Bidder motives in cause-related auctions

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2009.07.001Get rights and content

Abstract

We study cause-related auctions where a percentage of the dynamically determined purchase price of an item is donated to charity. Little is known about the effectiveness of such auctions. Bidders who value donations to charity have an incentive to bid more aggressively in such auctions. Regardless of whether they win or not, these bidders can significantly affect prices. The purpose of this paper is to study bidders' willingness to pay a premium in charity auctions and the drivers that affect the charity premium. We use a carefully designed field experiment involving simultaneous pairs of auctions that are identical in all respects but percentage of the proceeds donated to charity. This design gives us the ability to look at bidder choice among auctions based on charitable considerations. We use a mixture model approach to allow for different types of individual preferences. We find that individuals fall into three segments: two altruistic segments and a selfish segment. The altruistic segments, which drive up the charity premium, can be classified as warm glow bidders who derive pleasure from the act of giving and other-regarding bidders who give for selfless reasons. Results show that the difference in donation percentages is the major factor influencing the charitable premium. However, bidders differ considerably in their responses to donation percentages. While other-regarding bidders tend to seek auctions where a greater percentage of revenue is donated to charity, warm glow bidders only contribute when the charity premium is sufficiently low. Thus, managers should focus their marketing efforts on appealing to these different segments, depending on the percentage donated to charity.

Introduction

Charitable giving has significantly increased in the past decade. Internet charity auctions are on the rise, in particular, with eBay dedicating a special section for charity auctions. Not only do these auctions play an important role for non-profit organizations, but an increasing number of firms are sponsoring these events in order to establish themselves as good corporate citizens. In turn, sponsorship of social causes may improve a firm's image or profits (Lichtenstein et al., 2004, Navarro, 1988, Varadarajan and Menon, 1988).2

While charitable auctions are an important fund-raising tool, little is known about their effectiveness or about participants' bidding behavior and charitable intent. Theoretical work (e.g., Engers and McManus, 2007, Ettinger, 2003, Goeree et al., 2005) has investigated the properties of different formats of charity auctions under the assumption that bidders care about the charity's revenue. The general result is that private benefits from charitable giving can translate into a “charity premium,” an increase in auction revenue resulting from charitable donations.

Unlike non-charity auctions, where careful analysis of bids can reveal preference for the item being auctioned, the decision to bid in charity auctions also relates to an individual's altruistic preference for donation. To identify the altruistic component separate from a bidder's valuation of the item, we focus on the endogenous choice between auctions with different donation percentages.3 We have designed a novel way to measure bidders' charitable intent.

With the exception of empirical works by Ku, Malhotra, and Murnighan (2005) on competitive arousal and Isaac and Schnier (2005) on jump bidding, extant empirical research on charity auctions has focused on identifying the optimal auction format (Carpenter et al., 2008, Salmon and Isaac, 2006). In contrast to past literature, we study the case where bidders are faced with a choice between identical simultaneous product auctions with different percentages donated to charity.

One key issue relates to individual selfish optimization in charity auction settings. This is a basic underlying assumption in analysis of non-charity auctions, and it is interesting to see whether it holds in charity auctions. It is plausible that not all individuals will behave in a manner consistent with seeking the best deal when faced with the decision to bid in a charity or non-charity auction for the same good (Engers and McManus, 2007, Ettinger, 2003, Salmon and Isaac, 2006). One reason that bidders might not be fully sensitive to price is due to charitable considerations. They may have a genuine concern for the well-being of others. This type of motive is often referred to as pure altruism (Becker, 1974, Lehmann, 2001). According to the model of pure altruism, an individual derives utility from the well-being of others regardless of the source of funding. This model may explain charitable giving, but it may also predict a substantial crowding out of an individual's own donations due to additional contributions by others (Roberts, 1984). However, individuals may also donate for other reasons (Fisher et al., 2008, Hill and Watkins, 2009), such as utility from the act of giving itself. This is known as warm glow (Andreoni, 1989, Konow, 2004, Eckel et al., 2005). The warm glow may arise because individuals think they are observed by others (Glazer and Konrad, 1996, Romano and Yildirim, 2001) or as a signal of social status (Rose-Ackerman, 1996, Glazer and Konrad, 1996).

