Elsevier

Energy

Volume 69, 1 May 2014, Pages 345-356
Energy

Optimal carbon taxes in carbon-constrained China: A logistic-induced energy economic hybrid model

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2014.03.022Get rights and content

Highlights

  • We establish a logistic-induced energy economic hybrid model of China.

  • We propose four carbon-constrained cases based on typical carbon allocation plans.

  • The optimal carbon tax in China is monotonically increasing and S-shaped.

  • It may take at least 30 years to promote the development of new technologies.

  • China is fully capable of achieving the voluntary goal of reducing carbon intensity.

Abstract

Carbon tax is an effective option for internalizing climate change and correcting market failure, an optimal set of carbon taxes can result in superior carbon mitigation. Then what is the optimal trajectory of carbon tax under various carbon-constrained scenarios, and what are the impacts of carbon controls on the economy and performance of carbon-free technologies are important questions to be addressed. We construct an energy–economy–environment aggregated model of China, combining top–down and bottom–up modeling and introducing revised logistic curves for enriching technical details. We also propose four carbon-constrained scenarios based on representative international carbon allocation plans. Our analysis shows that the optimal carbon tax in China is a monotonically increasing one, following a classical, S-shaped pattern. Carbon space constraints play an important role in promoting development of carbon-free technologies, while the substantial transition from fossil fuels to non-carbon energy would not happen before 2040, making clear that it will take at least 30 years to promote the development of carbon-free technologies. However, present energy-saving and efficiency-improving measures ensure that China is capable of achieving the voluntary goal of reducing carbon intensity in 2020 by 40–45% of what they were in 2005; nevertheless, introducing some carbon controls is necessary to fulfill the task of carbon emissions reduction in the Chinese Twelfth Five-Year Plan.

Introduction

The issue of climate change has gained considerable attention in both academia and politics in the past few years for its complex causes, widespread and uncertain consequences, and the global cooperation required to control carbon emissions. The difficultly in dealing with the problem lies in how to appropriately address the environmental externalities it brings about. The existence of negative environmental externalities makes market prices of fossil energy unable to reflect the full social cost of climate change, and therefore leads to market failure. Hence, how to internalize climate damage into market prices is the root of curbing CO2 emission, and even of addressing the problem of global climate change.

Carbon tax (or other equivalent measures) is an effective option for internalizing climate change and correcting market failure. An optimal set of carbon taxes can result in superior carbon mitigation. First, by taking into account climate damage, the prices of carbon-intensive goods, especially energy goods, will rise, which gives individual consumers the incentive to reduce energy use and increase the consumption of less-carbon-intensive goods. Second, the relative prices of new energy technologies will be lower when carbon tax is levied on the conventional ones, and this may enhance the market competitiveness of new technologies. Furthermore, revenues from a carbon tax could be used not only to finance cuts in ordinary income taxes, thereby helping to avert inefficiencies brought about by disincentives to work, but also to subsidize R&D activities for carbon-free technologies and accelerate their substitution to carbon-based energy [1]. Finally, as compared to fuel-efficiency standards, direct caps, or other carbon-management measures, a carbon tax is more flexible and dynamic in response to new information, and it is a potentially cost-effective option for reducing CO2 emissions [2], [3].1

Currently, carbon tax policies or equivalent measures have been implemented in several countries, notably European countries, despite EU Emission Trading Scheme which covers most of the EU countries, such as France, Denmark, Norway, and Switzerland have launched carbon tax policies in their domestic market, so as to enhance their measures in control CO2 emissions [4]. In addition, in recent years, attempts have been made in some Asian countries to introduce carbon taxes for fossil energy use. For example, in order to achieve the domestic voluntary target of cutting CO2 emissions in 2020 by 25% from what they were in 2005, India has levied a tax on coal from both domestic production and import since July 1, 2010, with a rate of 50 rupees per ton of carbon (11.07 USD (US dollar) per ton of carbon). The Australian government has also taxed fossil energy since July 1, 2012. The initial tax level is 23 AUD per ton of CO2 (around 6.3 USD per ton of carbon), with a growth rate of 5% per year, and the revenues from the carbon tax will be used to reduce income taxes, increase pensions and welfare payments, and compensate industries that suffer from implementation of carbon tax policy. In addition, China and South Korea have also put carbon taxes on their agendas, and policies might be implemented to reduce CO2 emissions in the near future [5].

