Pharmaceutical followers

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2013.10.005Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Estimates how me-too and generic drugs affect demand for anti-ulcer drugs.

  • Calculates counterfactual profits, insurance spending, and consumer welfare.

  • Forecasts changes in demand and prices from Nexium coming off patent.

  • Removing generic and me-too drugs decrease consumer welfare in similar ways.

  • However, they have vastly different effects on insurance spending and firm profits.

Abstract

We estimate a model of drug demand and supply that incorporates insurance, advertising, and competition between branded and generic drugs within and across therapeutic classes. We use data on antiulcer drugs from 1991 to 2010. Our simulations show that generics and “me-too” drugs each increased consumer welfare more than $100 million in 2010, holding insurance premiums constant. However, insurance payments in 2010 fell by nearly $1 billion due to generics and rose by over $7 billion due to me-too antiulcer drugs.

Introduction

Prescription drug spending as a share of U.S. national income more than tripled between 1984 and 2010.1 This occurred despite the generic share of prescriptions quadrupling over the same period.2 The increased use of generic drugs was facilitated by the U.S. Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984 (also known as the Hatch-Waxman Act) which exempted generic manufacturers from costly clinical trials. However, some branded manufacturers responded by launching “me-too” drugs, meaning patented drugs that require clinical testing for regulatory approval, but are little differentiated from drugs already on the market. The quintessential me-too drug is Nexium (esomeprazole) which became one of the highest-selling drugs of all time, despite being the fifth branded drug in its class and facing competition from generic versions of other drugs in its class. We formulate a demand and supply model to examine how pharmaceutical followers – both generic and me-too drugs – affect competition and welfare.

Some contend me-too drugs waste resources, perceiving that the gains in therapeutic value are small given that their molecular structure is similar to existing drugs and, unlike generics, me-too drugs require costly clinical trials to gain approval. In 2000, the editor of the New England Journal of Medicine recommended that regulators reject drugs that are too similar to existing options: “requiring manufacturers to demonstrate that a new drug is substantially better than anything available would help to stem the rising tide of me-too drugs” (Angell, 2000). Me-too drugs may also drain regulatory resources, because they require approval by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA), which has a backlog of drugs to review.3

A key challenge in quantifying the impact of new product entries in the U.S. drug market is the pervasive role of health insurance.4 Insured patients only pay a fraction (copayment) of the full price of pharmaceutical products, so the relevant price that the decision-maker faces is typically much lower than the posted price recorded in national datasets. Moreover, insurers often receive substantial rebates from manufacturers, creating an additional disconnect between the price observed in the data and the actual payoff to the producer. Accounting for both distortions is critical to performing meaningful counterfactuals: ignoring the first risks incorrectly concluding that patients are insensitive to price, while ignoring the second distorts the implied costs faced by suppliers.

Ours is the first study to tackle the distortions from both insurance copayments and rebates. To account for copayments, we estimate the relationship between price and copayment using insurance plan data, imputing copayments at the national level. The copayment–price relationship is then used to link the supply-side modeling of pricing decisions to copayments. To account for rebates paid by manufacturers to insurers, we exploit a government policy that constrains optimal rebates prior to generic entry. For rebates after generic entry, we identify implied rebate levels from changes in estimated marginal costs over time under the assumption that rebates are constrained prior to generic entry. After generic entry, fixed-rebate marginal costs jump, indicating a change in rebates consistent with the aforementioned cost distortion. We exploit this discrete jump to estimate the new rebate level.

Our demand model also allows for rich substitution patterns among drugs, which is important for obtaining accurate counterfactual predictions. To do so, we extend the work of Ellison et al. (1997), Stern (1996), Branstetter et al. (2011), and Bokhari and Fournier (2013) by modeling pharmaceutical demand using a discrete choice framework developed by Bresnahan et al. (1997). The framework allows for correlations across multiple nests, or clusters, of products. In particular, we allow for preferences to be correlated among products of the same class, same brand status (branded or generic), same form (tablet or capsule), and same molecule. Our framework allows the data to inform whether (and quantify the extent to which) drugs that vary across one or more of these dimensions are substitutes. Alternatively, drugs that vary across a dimension could be treated as perfect substitutes, or as non-substitutes that exist in separate markets altogether. On the supply side, we follow Bresnahan (1987) and others in modeling firms as playing a static pricing game. Incorporating the supply side allows us to recover marginal costs as well as simulate how prices would change under counterfactual scenarios.

We use monthly U.S. pharmaceutical price, advertising, and utilization data from 1991 to 2010. We focus on classes of drugs that contain quintessential me-too drugs: the H2 antagonists (H2s) and proton pump inhibitors (PPIs), including the aforementioned Nexium (esomeprazole), which treat ulcers and reflux. Our data include generic entry for every H2 and PPI molecule that has a generic version as of 2010.5

We estimate own-price (copayment) elasticities for branded drugs in the range of − 1.5 to − 5.1, with higher magnitudes corresponding to branded drugs that face generic competition. As expected, we find higher cross-price elasticities associated with the same classes, brand/generic statuses, forms, and molecules. Cross-price elasticities are also higher when a drug faces more competition from other sources. For example, an increase in the price of Nexium (esomeprazole), the market leader from 2005 to 2010, has a much larger effect on other PPIs that face generic competition than those that do not. This occurs because the primary market for PPIs faces generic competition from those who have preferences for branded drugs. Hence, these drugs are particularly sensitive to price movements by branded competitors.

