Elsevier

Global Environmental Change

Volume 34, September 2015, Pages 172-184
Global Environmental Change

Managing the socio-ecology of very large rivers: Collective choice rules in IWRM narratives

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2015.06.012Get rights and content

Highlights

  • The integrated water resources management (IWRM) paradigm can be modified to include narratives at the meso-level.

  • These narratives can resolve or ameliorate tensions between different interests.

  • This study shows a possible typology of narratives of collective choice rules.

  • In the two cases studied (China and India), these include the economics of water use, gains from technology and normative incentives.

Abstract

Integrated water resources management (IWRM) has been lauded as an integrative and participatory form of governance. However, critics claim that actual implementation remains problematic, because of deep path dependencies and the entrenched interests. This paper investigates this claim by looking at the formation of collective choice rules in integrated water resources management reforms in China’s Yellow River and the Ganges in India. The two rivers provide a natural experiment—similarity in physical scale, complexity, and integrated water resources management reforms, but highly different in social and policy contexts. Using the Q methodology and Ostrom’s Institutional Analysis and Development (IAD) framework, we find that, despite differences in policy contexts, narratives amongst the stakeholders in the two rivers are surprisingly similar, including a continued role for a negotiated local approach, and the presence of normative incentives for collective action, underwritten by deep historical meanings of the rivers. These narratives in turn provide some explanation for the choice of collective rules in use. They suggest that a modified form of integrated water resources management, taking into account narratives and collective choice rules, is useful for the governance of very large rivers across different contexts.

Introduction

The management of very large trans-boundary rivers is a critical component of the ecological equation, as they host 40% of the world’s population (Jansky et al., 2004). The concept of Integrated Water Resources Management (IWRM) has emerged as a possible socio-ecological governance model (Cook and Bakker, 2012), involving physical, sectorial, and organizational integration (Kidd and Shaw, 2007). IWRM has practical as well as normative dimensions, relating to hard infrastructural integration such as at the basin level or catchment scale of a water body, as well as softer integration in management and governance including in laws, or management agreements that are formal decision-making structures in water allocation and management (Bressers and Kuks, 2004).

This broad normative appeal allowed IWRM to gain traction (Ohlson, 1999, Newson, 2000, Matondo, 2002, Global Water Partnership, 2007, UNEP, 2006)—from a management perspective, IWRM is expected to provide better adaptability against unforeseen conditions such as droughts or floods (e.g. Pahl-Wostl, 2007, UNEP, 2006, Watson, 2007, Mitchell, 2007); as a decision-making matrix, it devolves authority from national or federal governments to local governments, river basin organizations, and local water users (Kemper et al., 2007), allowing for multi-stakeholder participation and knowledge interests from different groups (Brunner and Steelman, 2005).

While elements of IWRM have been widely adopted in countries as diverse as America, Israel and Chile (Watson, 2007), and (although somewhat less well-recorded) in China (Zhang et al., 2010) and India (Janakarajan, 2006), IWRM has its share of detractors. Many attempts to implement IWRM have failed (Jonker, 2002, Jeffrey and Gearey, 2006, Pahl-Wostl and Jeffrey, 2007). In those cases where IWRM has been successfully implemented, the outcomes have fallen short of what its advocates have anticipated (Shah and Van Koppen, 2006, Medema and Jeffrey, 2005).

Current research on the failures of IWRM has focused on difficulties in implementation, especially the need to deal with complexity and uncertainty (Ohlson, 1999, Jeffrey and Gearey, 2006, Medema et al., 2008), along both the social and the physical dimensions. First, integration needs to take place across existing organizations and sections where there are already entrenched groups and interests (UNESCO and Green Cross International, 2003). Agreement on what a “collective interest” constitutes and how best to pursue this is difficult (Blomquist and Schlager, 2005). But such agreement is crucial to implementation. A second challenge stems from the physical integration of an IWRM system. Expansive scales and multiple physical dimensions can make it difficult for stakeholders to reach agreement (Van Cleve et al., 2006). As Barnett and O’Neill (2010, p. 212) point out, “a major issue with large infrastructural developments is the way they commit capital and institutions to trajectories that are difficult to change in the future”. This has variously been described as the problem of “sunk costs,” (Ingram and Fraser, 2006) or path dependencies. Complexity is also generated when the social and the physical interact—for example, environmental damage caused by over-exploitation, excessive pollution, and river engineering works (Brookes, 2002), integrating local livelihoods with ecology (fisheries and aquaculture), and taking into consideration the spiritual and cultural aspects of water, which might play a key role in influencing public sentiments (Rahaman and Varis, 2005).

