New evidence on nominal exchange rate predictability

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2008.12.008Get rights and content

Abstract

The Meese–Rogoff puzzle, one of the well-known puzzles in international economics, concerns the weak relationship between nominal exchange rates and market fundamentals. The purpose of this paper is to show that market fundamentals do in fact matter in forecasting nominal exchange rates. In particular, we emphasize the importance of the Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson effect in modeling deviations from purchasing power parity. Based on the post-Bretton Woods period, we provide solid out-of-sample evidence that rejects the random walk forecast model at medium-term and long-term forecast horizons. We also find mild evidence for out-of-sample predictability of nominal exchange rates over the short term.

Introduction

Since the publication of the seminal paper by Meese and Rogoff (1983), the predictability of exchange rates has been the subject of an ongoing scholarly debate in empirical international finance and has inspired a large volume of papers over the past two decades. Meese and Rogoff (1983) compare the predictive ability of a variety of exchange rate models and conclude that no existing structural exchange rate models can reliably beat random walks at short- or medium-term forecast horizons in out-of-sample forecast contests. Their finding is robust to assumptions of different fundamentals such as purchasing power parity (PPP) and uncovered interest rate parity, as well as to the use of the realized value of fundamentals in the forecast period and is now known as the Meese–Rogoff Puzzle. This puzzle is also sometimes referred to as the exchange rate disconnect puzzle (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000). Meese and Rogoff's findings are quite striking since a random walk model is not embedded within any economic wisdom or theory. The goals of research on exchange rate predictability over the past two decades have been to uncover the reasons which explain the Meese–Rogoff puzzle and to provide evidence which rejects the random walk forecast model.

A number of authors have found evidence which beats random walk forecasts in out-of-sample contests (e.g. Chinn and Meese, 1995, Mark, 1995, MacDonald and Marsh, 1997). The empirical procedure and the robustness of results in the previously mentioned literature have been challenged by a number of authors (e.g. Cheung et al., 2005, Kilian, 1999, Berkowitz and Giorgianni, 2001, Berben and van Dijik, 1998, Rossi, 2005). Recently several authors have applied the panel approach to show evidence of co-integration between exchange rates and fundamentals and then have provided evidence which beats random walk forecasts (e.g. Mark and Sul, 2001, Groen, 2000). However, these articles fail to examine the significance of deviations between two forecast errors.

One possible explanation for the Meese–Rogoff puzzle is that the linear forecasting model fails to capture important non-linearities in the data. However, a number of authors have found that allowing for regime switching in exchange rate models does not improve the out-of-sample predictability of the models (e.g. Engel and Hamilton, 1990, Engel, 1994). Other forms of non-linearity have also been found to be largely unimportant for exchange rates (e.g. Diebold and Nason, 1990, Meese and Rose, 1991). Recent empirical work has supported non-linear, mean-reverting adjustment of real exchange rates and has shown that the exponential smooth transition autoregressive (ESTAR) model provides a parsimonious fit to the data (e.g. Michael et al., 1997, Taylor et al., 2001, Taylor and Peel, 2000). Given the fact that real exchange rates follow an ESTAR process, Kilian and Taylor (2003) provide in-sample evidence to beat the random walk forecast at horizons of 2–3 years, but their out-of-sample evidence is fairly weak. Based on simulation results, Kilian and Taylor (2003) argue that the reason for the poor out-of-sample predictability of their model may be due to the short sample period available for empirical analysis.

