Elsevier

European Economic Review

Volume 55, Issue 8, December 2011, Pages 1046-1071
European Economic Review

Formation and persistence of oppositional identities

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2011.04.009Get rights and content

Abstract

We develop a dynamic model of identity formation that explains why ethnic minorities may choose to adopt oppositional identities (i.e. some individuals may reject or not the dominant culture) and why this behavior may persist over time. We first show that the prevalence of an oppositional culture in the minority group cannot always be sustained in equilibrium. Indeed, because the size of the majority group is larger, there is an “imposed” process of exposition to role models from the majority group that favors the diffusion of mainstream values in the minority community. In spite of this, an oppositional culture in the minority group can nevertheless be sustained in steady state if there is enough cultural segmentation in terms of role models, or if the size of the minority group is large enough, or if the degree of oppositional identity it implies is high enough. We also demonstrate that the higher the level of harassment and the number of racist individuals in the society, the more likely an oppositional minority culture will emerge. We finally show that ethnic identity and socialization effort can be more intense in mixed rather than segregated neighborhoods.

Introduction

In April 1992, when a mostly white jury acquitted four police officers accused in a videotaped of beating a black motorist, thousands of people in Los Angeles, mainly young black and Latino males, joined in what has often been characterized as a race riot. In the summer of 2001, ethnic riots occurred on the streets of towns and cities in the north of England (e.g. Oldham, Leeds, Burnley, Bradford), involving young British Asian men. More recently, in November 2005, riots emerged in Paris' suburbs, sparked by the accidental deaths of two Muslim teenagers, and then spread to 300 French towns and cities. Most of the rioters were the French-born children of immigrants from Arab and African countries.

These race and ethnic riots1 have all recently placed the issue of racial and ethnic identity at the forefront of political debate in the United States and in Europe. Identity is the result of an individual's choice, often the choice not to conform to the accepted norms but rather to different norms that characterize a social, ethnic, or religious group.2 Furthermore, ethnic identities can be “oppositional”, that is, they require the rejection of the accepted norms of the majority group (Ainsworth-Darnell and Downey, 1998). This is the case, for instance, of the so-called “ghetto culture” in the United States (Wilson, 1987). Also, studies in the US have found that African American students in poor areas may be ambivalent about learning standard English and performing well at school because this may be regarded as “acting white” (Delpit, 1995, Fordham and Ogbu, 1986, Ogbu, 1997, Austen-Smith and Fryer, 2005, Selod and Zenou, 2006, Battu et al., 2007, Fryer and Torelli, 2010).3

Oppositional identities often produce significant economic and social conflicts, as in the case of the ethnic and race riots cited above. But how intense are oppositional identities? Which economic and sociological factors mostly contribute to their formation? In particular, does neighborhood segregation induce intense and oppositional identities? In this paper we attempt to provide some answers to these questions.

A large literature in economics, sociology and anthropology, documents how ethnic traits are transmitted from parents to children and how ethnic identity is adopted (see, in particular, Akerlof and Kranton, 2000, Alba, 1990, Bernal and Knight, 1993, Boyd and Richerson, 1985, Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman, 1981, Phinney, 1990). In our reading of the evidence, parents directly make various socialization choices, e.g. the rules and beliefs the family conforms to and how much time they spend with their children. Parents also realize that socialization is partially the product of the social interaction their children engage into, which they affect by choosing which neighborhood to live in, the school children attend, their social circle of friends and acquaintances, the civic/social clubs and churches they belong to, etc. The role of parents in the socialization of their own children is nonetheless limited by the children's pro-active role in choosing who to imitate and learn from, thereby directly shaping their own cultural identity. An individual's general identity, in the words of Akerlof and Kranton (2000, p. 720), “is bound to social categories; and individuals identify with people in some categories and differentiate themselves from those in others.”

We model the formation of ethnic traits along these lines, that is, as a mechanism that interacts cultural transmission and socialization inside the family,4 peer effects and social interactions, and identity choice.

To be more precise, our model has three main components:

(i) Trait transmission from parent to child: In period t, the child adopts his parent's identity with some probability, which is a positive function of parental effort τi. Parent also chooses the intensity of their own identity αi. The parent's choice of τi is determined altruistically, but with “imperfect empathy” in that the parent evaluates the child's future well-being as if the child has picked up the same trait (oppositional or mainstream) as the parent himself.

(ii) Trait transmission from role model to child: In the absence of successful parental transmission, the child can adopt the trait of a randomly picked role model in the society at large. In this perspective, d represents the “segmentation” of society, which captures the populations from which a minority role model is chosen from. When d=1, the role model is drawn from society at large. When d=0 the role model is drawn only from the minority population.