It may be important for China to introduce carbon tax (or equivalent measures) to control its greenhouse gas emission. On one hand, China has already announced its carbon intensity reduction target, i.e., 17% reduction in 2015 compared to that of 2010,2 and 40–45% reduction in 2020 compared to that of 2005.3 As the economy still grows rapidly in China, the government realizes that it may not be easy to achieve such targets if only traditional command and control measures are used (e.g., the measures for energy-efficiency improvement target during the Eleventh Five-Year Plan). The introducing of market-based emission reduction measures (carbon tax) can help the policy makers to promote the emission reduction to a greater extent. On the other hand, the 2 °C target requires us to control the atmospheric carbon concentration within 450 or 400 ppmv, and this emission-constrained task needs to be decomposed to each country. For China, there is a huge gap between emission space constraints and our current carbon intensity reduction targets. If we take a review of existing allocation plans of CO2 emission space [6], [7], [8], [9], nearly all of these plans are requiring China to cut off its domestic CO2 emissions substantially before 2050. If China has to face CO2 emission space constraint, the policy makers may have no choices but to internalize climate damage and introduce market-based emission reduction measures. Also the policy makers need to decide when and how to reduce the CO2 emissions among different periods. Therefore, carbon tax is more flexible and dynamic in response to new information; it can also be used as an emission regulatory tool for policy makers to achieve the long-term emission control target effectively. In addition, carbon tax takes an important impact on conventional energy system design, and it is also a benefit to advanced systems utilization [10], [11], [12].

In this paper, we first try to explore the optimal trajectory of carbon tax to restrain carbon use in China, as well as its level change under different stringency of carbon control targets. Theoretically, the optimal carbon tax should be equal to the marginal climate damage associated with CO2 emissions; however, climate damage is difficult to measure, and a carbon tax, therefore, is less than optimal [13], [14], [15]. Given the specific carbon reduction targets in the future, there is a lot of controversy about the trajectories of the optimal carbon tax along time period (monotonically increasing, steadily decreasing, U-shaped, or hump-shaped) among scholars. Dasgupta and Heal [16] argue that a carbon tax policy with fixed rates plays little role in mitigating the consumption of fossil fuels, and thereby reducing CO2 emissions, no matter how high the tax rate is. Sinclair [17] concludes that the carbon tax rate of ad valorem will keep monotonically declining in the steady-state. While Ulph and Ulph [18] hold the opposite view, arguing that Sinclair's conclusion is not generally true and the carbon tax may rise and then fall (i.e., the so-called hump-shape) under some circumstances. Hoel and Kverndokk [19] come to a similar conclusion as Ulph and Ulph [18]. In addition, Farzin and Tahvonen [20] believe that the optimal carbon tax may also be monotonically increasing or follow a U-shaped pattern, and van der Zwaan et al. [15] and Bosetti et al. [21] also make this point in their research. It is, therefore, important to determine the optimal carbon tax in the context of constrained carbon emission space.

The second question that we attempt to address is how to evaluate the impacts of various carbon control targets on China's economy, consumption, and energy demand, as well as the performances of carbon-free technologies. Despite a substantial literature studying the influences of carbon tax policy in China, the majority of studies are based on static or dynamic computable equilibrium (CGE) models and econometric approaches [22], [23], [24], [25], [26], and carbon taxes in most of these studies are exogenous. However, the social-economic impacts resulted from exogenous carbon taxes in previous studies may be insufficient to support the policy makers to make effective carbon tax policies in the long run.

To address these questions, we first build a regional energy–economy–environment aggregated model with a more detailed energy technical sector and an emissions-control and management sector, as compared to the previous methodology framework of CGE and econometric models. Second, the carbon tax is solving endogenously in our model. The model takes carbon tax as an unknown variable and solved by optimizing the objective function. Meanwhile, it allows us to explore China's optimal carbon tax trajectory in the proposed four carbon-constrained scenarios, which based on representative international carbon space allocation plans. Also the model can investigate the impacts of various carbon control targets on China's economy, consumption, and energy demand, as well as the performances of carbon-free technologies.

Although our model is still type of top-down model, we employ the revised logistic sub-model to enrich the technical detail of the energy module, which brings us more bottom-up features. In general, top-down, endogenous technological models are popular options to assess environmental damage and simulate climate policy. These models are based on neoclassical economic theory and the Ramsey saving principle, and they assume that central planners have perfect foresight and that their lifes are infinite, hence, such types of model are usually referred to as Infinitely Lived Agent (ILA) model [13], [27], [28], [29], [30], [31]. Conventional constant elasticity substitution (CES) function method is often used in these top-down ILA models to describe the competitive relationships between fossil and non-fossil technologies, while this method may be incapable of considering multiple new carbon-free technologies, and may cause too much uncertainties resulting from sensitive substitution elasticity. The revised logistic model is a suitable option to make up this gap; furthermore, it allows us to introduce policy variables, such as carbon taxes and subsidies, to the energy module, which brings convenience for us to study the impacts of climate policies on economy as well as technological diffusion.

