of the Scientific and Technical Research Council of Turkey (TÜBİTAK) and the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada. The paper was written when the first author was visiting University of Ottawa. The authors would like to thank the editor and reviewers and Dr. Ignacy Kaliszewski for their comments on an earlier draft of the paper and Ms. Anne Burgess for editorial assistance.

References (24)

  • I. Kaliszewski

    Using trade-off information in decision-making algorithms

    Computers and Operations Research

    (2000)
  • P. Korhonen et al.

    A visual interactive method for solving the multiple criteria problem

    European Journal of Operational Research

    (1986)
  • M. Allais

    The general theory of random choices in relation to the invariant cardinal utility function and the specific probability function

  • D. Ellsberg

    Risk, ambiguity and the savage axioms

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1961)
  • D. Kahneman et al.

    Choices, values, and frames

    American Psychologist

    (1983)
  • D. Kahneman et al.

    Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk

  • I. Kaliszewski

    Calculating trade-offs by two-step parametric programming

    Central European Journal of Operational Research and Economics

    (1993)
  • I. Kaliszewski

    Quantitative Pareto Analysis by Cone Separation Technique

    (1994)
  • I. Kaliszewski et al.

    Generation of outcomes with selectively bounded trade-offs

    Foundations of Computing and Decision Sciences

    (1995)
  • I. Kaliszewski et al.

    Efficient solutions and bounds on global trade-offs

    Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications

    (1997)
  • P. Korhonen et al.

    Choice behavior in interactive multiple criteria decision making

    Annals of Operations Research

    (1990)
  • Cited by (18)

    • A coradiant based scalarization to characterize approximate solutions of vector optimization problems with variable ordering structures

      2017, Operations Research Letters
      Citation Excerpt :

      By using a nonlinear separation theorem for two cones, Kasimbeyli introduced the conic scalarization method to characterize efficient elements of problem (1) [15,16]. In this scalarization, boundedness and convexity conditions are not required, while in most scalarization methods these conditions are essential (see e.g. [5,14,18,17,22]). By using nonlinear scalarization functionals, Eichfelder presented a complete characterization of nondominated and minimal elements in variable ordering structures [6,7].

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text