Applying IWRM to the socio-ecology of rivers is therefore an attempt at a highly complex institutional change (Folke, 2006). In dealing with this complexity, scholars have argued for complements such as decentralised environmental management (Oates, 1998) or multi-level governance (Marks and Hooghe, 2004). More recently, the notion of adaptive water management and the need for social learning has been persuasively made by Pahl-Wostl et al. (2007) who argue that “sustainable management of water resources and the implementation of IWRM cannot be realized unless current water management regimes undergo a transition towards more adaptive water management.” Given that large riparian systems are too complex to be managed by high-level integrative plans, water management is a necessarily a political process and the implementation is to some extent experimentation.

But how do we reconcile the need for integration and decentralization? And how do we understand political realities of IWRM without resorting to idiosyncratic experimentation? This paper proposes that an investigation of meso-level rules about IWRM can provide some answers. Such an investigation also addresses an empirical gap in extant IWRM analyses, which have tended to focus either on fairly abstract, constitutional choice level (Blomquist and Schlager, 2005) or operational level rules (Fischhendler, 2008). Table 1 provides an illustrative list.

Our study is on the narratives in the Yellow River in China and Ganges in India, using Ostrom’s (1990) Institutional Analysis and Development (IAD) framework, a device for studying collective-choice rules amongst communities. This paper outlines our study in four parts. First, we outline the theoretical framework of socio-ecology and explain our use of the IAD, in particular the impact of “rules-in-use” on policy outcomes. Second, we provide a conceptual map of the two cases, showing the crisis that brought about the IWRM reforms. Third, we discuss the results of the Q-methodology in uncovering the key discourse coalitions and narratives of both rivers and show how they are similar to each other, a key contribution of this paper. In particular, we find that, although the formal rules and regulations had been changed to a more centralized, integrated structure, the narratives display a continued reliance on local, negotiated approach. Second, the deep cultural and historical meanings of the rivers play a pivotal role in providing normative incentives for collective action; and relatedly, this provides a way of ameliorating between local and national interests. Last, we argue that understanding narratives allows for a modified form of IWRM which provides explicitly for the contested nature of rules-in-use, as well as a role for normative incentives, which can account for a reframing of entrenched interests and existing path dependencies.

Section snippets

Studying socio-ecology as institutional change

Institutional scholars recognise that rules governing a system of interaction could be the informal norms and conventions – the “rules-in-use” – as well as the more obvious “rules-in-form” on formal record (Ostrom, 1990). However, the effects of particular rules are also difficult to study in isolation, as rules and norms interact with exogenous factors. Rules exist at multiple levels, and rules at any one level are embedded in the next higher tier. Kiser and Ostrom (2010) outline the hierarchy

Natural experiment in two rivers

IWRM was implemented in the Yellow River in 1997, and in the Ganges about 10 years later in 2008. Although the policy contexts were very different, the main IWRM intents and regulatory instruments were similar. The ecological subjects – the Yellow River and the Ganges – were also alike in scale, complexity and severity of environmental problems. In the Yellow River in China, the main ecological problem is over-siltation and repeated zero flow, resulting in extreme seasonal drought and flood.

Case of Ganges

River Ganges (Fig. 4), at 2525 km, is nearly half the length of the Yellow River. But it is not lesser in terms of complexity and governance challenge.