(iii) Child's determination of the intensity of his trait, or his own identity: Last, the intensity with which the child identifies himself with his trait is chosen by the child, along with a “good” or “bad” action. These two choices are referred to as an “identity choice.” Choosing an identity of any kind is costly (denoted by C(αi)). But having a strong identity reduces psychological cost of interacting with others. The optimal choice of action is predetermined by assumption (mainstream individuals chooses the “good” action, oppositional ones chooses the “bad” action) but the optimal choice of intensity of identity will depend on Qi, the probability of interacting with someone of a different type, and Ii, the psychological cost of this interaction. As a result, Qi×Ii is the expected psychological cost of interacting with someone with a different value system.

We first show that the prevalence of an oppositional culture in the minority group (i.e. individuals who reject the mainstream values) can be sustained if and only if there is enough cultural segmentation in terms of role models, and/or the size of minority group is large enough, and/or the degree of oppositional identity it implies is high enough, and/or the socio-economic opportunity cost of the actions it prescribes is small enough. In this steady-state equilibrium, the socialization effort of oppositional parents is higher than that of the mainstream minority families. There is indeed an asymmetry between the two cultural traits, “mainstream” and “oppositional”. Since the majority group individuals are by definition mainstreams, there is an “imposed” process of exposition to role models from that group.5 This tends, quite naturally, to favor the diffusion of the mainstream values into the minority community. Given that, in order to have a long-run constant fraction of oppositional individuals, it has to be the case that their family socialization effort compensates for this asymmetric cultural bias. However, when the “imposed” socialization through the majority cultural model is strong enough, then there is no way for the oppositional culture to survive and there is, in that case, full assimilation of the minority group to the mainstream values.

We then show that it is possible (and we identify sufficient conditions on economic fundamentals) that ethnic identity and socialization efforts are more intense in mixed rather than in segregated neighborhoods. As a result, our analysis suggests that the effect of mixed neighborhood on identity formation and socialization might be quite complex and may generate in some cases perverse results. This is particularly so if mixed neighborhood are conducive of explicit acts of rejection on the part of the majority group.

The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we discuss the contribution of our paper with respect to the literature. In Section 3, we present the main model. Section 4 deals with the cultural equilibrium analysis and some comparative statics results. Section 5 is devoted to the justification of our assumptions and modeling choices. In Section 6, we introduce the possibility of harassment of the minority group. Section 7 considers the joint cultural evolution of both racist or intolerant majority preferences and oppositional minority culture. Finally, Section 8 concludes, provides some empirical evidence and discusses some policy issues.

Section snippets

Background and previous literature

Our model is linked to several literatures that we would like to discuss now.

The model

Suppose that the population is of fixed size N and composed of a majority group and a minority group. We denote by subscript b the minority group, whose size is Nb, and by subscript w the majority group, whose size is Nw (with Nb+Nw=N), to which some individuals from the minority group might want to assimilate, i.e. share the same preferences and values. The two groups can be differentiated by some external attribute, such as the skin color, hair, size, etc. which is exogenous to the

Steady-state equilibrium

The dynamics of cultural evolution from period t to period t+1 is described by the following equation:qm,t+1=qm,tPmm+(1qm,t)Pom=qm,t[τmt+(1τmt)rmt]+(1qm,t)(1τot)rmtwhere τit=τi(qm,t) is defined by (24) and rmt=rm(qm,t) by (20). The interpretation of this equation is straightforward. The proportion of mainstream minority individuals qm,t+1 at time t+1 is equal to all new-born minority children who become mainstream and whose parents were mainstream (qm,tPmm) plus all new-born minority

Justification of assumptions and modeling choices

Our model, like most models, is based on assumptions and modeling choices. It is relatively complex since we model three main aspects: (i) the parental investment in transmitting his own trait, (ii) the role of peers and neighborhood when this transmission fails, (iii) the choice of intensity of identity of children.

One could have, for example, developed a simpler model with no parental investment. Let us now argue what we believe that this last aspect is crucial for the result.