Most existing literature which applies the ESTAR model to describe real exchange rate dynamics assumes that the long-run equilibrium of real exchange rates is time invariant and hence ignores the effects of real factors on the equilibrium of real exchange rates. Several articles argue that productivity differentials between countries affect real exchange rates (e.g. Harrod, 1939, Balassa, 1964, Samuelson, 1964). The Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson (HBS) effect suggests that, under some assumptions, fast growing economies will experience a rising relative price of non-tradables and hence a real appreciation over time. In this case, deviations from PPP will revert to an equilibrium trend instead of a constant mean implying that the real exchange rate would exhibit a trend behavior if one takes the Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson (HBS) effects into account.1 Based on the idea of differential productivity growth in tradables and non-tradables, Obstfeld (1993) develops a simple stochastic model in which real exchange rates contain a pronounced deterministic trend. Kilian and Taylor (2003) argue that the HBS effect is significant when long historical data are used, but may not be significant in the shorter post-Bretton Woods period. Their arguments are also underscored by recent empirical findings with long historical data (e.g. Lothian, 1990, Cuddington and Liang, 2000, Lothian and Taylor, 2000, Lothian and Taylor, 2008, Taylor, 2002, Peel and Venetis, 2003, Taylor and Taylor, 2004). However, Bergin et al. (2006) point out that “the HBS effect has not always been a fact of economic life, and appears to be a phenomenon of only the postwar period.” Their empirical evidence reveals that the effect virtually vanishes from the data if one looks back fifty years or more. Several recent studies also point out the significance of the HBS effect on equilibrium real exchange rates over the post-Bretton Woods period, which indicates the significance of the HBS effect even in relatively short spans of data (Paya et al., 2003, Paya and Peel, 2003, Sollis, 2005).2

If the HBS effect is significant and is neglected in an empirical exchange rate model, then the estimation would suffer from omitted-variable bias, which could in turn result in the failure of the model in its out-of-sample predictability. The purpose of this paper is two-fold. First, we combine the non-linear adjustment of real exchange rates and the HBS effect in a model and then apply it to address the issue of nominal exchange rate predictability. Second, we investigate the significance of the HBS effect in enhancing exchange rate forecasts by examining whether the failure to reject the random walk forecast as observed in most existing literature can be explained solely by the restriction of short sample period.

Using the data over the post-Bretton Woods period for several industrialized countries, we obtained the following significant findings. First, our model fits the data reasonably well and shows that real effects (such as the HBS effect) on the equilibrium real exchange rate are important even in relatively short spans of data. Second, we provide strong out-of-sample evidence which rejects the random walk forecast of nominal exchange rates at horizons of 2–4 years. We also find mild evidence for out-of-sample predictability of nominal exchange rates when forecast horizons are less than one year. These results are robust to several newly developed statistical tests, to different sample periods and to different initial windows of estimation. Our findings are illuminating since they indicate that taking the HBS effect into account in an ESTAR model can help to strengthen the recursive out-of-sample predictability of the long-horizon regression equation.3 Using a less parsimonious model we obtain evidence of out-of-sample predictability. To the best of our knowledge, our paper is the first paper that provides solid out-of-sample evidence to reject random walk forecasts at short-term, medium-term and long forecast horizons.4

Third, simulation results point out that our bootstrap tests have correct size and good power given the modified ESTAR dynamics of real exchange rates. There is no indication that the power of bootstrap tests increases with forecast horizons. The contribution of the paper is to complement the existing literature by providing new out-of-sample evidence on the predictability of nominal exchange rates, which enriches our understanding of the Messe–Rogoff puzzle.

The article proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a brief discussion of the HBS effect and several issues in its empirical application. Section 3 describes the estimation results of our model. Section 4 offers the bootstrap tests provided by Kilian (1999) and Kilian and Taylor (2003) given the modified ESTAR dynamics of real exchange rates. The size and power analysis of the bootstrap tests are given in Section 5. Section 6 concludes our discussion.