In field data, where valuations cannot be observed, alternative utility specifications are typically very difficult to extract. However, in the present setting, we can make some inferences about individual preferences based on choices among competing auctions. We identify different segments of bidders based on their bidding behavior in charity and non-charity auctions. We find a non-charitable segment and two charitable segments, corresponding to both warm glow and other-regarding altruism, willing to pay a significant price premium for auctions involving charitable donations.

Section snippets

Data description

All experiments were conducted on a local internet auction website, hosted in a major North American city. The auction website was established in September 2002 and had over 6300 registered users as of October 2007. It used a format similar to eBay.com. It conducted both charity and non-charity auctions, and registered users were familiar with the website as a regular auction site, not just a charity auction site.4

Charity premium

The fact that people can behave in a seemingly non-selfish manner is well known. People have been observed doing kind acts, giving to others, and helping others in need (see Fehr & Fischbacher, 2003, for an overview). The ability of a marketing manager to harness that altruism is less certain. In a market setting, people are predisposed to seek bargains (see Vohs, Mead, & Goode, 2006 for the difference between market and social settings). Moreover, individuals may be inclined to free-ride on

Charity premium

We begin by characterizing the charity premium and its factors. We define the charity premium as the difference in auction revenue between the higher donation percentage charity auction and the lower percentage charity auction (non-charity auctions are denoted as 0%). Since different auctions involve different items, it may be more informative to look at charity premiums as percentages. The percentage charity premium is computed in Eq. (5) as the difference in revenues divided by the average

Discussion

Our first result is the finding that a charity premium is significant and substantial in simultaneous auction pairs that are identical in all respects but percentage donated to charity. A second result is that this premium depends most crucially on the donation percentage difference between the auctions in a pair. To date, this is the cleanest empirical demonstration of such an effect. First, the design eliminates all confounds naturally arising from different times, different sellers, and

Viability of cause-related donation in auctions

A business with the objective of maximizing profit finds it profitable to engage in cause-related donations when the incremental profit from a $1 donation exceeds the $1 donated. This incremental profit typically comes from tax write-offs and the value of goodwill. This means that, for a non-auction item, the value of goodwill should be about sixty plus cents on the dollar. For auction items, unlike non-auction items, the presence of a charity contribution actually increases the price of the

Limitations and future extensions

The first and natural question in any experimental study is external validity. In particular, would the results that we reported here hold on eBay or other websites that run charity auctions? Without further research, we can only speculate on applicability to other platforms. However, we can safely say that this particular auction site is a substantial and well-recognized market in its geographical area and is, in fact, a primary fund-raising vehicle for local charities. The implications have a

References (43)

  • AmemiyaT.

    Advanced econometrics

    (1985)
  • AndreoniJ.

    Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1989)
  • AndreoniJ.

    Philanthropy

  • AndreoniJ. et al.

    Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2001)
  • AndrewsR.L. et al.

    Retention of latent segments in regression-based marketing models

    International Journal of Research in Marketing

    (2003)
  • AroraN.

    Estimating joint preference: A sub-sampling approach

    International Journal of Research in Marketing

    (2006)
  • BeckerG.S.

    A theory of social interactions

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1974)
  • BrownT.J. et al.

    The company and the product: Corporate associations and consumer product responses

    Journal of Marketing

    (1997)
  • BultJ.R. et al.

    Interaction between target and mailing characteristics in direct marketing, with an application to health care fund raising

    International Journal of Research in Marketing

    (1997)
  • CarpenterJ. et al.

    Charity auctions: A field experimental investigation

    Economic Journal

    (2008)
  • EckelC.C. et al.

    An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis

    Journal of Public Economics

    (2005)
  • EngersM.P. et al.

    Charity auctions

    International Economic Review

    (2007)
  • Ettinger, D. (2003). Bidding among friends and enemies. Unpublished working paper, University College London. Available...
  • FehrE. et al.

    The nature of human altruism

    Nature

    (2003)
  • FisherR.J. et al.

    The effects of content, placement, and delivery characteristics on televised fundraising for nonprofit organizations

    Journal of Consumer Research

    (2008)
  • GlazerA. et al.

    A signaling explanation for private charity

    American Economic Review

    (1996)
  • GoereeJ.K. et al.

    How (not) to raise money

    Journal of Political Economy

    (2005)
  • HandelmanJ. et al.

    The role of marketing actions with a social dimension: Appeals to the institutional environment

    Journal of Marketing

    (1999)
  • HillR.P. et al.