Pollution abatement in the Ganges has been an on-going process for 30 years without any positive results, the reasons being both regulatory as well as bureaucratic obstacles against an integrated approach. The first setback to realize a collective approach is the position of water in Indian Constitution as a state subject. It means that states

Operationalizing the Q: analysis of narratives

For the China survey, some 250 raw statements from the years 1997 to 2008 were gathered from online media, local newspapers and documents. These were then reduced to 69, after culling the statements that were very close in meaning or repeats. These statements were then used for a Q sort by 51 interviewees from different provinces, including water managers, farmers and government officials. The responses to the 69 statements were correlated in a 51 by 51 matrix. The matrix was factor-analysed

Comparative analysis

While the institutional endowments of both India and China are very different, in terms of IWRM reforms we have traced broad similarities in three ways—the ecological crises which necessitated IWRM reforms, the appointment of a formal central agency for implementation, and the formal regulatory changes supported by high level political attention. In the formation of meso-level action rules on collective choices, our analysis shows that Ganges narratives are less developed, not unexpectedly as

Conclusion: complementing IWRM

This study contributes to our current understanding of large rivers in two ways. First, recent IWRM studies have argued that it needs to be complemented by other approaches such as adaptive water management, or multi-level governance because of the complexity of the issues. We align ourselves with the need for complementarity, and argue that IWRM, in addition to being a paradigm for integration, can also be seen as narrative device for explaining (if not influencing) collective choice rules.

References (69)

  • M. Webber et al.

    The Yellow River in transition

    Environ. Sci. Policy

    (2008)
  • W. Blomquist et al.

    Political pitfalls of integrated watershed management

    Soc. Nat. Resour. Int. J.

    (2005)
  • C. Brannstrom

    A Q-method analysis of environmental governance discourses in Brazil’s northeastern soy frontier

    Prof. Geogr.

    (2011)
  • H. Bressers et al.

    Governance of water resources

  • A. Brookes

    Channelized Rivers: Perspectives for Environment Management

    (2002)
  • S. Brown

    Political subjectivity: Applications of Q-methodology in Political Science

    (1980)
  • R. Brunner et al.

    Beyond scientific management

  • Central Pollution Control Board (CPCB), India

    Pollution Assessment: River Ganga

    (2013)
  • Comptroller and Auditor General of India (CAG) Report/Union Government

    Ganga Action Plan

    (2000)
  • P. Das et al.

    The Ganges and the GAP: an assessment of efforts to clean a sacred river

    Sustainability

    (2012)
  • J.W. Dellapenna et al.

    The Evolution of the Law and Politics of Water

    (2009)
  • M.R. Doukkali

    Water institutional reforms in Morocco

    Water Policy

    (2005)
  • D. Durning

    The transition from traditional to postpositive policy analysis: a role for Q-methodology

    J. Policy Anal. Manag.

    (1999)
  • I. Fischhendler

    Institutional conditions for IWRM: the Israeli case

    Ground Water

    (2008)
  • J. Fisher et al.

    Wind energy on the Isle of Lewis: implications for deliberative planning

    Environ. Plan. A

    (2009)
  • Global Water Partnership (GWP)

    How IWRM will contribute to achieving the MDGs

    Technical Committee Policy Brief No. 4

    (2007)
  • E. Harris

    The impact of institutional path dependence on water market efficiency in Victoria, Australia

    Water Resour. Manag.

    (2011)
  • J. Harsha

    IWRM and IRBM concepts envisioned in Indian water policies

    Curr. Sci. (Bangalore)

    (2012)
  • H. Ingram et al.

    Path dependency and adroit innovation: the case of California water

  • S. Janakarajan

    Approaching IWRM through multi-stakeholders’ dialogue: some experiences from South India

  • P. Jeffrey et al.

    Integrated water resources management lost on the road from ambition to realisation?

    Water Sci. Technol.

    (2006)
  • K. Kemper et al.

    Integrated River Basin Management Through Decentralization

    (2007)
  • S. Kidd et al.

    Integrated water resource management and institutional integration: realising the potential of spatial planning in England

    Geogr. J.

    (2007)
  • L.L. Kiser et al.

    The three worlds of action: a metatheoretical synthesis of institutional approaches

  • Cited by (0)

    1

    Fax: +65 6468 4186.

    View full text