Section snippets

The Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson effect

The classical model of the HBS effect implies that the relative price of non-tradable goods in terms of tradable goods (or real exchange rates) is determined entirely by the production technology. The HBS effect relies on the following four assumptions. First, there are two symmetric countries in the world and each country has two, traded and non-traded, sectors. Both factor and final goods markets are perfectly competitive. Second, production takes place under constant returns to scale. Third,

The estimation of the ESTAR model

To combine the HBS effect and the non-linear ESTAR dynamics of real exchange rates into a model, we specify an ESTAR model with a non-constant equilibrium for the real exchange rate. Let st, pt, and pt be the logarithm of the spot nominal exchange rates (US dollar per foreign currency), domestic (US) and foreign consumer price indices, respectively, and let ftptpt denote the PPP fundamental. The real exchange rate is defined as the deviation of the nominal exchange rate from relative prices

The bootstrap tests of long-horizon predictability

Given the fact that our model fits the data well, we evaluate the predictive accuracy of the long-horizon regression equation relative to a random walk model. The long-horizon regression equation is described as follows:st+kst=αk+βk(ztgˆt)+ɛt+k,k=1,4,8,12,16,where gˆt is the estimate of gt. The specification in Eq. (2) is different from the conventional long-horizon regression equation in which zt instead of ztgˆt is used. The reason for using a trend adjusted series (ztgˆt) is that the

Size and power of bootstrap tests

Since our bootstrap tests reject the random walk forecast model across forecast horizons, especially for an extended sample, we are interested in whether these are reliable tests. A test is said to be unreliable if its effective size exceeds its nominal size. Following the strategy provided by Kilian and Taylor (2003), we impose the hypothesis that nominal exchange rate changes are unpredictable and then postulate the following data-generating process for the representative country, GER, as

Conclusion

Although our knowledge on exchange rate behavior has improved during the past two decades, economists are still puzzled by the failure to beat random walk models in out-of-sample forecasting contests. Recently, a number of authors have suggested that the adjustment in the real exchange rate is in fact non-linear. Kilian and Taylor (2003) focus on PPP fundamentals and argue that an ESTAR model with a constant equilibrium is appropriate in describing real exchange rate dynamics over the period of

Acknowledgements

For helpful comments we appreciate James Lothian (the editor), an anonymous referee, Alan Taylor, Paul Bergin as well as participants in seminars at UC Davis and National Sun Yat-sen University. Part of the paper was finished while Wu was visiting at UC Davis where the Institute of Governmental Affairs and Department of Economics graciously provided him with superior research facilities. Wu is grateful for financial support from National Science Council in Taiwan.

References (63)

  • C. Engel

    Can the Markov switching model forecast exchange rates?

    Journal of International Economics

    (1994)
  • J.A. Frankel et al.

    Empirical research on nominal exchange rates

  • K. Froot et al.

    Perspectives on PPP and long-run real exchange rates

  • J.J. Groen

    The monetary exchange rate model as a long-run phenomenon

    Journal of International Economics

    (2000)
  • L. Kilian et al.

    Why is it so difficult to beat the random walk forecast of exchange rates?

    Journal of International Economics

    (2003)
  • J.R. Lothian et al.

    Purchasing power parity over two centuries: strengthening the case for real exchange rate stability: a reply to Cuddington and Liang

    Journal of International Money and Finance

    (2000)
  • J.R. Lothian

    A century plus of yen exchange rate behavior

    Japan and the World Economy

    (1990)
  • N.C. Mark et al.

    Nominal exchange rates and monetary fundamentals: evidence from a small post-Bretton Woods panel

    Journal of International Economics

    (2001)
  • R.A. Meese et al.

    Empirical exchange rate models of seventies: do they fit out-of-sample?

    Journal of International Economics

    (1983)
  • A. Siddique et al.

    Forecasting real exchange rates

    Journal of International Money and Finance

    (1998)
  • M.P. Taylor et al.

    Nonlinear adjustment, long-run equilibrium and exchange rate fundamentals

    Journal of International Money and Finance

    (2000)
  • D. Andrews

    Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimation

    Econometrica

    (1991)
  • P.K. Asea et al.

    A Balassa–Samuelson model: a general equilibrium appraisal

    Review of International Economics

    (1994)
  • P.K. Asea et al.

