Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 65, Issue 2, 1 April 2008, Pages 253-261
Ecological Economics

METHODS
Environmental policy in the European Union: Fostering the development of pollution havens?

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.12.018Get rights and content

Abstract

A pollution haven occurs when dirty industries from developed nations relocate to developing nations in order to avoid strict environmental standards or developed nations imports of dirty industries expand replacing domestic production. The purpose of this study is to determine whether the European Union (EU) has increased its imports of “dirty” goods from poorer, less democratic countries during a period of more stringent environmental standards. Previous empirical studies such as those by Levinson and Taylor [Levinson, A., and Taylor, M.S., in press. Unmasking the Pollution Haven Effect. International Economic Review.], Ederington, Levinson and Minier [Ederington, J., Levinson, A., and Minier, J., 2005. Footloose and Pollution-Free. Review of Economics and Statistics., 87: 92–99.], Kahn and Yoshino (2004), and Ederington and Minier [Ederington, J., and Minier. J., 2003. Is Environmental Policy a Secondary Trade Barrier? An Empirical Analysis. Canadian Journal of Economics., 36: 137–54.] find evidence that United States imports are responsive to changes in environmental stringency, but the effects of EU policy have not been examined as thoroughly. Our study follows Kahn [Kahn, M.E., 2003. The Geography of Us Pollution Intensive Trade: Evidence from 1958 to 1994. Regional Science and Urban Economics., 33: 383–400.] and examines the impact of industry energy intensity and toxicity, measured by an energy index and a Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) index, on imports into the EU, at the 2-digit industry level from 1970 to 1999. We use the signing of the Maastricht Treaty to signify a period of more uniform and stringent community wide environmental standards (1993–1999), and identify the level of per capita GDP within an EU trading partner. We find an increased amount of EU energy intensive trade with poorer countries during the period with more stringent EU environmental standards. This result is not robust, however, when poorer countries are defined by OECD membership and geographic region. We do not find an increased amount of EU toxic intensive trade with poorer countries although there is some evidence of increased EU imports of toxic goods from poorer OECD and non-EU European countries. For our full sample of trading partners in all regions, the evidence supports the PHH for EU energy intensive trade, but not for toxic intensive trade. Results for regional trade analysis are less clear.

Section snippets

Pollution havens

The 1990s was a decade in which environmental standards were tightened throughout the developed world. This rise in environmental stringency has led to a discussion about the pollution haven hypothesis (PHH). The PHH proposes that environmental stringency differences between developed and developing countries, encourages developing countries to specialize and gain a comparative advantage in the production of “dirty” goods. If the PHH holds, developed nations should observe a rise in imports of

New EU environmental policy implementation period

In 1957, six European States signed the Treaty of Rome and formed the European Economic Community (EC). The primary goal of the Treaty was to increase economic performance for member nations. No explicit provisions for environmental policies, environmental agencies, or environmental law were made (Jordan, 2005, p1). It was not until the late 1960s and 1970s when the U.S. Clean Air Act Amendments were passed, and Europe experienced a period of rising income and wages, that the EC became

EU trade

The purpose of this paper is to examine the PHH with respect to the EU. We start by defining the EU as the fifteen countries that joined by 1995, each country is included as part of the EU from the year that they join.7

Energy index and results for fossil fuel pollution havens

The first measure of industry dirtiness that we use is an energy intensity index similar to the one used by Kahn and Yoshino (2004), Eskeland and Harrison (2003), Kahn (2003), and Xing and Kolstad (2002). However, we use an index based on EU production. This index denotes those industries that are dirty in the sense that they use a lot of fossil fuels in the production process. Eskeland and Harrison (2003) and Kahn (2003) have shown that energy consumption may be used to proxy for pollution

Toxic index and results for toxic pollution havens

The second measure of industry pollution is the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) index17

Discussion and conclusion

The overall results vary depending on the definition of industry dirtiness. There is evidence that the EU imported an increased amount of energy intensive goods from poorer nations during a period of more stringent environmental standards. This result is not consistent when we break down trading partners by membership in the OECD and regional definition. Apparently low income countries all together are driving the pollution haven effect, but that this is not a regional effect.

The results are

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Per Fredriksson, John List, Jenny Minier, anonymous reviewers, and participants at the 2004 Association of Environmental and Resource Economists/Southern Economic Association meetings for their helpful comments and advice. The authors alone, however, are responsible for the views in this paper.

References (39)

  • EderingtonJ. et al.

    Footloose and pollution-free

    Review of Economics and Statistics

    (2005)
  • EderingtonJ. et al.

    Trade liberalization and pollution havens

    Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy

    (2004)
  • EderingtonJ. et al.

    Is environmental policy a secondary trade barrier? An empirical analysis

    Canadian Journal of Economics

    (2003)
  • Energy Information Administration (Eia)

    Crude Oil Domestic First Purchase Prices, 1949–2002

    (2002)
  • Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)

    Toxic Release Inventory

    (2007)
  • HavemanJ.

    Industry Concordances

    (2005)
  • HestonA. et al.

    Penn World Tables Version 6.1. Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP)

    (2002)
  • Industrial Pollution Projection System (Ipps)

    World Bank

    (2004)
  • International Energy Agency (Iea)

    OECD Energy Balances Tables

    (2004)
  • Cited by (55)

    • Trading-off between being contaminated or stimulated: Are emerging countries doing good jobs in hosting foreign resources?

      2022, Journal of Cleaner Production
      Citation Excerpt :

      FDI and environment degradation nexus is an inverted U-shape hypothesis, which are divided into two sides of pollution halo hypothesis and pollution haven hypothesis. The ”Pollution Haven” hypothesis explained that developed countries often implement strict environmental benchmarks, which partially push the costs of production, management and technology innovation to minimize the emission output (Acharyya, 2009; Cave and Blomquist, 2008; He, 2006). To maximize profits, multinational firms in heavily polluting industries will shift operations or parts of their operations to subsidiaries in developing countries with less stringent environmental regulations.

    • An empirical investigation of the balance of embodied emission in trade: Industry structure and emission abatement

      2020, Economic Modelling
      Citation Excerpt :

      Section 5 provides the empirical evidence and the last section concludes. The empirical studies in the literature on international trade and the environment can be categorized into three different approaches: (1)studies investigating the effect of international trade on pollution emission from domestic production (Grossman and Krueger, 1993; Antweiler et al., 2001; Cole and Elliot, 2003; Frankel and Rose, 2005; Managi et al., 2009; Roy, 2017; Shahbaz et al., 2017; Kim et al., 2019), (2)studies investigating the effect of environmental regulations on international trade of dirty industries (Tobey, 1990; Ederington et al., 2004, 2005; Cave and Blomquist, 2008; Levinson and Taylor, 2008; Cole et al., 2010; Tsurumi et al., 2015), and (3)studies measuring the pollution emission embedded in international trade (Muradian et al., 2002; Ederington et al., 2004; Pan et al., 2008; Peters and Herwich, 2006; Levinson, 2009; Peters et al., 2011; Douglas and Nishioka, 2012; Grether and Mathys, 2013; He and Fu, 2014; Xu and Dietzenbacher, 2014; Duan and Jiang, 2017; Liddle, 2018; Honma and Yoshida, 2019). The BEET including this study is most closely related to the last approach.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    Tel.: +859 257 3924; fax: +859 323 1920.

    View full text