Complementary credit networks and macroeconomic stability: Switzerland's Wirtschaftsring

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2009.06.002Get rights and content

Abstract

The Swiss Wirtschaftsring (“Economic Circle”) credit network, founded in 1934, provides residual spending power that is highly counter-cyclical. Individuals are cash-short in a recession, and economize by greater use of WIR-credits. A money in the production function (MIPF) specification implies that transactions in WIR form a stabilizing balance that makes up for the lack of ordinary currency. Thus, unlike the ordinary money, WIR money is negatively correlated with GDP in the short run. This implication is confirmed by empirical estimates. Such credit networks play a stabilizing role that should be considered in monetary policy.

Introduction

Large scale moneyless clearing, as portrayed by the Walrasian auctioneer, flourished in the “storehouse” economies of the ancient Middle East and Americas (Polanyi, 1947) when all relevant information could be centralized. Decentralized monetary systems evolved as the information for a complex economy became too great to be centrally managed with ancient information technology (Stodder, 1995a, Stodder, 1995b). Modern IT is again making centralized exchange plausible, however, on sites like http://www.irta.com, http://www.barter.net, http://www.swap.com, and http://www.itex.com.

A few prominent macroeconomists have speculated that computer-networked exchange might eventually replace decentralized money, as well as central banking (King, 1999, Beattie, 1999, Friedman, 2001, Economist, 2000a, Economist, 2000b, World Bank, 2000). The purpose of this paper is not to gauge the likelihood of such change, but to explain why centralized exchange is counter-cyclical.

This paper's subject, the Swiss Wirtschaftsring, or “WIR”, is sometimes called an alternative or complementary currency. It is really a centralized credit system for multilateral exchange, however, with no physical currency. The present paper is not based on a microeconomic search model of a decentralized currency, such as the work of Kiyotaki and Wright, 1989, Kiyotaki and Wright, 1993. Their model has been applied to the conditions under which a national currency is replaced, in whole or in part, by a foreign currency, as in several Latin American and East European economies (Calvo and Végh, 1992, Trejos and Wright, 1995, Curtis and Waller, 2000, Feige, 2003). This dual-currency literature is well surveyed by Craig and Waller (2000).

These Kiyotaki–Wright (KW) type models are not appropriate for our study of the Swiss WIR, however, for at least two reasons. First, KW models show the costs of matching holders of goods with holders of a decentralized and freely circulating currency. But these search costs approach zero for members of WIR, an informationally centralized exchange network. A second point, emphasized in Clower and Howitt, 1978, Clower and Howitt, 1996, Clower and Howitt, 1998, Clower and Howitt, 2000, is that WIR-credit is a consciously designed system of exchange, rather than one that emerges as the lowest transaction-cost medium:

In our view what characterizes a monetary economy is not so much that different transactors all choose to accept the same exchange intermediary for their production commodities, as in search theory, but that the shops they deal with don’t give them any choice. (2000, p. 58).1

The KW literature models dual-currency equilibrium and does not usually consider persistent shortages of the primary currency. An exception to this is the KW model of Colacelli and Blackburn (2006), analyzing surveys of Argentine users of creditos or localized currencies, during that country's recession of 2002–2003 (cf. Gomez, 2008). These surveys show credito usage especially common among less skilled employees and women, who may be more economically vulnerable. Importantly for the counter-cyclical thesis of the present paper, Colacelli and Blackburn (2006) show that:

  • (a)

    The circulation of creditos was strongly correlated with shortages of the national currency, as was the growth of local ‘script’ currencies in the US depression of the 1930s (Fisher, 1934);

  • (b)

    Real income gains to credito users were substantial, averaging 15 percent of Argentina's mean personal income.

There are hundreds of alternative-currency examples in existence today, described in the literature on local exchange and trading systems, or LETS (Williams, 1996, Greco, 2001, Gomez, 2008); some of these use a centralized credit system with no circulating currency. The Swiss WIR-Bank is the largest such system, operating on the basis of centralized credit, rather than a circulating currency. The WIR is also longer-lived than any LETS or corporate barter network (Stodder, 1998, Studer, 1998).

The thesis of this paper is that WIR exchange has been strongly counter-cyclical within the Swiss Economy. The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 explains how exchange works with WIR-credits and outlines my basic argument. Section 3 translates this thesis into formal propositions and empirical specifications. Section 4 presents the empirical tests of the counter-cyclical thesis. Section 5 summarizes my conclusions and suggests that a WIR-type system – centralized exchange plus multilateral trade credits – should have a similarly stabilizing effect in any advanced economy.

