Business fluctuations in Italy, 1861–1913: The new evidence

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2006.06.001Get rights and content

Abstract

Band-pass filters and structural time-series models are applied to the new estimates of Italy’s domestic product from 1861 to 1913. These indicate a strong four-year cycle, derived from the agricultural sector, which curiously (and perhaps spuriously) vanishes after 30 years. Over the longer term GDP and the services reflect the long swing in industrial production, tied to the investment cycle. Agriculture seems marked instead by a further cycle of some 12–15 years, and also by a long wave related to the sector’s terms of trade.

Introduction

Italy’s national historical accounts were reconstructed just over a half-century ago by Istat (the Istituto Centrale di Statistica) and Ornello Vitali (the statistician of the “Ancona Group” organized by Giorgio Fuà). The Istat–Vitali estimates for the decades between Unification (1861) and World War I have long been considered seriously distorted; preliminary alternative estimates that combine Giovanni Federico’s constant-price value added series for agriculture and the corresponding Fenoaltea series for industry and the services point to higher and above all much steadier long-term growth.1 This paper examines business fluctuations in post-Unification Italy in the light of these new estimates. Section 2 considers the short-term business cycle, and Section 3 the longer-term fluctuations in GDP; a brief conclusion summarizes the main empirical results, and the research agenda to which they point.

The business cycle in the new GDP series is identified through alternative standard decompositions; these yield very similar results, which are correspondingly robust. Post-Unification Italy was largely agricultural, and the short-term cycle in GDP derived overwhelmingly from the movements of agricultural production. The estimated cyclical deviations were unusually moderate over the quarter-century before the war; but this comparative stability is not clearly confirmed by the available historical data, and it may be a statistical artifact.

Over the longer term trend growth appears to have been above average in the 1880s, and even more so after the turn of the century; alternative decompositions again yield very similar results, and these fluctuations too appear to be robustly identified. The agricultural series displays a further cycle of some 12–15 years, and an even longer fluctuation apparently related to the sector’s terms of trade; but these movements are relatively mild. The estimated fluctuations of the services sector are even milder, and the major longer-term movements in GDP paralleled those in industrial output. The statistically significant turn-of-the-century acceleration of GDP growth is tied to the rising industrial production of durables; it appears to reflect a sustained upswing in the investment cycle induced by the varying supply of foreign capital, rather than a break in the deep structure of the economy.

Section snippets

The business cycle over time

The new GDP series is illustrated in Fig. 1a.

The trends over time

In much of the current literature “the business cycle” is in a predetermined, relatively high-frequency range, and the “local,” “flexible” trend absorbs a good deal of the original series’ low-frequency variation (e.g., Zarnowitz and Ozyildirim, 2002). The older literature defined the “trend” as a very low-order polynomial, that could not snake around; and it spoke not of “the” business cycle but of Juglars and Kitchins, Kuznets and Kondratieffs, Dungeons and Dragons. Its richness was there,

Conclusions

Italy’s national historical accounts have recently been revised, and the new series are substantially different from the old.

The decomposition of these series’ fluctuations suggests that the (high-frequency) “business cycle” was essentially agricultural. A clear four-to-five-year cycle is evident until about 1890; after that date the short-term variability of agricultural production, and of GDP, is sharply lower than before. This “passing of the business cycle” is only weakly confirmed by the

References (34)

  • D.A. Andrews

    Test for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point: a corrigendum

    Econometrica

    (2003)
  • C. Bardini et al.

    The national accounts for Italy, Spain and Portugal

    Scandinavian Economic History Review

    (1995)
  • M. Baxter et al.

    Measuring business cycles: approximate band-pass filters for economic time series

    Review of Economics and Statistics

    (1999)
  • Bonelli, F., 1978. Il capitalismo italiano. Linee generali di interpretazione. In: Romano, R., Vivanti, C. (Eds.),...
  • L. Cafagna

    Protoindustria o transizione in bilico? (A proposito della prima onda dell’industrializzazione italiana)

    Quaderni storici

    (1983)
  • L. Cafagna

    La formazione del sistema industriale: ricerche empiriche e modelli di crescita

    Quaderni della Fondazione G.G. Feltrinelli

    (1983)
  • Christiano, L.J., Fitzgerald, T.J. 1999. The band pass filter. NBER Working Paper No....
  • L.J. Christiano et al.

    The band pass filter

    International Economic Review

    (2003)
  • N.F.R. Crafts et al.

    Modelling trends in economic history

    The Statistician

    (1996)
  • D. Delli Gatti et al.

    On the nature and causes of business fluctutations in Italy, 1861–2000

    Explorations in Economic History

    (2005)
  • Dirstat (Direzione generale della statistica), 1915. Annuario statistico italiano 1914. Bertero,...
  • Federico, G., 2000. Una stima del valore aggiunto dell’agricoltura italiana. In: Rey, G.M. (Ed.), I conti economici...
  • G. Federico

    Le nuove stime della produzione agricola italiana, 1860–1910: primi risultati e implicazioni

    Rivista di storia economica

    (2003)
  • G. Federico

    The growth of world agricultural production, 1800–1938

    Research in Economic History

    (2004)
  • S. Fenoaltea

    Italy

  • S. Fenoaltea

    International resource flows and construction movements in the Atlantic economy: the Kuznets cycle in Italy, 1861–1913

    Journal of Economic History

    (1988)
  • S. Fenoaltea

    Notes on the rate of industrial growth in Italy, 1861–1913

    Journal of Economic History

    (2003)
  • Cited by (19)

    • The changing relationship between inflation and the economic cycle in Italy: 1861-2012

      2015, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      Given that the output gap is measured as a principal component, it is a zero-mean and a unit-standard deviation variable. If we agree with Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea (2007), to define as “strong” a cyclical peak or trough during which the output gap is greater than one time its standard error in absolute value, all of the results in Table 3 suggest that, in the occurrence of a strong peak/trough, inflation is subject to an acceleration/deceleration in the 1–2 percentage points range. The exploration of the trade-off between inflation and the economic cycle in Italy since its unification (i.e., over a span of 150 years) shows that the macroeconomic history can be disentangled in two broad periods (before and after 1913).

    • Exports, imports and growth. New evidence on Italy: 1863-2004

      2012, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      The new GDP series incorporated Federico (2003) series for agriculture, Fenoaltea (2003) series for industry, and a newly derived series for services that extrapolate the Bank of Italy estimates of their value added in 1911 (Rey, 2000). This new Fenoaltea series is now considered as the more accurate estimate of Italy's annual GDP for the years from Unification to the eve of the First World War and has been used in some recent empirical works (Ciccarelli and Fenoaltea, 2007; Federico and Vasta, 2010). We also use it in this paper.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    Helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper were received from Brian A’Hearn, Fabio Busetti, Tommaso Proietti, Robert Waldmann, participants at seminars at Tor Vergata and the Bank of Italy, and an anonymous referee. The usual disclaimer applies.

    View full text