Using our estimates of the supply-side and demand-side parameters, we perform two sets of counterfactuals. The first considers removing the pharmaceutical followers currently on the market. Removing me-too drugs (i.e. only keeping the first molecule in each class) or removing all generics leads to substantial drops in utilization which correspond to drops in consumer welfare of more than $100 million per year, holding insurance premiums fixed. However, the removal of these two groups has starkly different effects on insurance payments and manufacturer profits, effects that dwarf the consumer surplus changes. When generics are removed, profits gross of fixed costs rise by over $1 billion as the market becomes less competitive. Insurance payments rise nearly $1 billion. When me-too drugs are removed, insurance payments plummet, falling by over $7 billion annually, with manufacturer profits also falling by more than $4 billion.

Our second set of counterfactuals examines the effects of generic competition for the blockbuster me-too Nexium (esomeprazole). In the short run (a few months after generic entry) with one generic manufacturer, the branded drug reduces its price and competes, so consumer welfare rises. Adding additional generic competitors beyond the first has little effect on welfare because there is already significant price competition between the branded and generic manufacturers. However, adding generics does shift sales from the branded drug to the generics, effectively shutting the branded drug out of the market.

If only one generic version of Nexium (esomeprazole) were available, we find that consumer welfare would actually be higher in the short run than in the long run. In the long run, generic quality is sufficiently high and marginal costs sufficiently low that the branded manufacturer would raise its prices to compete only for consumers with strong preferences for branded drugs. This phenomenon – the branded manufacturer raising its price in the face of generic competition – is known as the “generic paradox” (Scherer, 1993).6 When the branded manufacturer raises price, it is not only bad for consumers of the branded drug, but also for consumers of the generic drug, because the generic drug manufacturer can raise its price as well. In this example, there is only one generic manufacturer. However, in markets with high demand, many generic manufacturers enter. With a second generic manufacturer, prices fall and consumer welfare rises. We estimate that with two or more generic manufacturers of Nexium (esomeprazole), consumer welfare will rise by about $200 million per year.

Dubois and Lasio (2013) also examine pharmaceutical demand in the antiulcer market. However, in contrast to our study of the U.S. market, they consider the impact of price regulation, a key institutional feature of most high-income markets, excluding the U.S. Exploiting cross-sectional variation in the degree or existence of price regulation, they are able to identify the impact of regulation in the settings in which it binds. Using their demand and supply estimates, they then identify the impact of regulation and examine counterfactuals in which regulation is eliminated.

While several studies have examined the welfare implications of pharmaceutical competition (Bokhari and Fournier, 2013, Branstetter et al., 2011, Chaudhuri et al., 2006, Dutta, 2011, Granlund, 2010), our paper is alone in tackling the intervening role of insurance, a key institutional feature of the U.S. market.7 Pharmaceutical studies using U.S. data frequently recover price elasticities that are inconsistent with profit maximization under standard models of supply, making it difficult if not impossible to solve for equilibrium prices in counterfactual simulations, thereby sharply limiting the scope of analysis.8 Further, consumer welfare calculations hinge on the magnitude of the price coefficient in the estimated indirect utility function, highlighting the importance of having correct pricing data.9 We show that our linking of prices and copayments yields economically reasonable elasticity estimates, making it possible to obtain both counterfactual equilibrium prices as well as conduct welfare analysis.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides background on the antiulcer market and shows how it has evolved over time. Section 3 describes the demand model, including a discussion of copayments and the evolution of the outside good. Section 4 explains the model of supply and the role of rebates. Section 5 gives the estimates of both the demand and supply models as well as showing their implications for elasticities and the evolution of rebates. Section 6 shows the counterfactuals, including the removal of generic or me-too drugs and the introduction of generic Nexium (esomeprazole). Section 7 concludes.

Section snippets

Background and data

Our focus is on the “antiulcer” market, which includes not only drugs that treat ulcers but also reflux (“heartburn”).10 The prevalence of reflux in the population is between 10% and 20% (Fedorak et al., 2010) and the prevalence of ulcers is approximately 1% (Kurata and Haile, 1984). The earliest entrants into the antiulcer market were H2 antagonists (H2s), followed by proton

Demand

Our demand model allows for four types of product differentiation: (i) between classes (H2 and PPI), (ii) between brands and generics (for example, branded omeprazole and generic omeprazole), (iii) between forms (capsule and tablet), and (iv) between molecules (branded omeprazole and branded lansoprazole).