Section snippets

Overview of CE3METL model

The model we establish in this paper is called the CE3METL model (Chinese Energy–Economy–Environment (E3) Model with Endogenous Technological change by employing Logistic curves). It is an optimal-growth tech-economic hybrid model, following the neoclassical theory and Ramsey principle [32]. This model is essentially based on the framework of the top-down macroeconomic ones, meanwhile we introduce revised logistic curves which considered multiple energy technologies and enriches the model's

Data processing and parameter calibration

CE3METL is a one-sector, inter-temporal, dynamic optimization model, and its running and numerical simulation relies heavily on the initial values of the key macroeconomic and technical variables which are presented in Tables 1and 2. The year of 2010 is chosen as the starting year of our model, the initial GDP, investment, consumption, import, and export are all based on the data in 2010, and lower bound for export, upper bound for import are estimated in terms of the historical data from 2000

BAU scenario

In the BAU case, the GDP of China will grow from 5.93 trillion USD in 2010 to 12.83 trillion USD in 2020, with a cumulative increase of 116%, and to 38.94 trillion USD in 2050. The GDP growth rate on average during the entire horizon (2010–2050) is 4.82%, versus 8.02% over the next decade (2010–2020). The average growth rate of primary energy demand over the horizon projection will be 3.59%, with its amount increasing from 7.34 Mega-Joule (MJ) in 2010 to about30.06 MJ in 2050. There is no peak

Sensitivity analysis to key parameters

In this section, we perform sensitivity analysis of the main simulation results to some key economic and technical parameters, such as depreciation rate (δ), substitution elasticity between capital–labor and energy (σ), automatic energy-efficiency improvement (AEEI), learning rate (lr), and substitution parameters in the logistic model (ai). A lower value, basis value, and upper value are chose for each parameter to finish the robustness analysis of the BAU case and a carbon constraint scenario

Conclusions

This study has three focuses. The first is that we build an E3 aggregated model (CE3METL) and introduce the revised logistic sub-model to the technical module. This allows the energy sector to be subdivided into multiple energy technologies and enables us to investigate the substitution relationships between carbon-based energy and non-fossil technologies. It is also feasible to introduce environmental policy variables, such as carbon taxes and subsidies, and then study the optimal trajectory

Acknowledgement

Financial support from the Chinese Academy of Sciences (No. XDA05150700) and the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71133005, 71273253, and 71210005) is acknowledged. The authors deeply acknowledge the weekly seminars at CEEP in CAS, from where the earlier draft of the paper got improved.

References (52)

  • F. Gracceva et al.

    Exploring the uncertainty around potential shale gas development-a global energy system analysis based on TIAM

    Energy

    (2013)
  • G. Kumbaroglu et al.

    CO2, GDP and RET: an aggregate economic equilibrium analysis for Turkey

    Energy Policy

    (2008)
  • D. Popp

    ENTICE: endogenous technological change in the DICE model of global warming

    J Environ Econ Manag

    (2004)
  • E.S. Rubin et al.

    Learning curves for environmental technology and their importance for climate policy analysis

    Energy

    (2004)
  • A. McDonald et al.

    Learning rates for energy technologies

    Energy Policy

    (2001)
  • H.B. Duan et al.

    What’s the most cost-effective policy of CO2 targeted reduction: an application of aggregated economic technological model with CCS?

    Appl Energy

    (2013)
  • N. Cantore et al.

    Equality and CO2 emissions distribution in climate change integrated assessment modeling

    Energy

    (2010)
  • S.H. Schneider et al.

    Achieving low-cost emissions targets

    Nature

    (1997)
  • H. Gerbelová et al.

    Potential of CO2 taxes as a policy measure towards low-carbon Portuguese electricity sector by 2050

    Energy

    (2014)
  • Fischer C, Newell R. Environmental and technology policies for climate change and renewable energy. Resources for the...
  • M.S. Anderson et al.

    Carbon-energy taxation: lessons from Europe

    (2009)
  • China ministries propose carbon tax from 2012

    Reuters Alibaba News

    (May 2010)
  • J.Y. Fang et al.

    Scenario analysis on the global carbon emission reduction goal proposed in the declaration of the 2009 G8 Summit

    Sci China

    (2009)
  • R. Garnaut

    The Garnaut climate change review

    (2008)
  • Human development report – fighting climate change: human solidarity in a divided world

    (2008)
  • Environmental outlook to 2030

    (2008)
  • Cited by (42)

    • Exploring the economic impacts of carbon tax in China using a dynamic computable general equilibrium model under a perspective of technological progress

      2023, Journal of Cleaner Production
      Citation Excerpt :

      Carbon tax policy may still play an essential role in China's future carbon emission reduction (Xiao et al., 2020). There is much carbon tax literature, ranging from the study of the economic impacts of carbon taxes (Liu and Lu, 2015; Zhou et al., 2018; Ojha et al., 2020; Li et al., 2020; Timilsina et al., 2021; Cao et al., 2021; Wang et al., 2022)to compare the carbon tax with other CO2 reduction mechanisms (Robert, 2019; Jia and Lin, 2020)to how to design the carbon tax policy (Duan et al., 2014; Presley and Lin, 2018; Shi et al., 2019; Xu, 2021; Sun et al., 2021; Malerba et al., 2021)to its double dividend effect (Fraser and Waschik, 2013; Presley and Lin, 2019). But, most of them find that the carbon tax would negatively impact the economy because they do not consider the technological progress caused by a carbon tax.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text