Section snippets

The WIR-Bank exchange system: statement of the argument

The Swiss WIR-Bank or Wirtschaftsring (“Economic Ring”), founded in 1934 (Studer, 1998, p. 14), is the world's largest and oldest exchange based solely on a private or ‘club’ form of money, with more than 77,000 small firm and household members in 2003 (see Table 1, Table 2). All types of goods and services are exchanged – house painting, hotel stays, used cars, legal services – with offerings posted online and in publications like WIR-Plus. Prices are quoted in units of WIR-credit, which for

Theoretical basics—money in the production function

A convenient way of showing the macroeconomic role of money is the “money in the production function” (MIPF) specification, analogous to “money in the utility function” (MIUF). Either MIPF or MIUF can be justified by the transactions-cost-saving role that money plays, to move an economy closer to its efficiency frontier (Patinkin, 1956, Sidrauski, 1967, Fischer, 1974, Fischer, 1979, Short, 1979, Finnerty, 1980, Feenstra, 1986, Hasan and Mahmud, 1993, Handa, 2000, Rösl, 2006). We will not

Data and initial estimates

Because the WIR record is not widely available, I provide the basic data. The WIR bank has provided 56 years of data on Nombre de Comptes-Participants (“Number of Account-Participants”), Chiffre (o Volume) d’Affaires (“Turnover” activity), and Autres Obligations Financières envers Clients en WIR (or “Credit” advanced in the form of credit to one's reciprocal exchange account). Turnover and credit are equivalent to m˜s and ms in our model, respectively, and are given in terms of WIR; i.e., their

Conclusions and discussion

This linkage between WIR and M2 begs the question of which was more effective as a counter-cyclical tool. There is clear evidence of M2's pro-cyclical performance (not shown here) for the entire period 1952–2003. This is consistent with our theory, which shows that short-term variation in mp can be pro-cyclical. And it is reinforced by a considerable literature (Mankiw, 1993, Mankiw and Summers, 1986, Bernanke and Gertler, 1995, Gavin and Kydland, 1999) finding that the broad money supply is

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Marusa Freire, Michael Linton, Daniel Flury, Tobias Studer, Gerhardt Rösl, and an anonymous referee for their help and encouragement; all remaining errors are my responsibility.

References (85)

  • B. Bernanke et al.

    Inside the black box: the credit channel of monetary policy transmission

    Journal of Economic Perspectives

    (1995)
  • Calvo, G., Végh, C., 1992. Currency substitution in developing countries: an introduction. IMF Working Paper,...
  • G. Chichilnisky et al.

    Volatility in the knowledge economy

    Journal of Economic Theory

    (2004)
  • R. Clower

    The Keynesian counterrevolution: a theoretical appraisal

  • R. Clower et al.

    The transactions theory of the demand for money: a reconsideration

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1978)
  • R. Clower et al.

    Taking markets seriously: groundwork for a post Walrasian macroeconomics

  • R. Clower et al.

    Keynes and the classics: an end of century view

  • R. Clower et al.

    The emergence of economic organization

    Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

    (2000)
  • M. Colacelli et al.

    Secondary Currency: An Empirical Analysis

    (2006)
  • B.R. Craig et al.

    Dual-currency economies as multiple-payment systems

    Economic Review

    (2000)
  • E.S. Curtis et al.

    A search-theoretic model of legal and illegal currency

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2000)
  • G. Davies

    A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day

    (2002)
  • Defila, H., 1994. Sixty years of the WIR economic circle cooperative: origins and ideology of the Wirtschaftsring. WIR...
  • Economist Magazine, 2000a. Economics focus: who needs money? January 22,...
  • Economist Magazine, 2000b. Economics focus: e-money revisited. July 22,...
  • J. Finnerty

    Real money balances and the firm's production function: a note

    Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking

    (1980)
  • E.L. Feige

    The dynamics of currency substitution, asset substitution and de facto dollarization and euroization in transition countries

    Comparative Economic Studies

    (2003)
  • S. Fischer

    Money and the production function

    Economic Inquiry

    (1974)
  • S. Fischer

    Capital accumulation on the transition path in a monetary optimizing model

    Econometrica

    (1979)
  • I. Fisher

    Mastering the Crisis—With Additional Chapters on Stamp Script

    (1934)
  • B. Friedman

    The future of monetary policy

    International Finance

    (2001)
  • M. Goldberg et al.

    Monetarism, overshooting, and the procyclical movement of velocity

    Economic Inquiry

    (1977)
  • G.M. Gomez

    Making Markets: The Institutional Rise and Decline of the Argentine red de trueque

    (2008)
  • T.H. Greco

    Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender

    (2001)
  • Greenspan, A., 1999. Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee. US Congress, June 14....
  • J. Handa

    Monetary Economics

    (2000)
  • M.A. Hasan et al.

    Is money an omitted variable in the production function? Some further results

    Empirical Economics

    (1993)
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2007. International Financial Statistics....
  • International Reciprocal Trade Association (IRTA), 2009....
  • N. Kiyotaki et al.

    On money as a medium of exchange

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1989)
  • Cited by (56)

    • Money is money: The economic impact of BerkShares

      2022, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Although we have incorporated smaller scale indicators into our analysis, it is still possible that the lack of observable impact from BerkShares is due to its small scope instead of (or in addition to) a failure of the CC to deliver positive results. Subsequent research should follow Stodder (2009) by examining CCs that are wide in scope. Without the complicating factor of the scope of the CC, such research would be able to more clearly evaluate CC success.

    • The Ecology of Money: A Critical Assessment

      2020, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      However, contrary to what Lietaer et al. (2009) claim, they do not go as far as saying that the existence of the WIR explains overall Swiss stability. Stodder (2009) makes clear that, while he found a statistically significant counter-cyclical effect of the WIR on the Swiss economy, that effect is rather small and does not constitute the main explaining factor of Swiss stability (see also Blanc, 2018, p. 99). The existence of “fall-back” currencies may indeed constitute a valuable mechanism for economic stability.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text