    The Balassa–Samuelson model: an overview

    Review of International Economics

    (1994)
  • B. Balassa

    The purchasing-power parity doctrine: a reappraisal

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1964)
  • R.B. Berben et al.

    Does the absence of cointegration explain the typical findings in long horizon regressions

    Report 9814

    (1998)
  • J. Berkowitz et al.

    Long-horizon exchange rate predictability?

    Reviews of Economics and Statistics

    (2001)
  • Y.W. Cheung et al.

    Exchange rates and Markov switching dynamics

    Journal of Business and Economic Statistics

    (2005)
  • T.E. Clark et al.

    Evaluating long-horizon forecasts

    Working Papers: 0302

    (2004)
  • R. Dacco et al.

    Why do regime-switching models forecast so badly?

    Journal of Forecasting

    (1999)
  • F.X. Diebold et al.

    Comparing predictive accuracy

    Journal of Business and Economic Statistics

    (1995)
  • Cited by (16)

    • Forecasting exchange rate: A bibliometric and content analysis

      2023, International Review of Economics and Finance
    • Revisiting the persistence of real exchange rates

      2020, Journal of International Money and Finance
      Citation Excerpt :

      Obstfeld (1993) developed a simple stochastic model in which real exchange rates contain a pronounced deterministic trend based on the idea of differential productivity growth in tradables and non-tradables. Several articles apply a linear trend model to take into account the BS effect (Taylor, 2002; Wu and Hu, 2009; Bergin et al., 2017).9 The lag order for each country in the sample is determined using the Akaike information criterion (AIC) with the maximum lag order being 8.

    • Forecasting the CNY-CNH pricing differential: The role of investor attention

      2018, Pacific Basin Finance Journal
      Citation Excerpt :

      The second group, named “macro attention”, consists of 45 macroeconomic terms. Although terms are subjectively chosen, the majority of which are suggested to have powerful explanatory ability or pervasive effects to exchange rate in previous literature, such as money supply, inflation, interest rate, etc. (Molodtsova and Papell, 2009; Wu and Hu, 2009; De Zwart et al., 2009; Balke et al., 2013; Ince, 2014; Bekiros, 2014). For the last group, since many studies demonstrate the relationship between stock prices and exchange rates (Phylaktis and Ravazzolo, 2005; Hau and Rey, 2006; Cumperayot et al., 2006), we are interested to find out if attention from stock market can also explain the movement of exchange rate.

    • Is there a homogeneous causality pattern between oil prices and currencies of oil importers and exporters?

      2013, Energy Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      However, the literature on the validity of PPP is not only extensive but controversial (see Sarno and Taylor (2003) for an overview). Considering recent empirical results, which have delivered evidence in favor of a nonlinear PPP adjustment of nominal and real exchange rates based on exponential smooth transition regression (ESTR) models (Kilian and Taylor, 2003; Taylor et al., 2001; Wu and Hu, 2009), a reasonable view would be that the price differential between two countries is important for the long-run path of the nominal exchange rate, although the relationship is not necessarily strictly proportional.5 Hence, oil price shocks might also introduce changes in nominal exchange rates in the long-run, which are not proportional to the price differential.

    • Nonlinear adjustment, purchasing power parity and the role of nominal exchange rates and prices

      2013, North American Journal of Economics and Finance
      Citation Excerpt :

      Kilian and Taylor (2003) apply the same model to quarterly data for Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Switzerland, Japan and the UK and report similar results. Wu and Hu (2009) provide further evidence of nonlinear real exchange rate dynamics by extending the analysis of Kilian and Taylor (2003) to include the Harrod/Balassa/Samuelson effect by allowing for deviations from purchasing power parity to return to an equilibrium trend. In the context of discrete threshold models, Nam (2011) has shown that the nominal exchange rate adjusts only outside a threshold band.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text