    The profit implications of altruistic versus egoistic orientations for business-to-business exchanges

    International Journal of Research in Marketing

    (2009)
  • IsaacR.M. et al.

    Silent Auctions in the Field and in the Laboratory

    Economic Inquiry

    (2005)
  • IslamT. et al.

    Modeling the effects of including/excluding attributes in choice experiments on systematic and random components

    International Journal of Research in Marketing

    (2007)
  • Cited by (36)

    • How does regulatory monitoring of cause marketing affect firm behavior and donations to charity?

      2022, International Journal of Research in Marketing
      Citation Excerpt :

      A 2012 Edelman study finds that 72% of consumers from 16 countries are more likely to spread the word on social media for a brand that supports a good cause over one that does not.10 While these studies are based on consumer surveys, theoretical and experimental academic research too has shown that CM can positively influence consumers’ attitudes, brand preferences, purchase intention, and willingness to pay (Arora and Henderson 2007; Haruvy and Leszczyc 2009; Krishna and Rajan 2009; Henderson and Arora 2010). In addition, the outcomes of CM campaigns are influenced by factors such as firm donation amount, donation-related and cause-related customer predispositions, the fit between the firm and the cause, and the co-creation of CM initiatives between consumers and brands (Chen and Huang 2016; Koschate-Fischer et al. 2012; Kull and Heath 2016; Müller et al. 2014; Zdravkovic et al. 2010).

    • Cause-related marketing is not always less favorable than corporate philanthropy: The moderating role of self-construal

      2016, International Journal of Research in Marketing
      Citation Excerpt :

      The present research has several additional limitations. First, we compared only CRM and corporate philanthropy; other types of CSR campaigns such as sponsorship (Cornwell, Weeks, & Roy, 2005) or cause-related auctions (Haruvy & Popkowski Leszczyc, 2009) were not included. Second, we did not consider other possible influential factors associated with the corporations and the charitable causes.

    • Measuring the Impact of Price Guarantees on Bidding in Consumer Online Auctions

      2016, Journal of Retailing
      Citation Excerpt :

      On average 55.7% (3.8%), or 97 of 174, bidders placed a bid in one of the other conditions (see online Appendix B and C, for more bidder-specific information), owing to bidder participation across conditions, the 174 bidders can be estimated in a single regression, accounting for the condition as an explanatory variable. We find that one-fourth to one-third of bidders never switch between auctions in a pair (most of these bidders placed a single bid), a finding that is consistent with similar percentages reported in earlier studies (Haruvy and Popkowski Leszczyc 2009b, 2010). Despite switching by the overwhelming majority of bidders, the number of switches as a percentage of total bids is small and typically under one-third of all bids (Table 4).

    • A comparison of different pay-per-bid auction formats

      2014, International Journal of Research in Marketing
      Citation Excerpt :

      Otherwise, the auction continues, and the bidder can wait and place an additional bid to reveal information regarding an updated (lower) price. Research on online auctions has recently been increasing in popularity (Barrot, Albers, Skiera, & Schäfers, 2010; Dholakia, Basuroy, & Soltysinski, 2002; Haruvy & Popkowski Leszczyc, 2009; Jap & Naik, 2008; Pinker, Seidmann, & Vakrat, 2003). Ever since the broad acceptance of the Internet online auctions such as eBay have become more popular.

    • A Network Bidder Behavior Model in Online Auctions: A Case of Fine Art Auctions

      2014, Journal of Retailing
      Citation Excerpt :

      Sales outcomes have also been studied as a function of design elements of the auction formats themselves, such as whether bids are sealed or transparent (Cheema, Chakravarti, and Sinha 2012; Jap 2002; Klemperer 1998; Lucking-Reiley 1999). For example, English (ascending) auctions tend to generate larger surpluses than second-price auctions or Dutch (descending) auctions (Milgrom and Weber 1982), and auctions designated to raise money to benefit charities tend to yield higher bid prices, whether all proceeds or a lesser percentage of sales are donated (Haruvy and Popkowski Leszczyc 2009b; Popkowski Leszczyc and Rothkopf 2010). Auction outcomes have also been studied as a function of characteristics of the products being sold.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    This research was supported by grants from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada, through both its Initiative on the New Economy Research Alliances Program (SSHRC grant 538-02-1013) and its Standard Research Grants Program (SSHRC grant 410-01-1332).

    1

    Tel.: +1 780 492 1866; fax: +1 780 492 3325.

    View full text