One type of switching – from brand to generic of the same molecule – is quite common. The pharmacist can freely switch a patient from branded lansoprazole to generic lansoprazole, unless

Supply

Consistent estimation of the demand system does not require a supply side, but performing counterfactuals does, because we will need to predict how prices change when products are added or deleted from the market.31

Results

Key demand-side parameter estimates are presented in Table 3, Table 4, Table 5. Table 3 contains the parameter estimates that link copayment to price. The coefficients show copayment increases with price, but at a diminishing rate. We then use these parameters to form copayments for all periods in the data, taking into account the adjustments outlined in Section 3.2.

The non-linear, or nesting, parameters, which drive cross-product substitution, are presented in Table 4. The molecule nesting

Value of eliminating pharmaceutical followers

We can now combine our supply- and demand-side estimates to calculate how equilibrium prices and shares will change under various hypothetical scenarios. We begin by considering three such counterfactuals: (1) no generics, (2) no me-too molecules (only the first in class), and (3) no PPIs.38 Table 9 lists shares

Conclusion

We estimate the demand and supply of antiulcer drugs, accommodating rich substitution patterns across classes, brand/generic status, forms, and molecules. We deal with two challenges caused by insurance. First, the prices we see in the data are not the prices paid by consumers due to insurance subsidies. Second, firm revenues are distorted because firms pay sizable rebates to insurance companies.

The estimates of the demand and supply models allow us to perform two sets of counterfactuals.

References (54)

  • E.R. Berndt et al.

    Brand loyalty, generic entry and price competition in pharmaceuticals in the quarter century after the 1984 Waxman-Hatch legislation

    Int. J. Econ. Bus.

    (2011)
  • E.R. Berndt et al.

    Information, marketing, and pricing in the U.S. antiulcer drug market

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1995)
  • E.R. Berndt et al.

    Consumption externalities and diffusion in pharmaceutical markets: antiulcer drugs

    J. Ind. Econ.

    (2003)
  • S.T. Berry

    Estimating discrete-choice models of product differentiation

    RAND J. Econ.

    (1994)
  • S.T. Berry et al.

    Automobile prices in market equilibrium

    Econometrica

    (1995)
  • J. Bhattacharya et al.

    A simple model of pharmaceutical price dynamics

    J. Law Econ.

    (2003)
  • F.A.S. Bokhari et al.

    Entry in the ADHD drugs market: welfare impact of generics and me-too's

    J. Ind. Econ.

    (2013)
  • K. Brand et al.

    Mergers when prices are negotiated: evidence from the hospital industry

  • L.G. Branstetter et al.

    Regulation and welfare: evidence from paragraph IV generic entry in the pharmaceutical industry

  • J. Breitkreutz et al.

    Drug delivery and formulations

  • T.F. Bresnahan

    Competition and collusion in the American automobile industry

    J. Ind. Econ.

    (1987)
  • T.F. Bresnahan et al.

    Market segmentation and the sources of rents from innovation: personal computers in the late 1980s

    RAND J. Econ.

    (1997)
  • S. Chaudhuri et al.

    Estimating the effects of global patent protection in pharmaceuticals: a case study of Quinolones in India

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2006)
  • A.T. Ching

    A dynamic oligopoly structural model for the prescription drug market after patent expiration

    Int. Econ. Rev.

    (2010)
  • A.T. Ching et al.

    The effects of detailing on prescribing decisions under quality uncertainty

    Quant. Mark. Econ.

    (2010)
  • G.S. Crawford et al.

    Uncertainty and learning in pharmaceutical demand

    Econometrica

    (2005)
  • J.M. Donohue et al.

    A decade of direct-to-consumer advertising of prescription drugs

    N. Engl. J. Med.

    (2007)
  • Cited by (36)

    • Pharmaceuticals, incremental innovation and market exclusivity

      2023, International Journal of Industrial Organization
    • Collusion in the US generic drug industry

      2022, International Journal of Industrial Organization
      Citation Excerpt :

      This is akin to assuming that demand is perfectly inelastic. A growing literature on pharmaceuticals finds that demand for drugs is elastic (for example, Arcidiacono et al., 2013, Björnerstedt and Verboven, 2016, Dubois and Lasio, 2018). However, estimates on US Medicare Part D beneficiaries find low elasticities for pharmaceuticals, both at the drug and the class (market) level.

    • Welfare effects of public procurement of medicines: Evidence from Ecuador

      2021, International Journal of Industrial Organization
    • Pricing strategy and moral hazard: Copay coupons in pharmaceuticals

      2020, International Journal of Industrial Organization
      Citation Excerpt :

      The marginal cost of generic drugs for a 30-day supply is $19 lower than that of their branded counterpart. The cost difference between branded and generic drugs is close to the estimate of $23.7 in Arcidiacono et al. (2013), in which data on antiulcer drugs from 1991 to 2010 are used for estimation.43 Furthermore, the marginal cost declines quickly since a drug’s entry, which implies that drug production gets much more efficient as a drug becomes mature on the market.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    Michael Anderson provided excellent research assistance. We are grateful for helpful comments from Yair Taylor and seminar participants at Duke University and the University of Massachusetts-Amherst.

    View full text