First, if there

Unconditional harassment

We would like now to extend the previous model to analyze the impact of racial harassment on the existence and evolution of an oppositional minority culture. Let us assume that, in the majority group, there are some individuals who are negatively affected when matched with a minority individual (it does not matter if this minority person is mainstream or oppositional). Because they feel a loss of identity Iγ when matched with a minority person, they are ready to take an harassment action Z in

Evolution of intolerance and oppositional cultures

So far, we assumed that the fraction of individuals with “racist preferences” in the majority group was exogenous. Still, sociologists have long argued that racial prejudices and discrimination in the dominant group tend to be endogenous and to increase with the size of the subordinate group (see, e.g. Blalock, 1956, Blalock, 1957, Blalock, 1967). For instance, using data from the Eurobarometer Survey on individual attitudes towards immigrants and racial minorities across 12 countries, Quillian

Our main results

By developing a dynamic model that interacts cultural transmission and socialization inside the family, peer effects and social interactions, and identity choice, we have found the following main results:

(i) The prevalence of an oppositional culture in the minority group can be sustained if and only if there is enough cultural segmentation in terms of role models (d small enough), and/or the size of minority group is large enough (qb large enough), and/or the degree of oppositional identity it

Acknowledgments

Thanks to Andrew Clark for the Morissey's quote. We are grateful to the editor, Eran Yashiv, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments.

References (89)

  • R.D. Alba

    Ethnic Identity: The Transformation of White America

    (1990)
  • G.A. Akerlof

    A theory of social custom of which unemployment may be one consequence

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1980)
  • G.A. Akerlof

    Social distance and social decisions

    Econometrica

    (1997)
  • G.A. Akerlof et al.

    Economics and identity

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2000)
  • G.A. Akerlof et al.

    Identity Economics: How Our Identities Shape Our Work, Wages, and Well-Being

    (2010)
  • A. Alesina et al.

    Ethnic diversity and economic performance

    Journal of Economic Literature

    (2005)
  • D. Austen-Smith et al.

    An economic analysis of ‘acting white’

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2005)
  • C. Ballester et al.

    Who's who in networks. Wanted: the key player

    Econometrica

    (2006)
  • H. Battu et al.

    Oppositional identities and the labor market

    Journal of Population Economics

    (2007)
  • R. Bénabou

    Workings of a city: location, education, and production

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1993)
  • R. Bénabou et al.

    Incentives and prosocial behavior

    American Economic Review

    (2006)
  • Bénabou, R., Tirole, J. Identity, morals and taboos: beliefs as assets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126 (2),...
  • M.E. Bernal et al.

    Ethnic Identity: Formation and Transmission among Hispanics and Other Minorities

    (1993)
  • B.D. Bernheim

    A theory of conformity

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1994)
  • A. Bisin et al.

    Beyond the melting pot: cultural transmission, marriage, and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2000)
  • A. Bisin et al.

    Religious intermarriage and socialization in the United States

    Journal of Political Economy

    (2004)
  • Bisin, A., Patacchini, E., Verdier, T., Zenou, Y., 2010. Bend it like Beckham: ethnic identity and integration. CEPR...
  • H. Blalock

    Economic discrimination and negro increase

    American Sociological Review

    (1956)
  • H. Blalock

    Percent mon-white and discrimination in the South

    American Sociological Review

    (1957)
  • H. Blalock

    Towards a Theory of Minority-Group Relations

    (1967)
  • L.D. Bobo

    Prejudice as a group position: microfoundations of a sociological approach to racism and racial relations

    Journal of Social Issues

    (1999)
  • R. Boyd et al.

    Culture and the Evolutionary Process

    (1985)
  • A.W. Boykin

    The triple quandary and the schooling of Afro American children

  • B.T. Bowyer

    The contextual determinants of white racial attitudes in England

    British Journal of Political Science

    (2009)
  • R. Brubaker

    The return of assimilation? Changing perspectives on immigration and its sequels in France, Germany, and the United States

    Ethnic and Racial Studies

    (2001)
  • L.L. Cavalli-Sforza et al.

    Cultural Transmission and Evolution

    (1981)
  • S. Currarini et al.

    An economic model of friendship: homophily, minorities, and segregation

    Econometrica

    (2009)
  • M. Davey et al.

    Parenting practices and the transmission of ethnic identity

    Journal of Marital and Family Therapy

    (2003)
  • J.B. Davis

    Personal identity and standard economic theory

    Journal of Economic Methodology

    (1995)
  • J.B. Davis

    The Theory of the Individual in Economics: Identity and Values

    (2003)
  • J.B. Davis

    Complex economic systems: using collective intentionality analysis to explain individual identity in networks

    Revue de Philosophie Economique

    (2004)
  • L. Delpit

    Other People's Children: Cultural Conflict in the Classroom

    (1995)
  • De Martí, J., Zenou, Y., 2010. Ethnic identity and social distance in friendship formation. Unpublished manuscript,...
  • D.H. Demo et al.

    Socialization and racial identity among black Americans

    Social Psychology Quarterly

    (1990)
  • Cited by (102)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text