The value of making commitments externally: Evidence from WTO accessions

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2009.01.008Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper studies the value of external commitment to policy reforms in the case of WTO/GATT accessions. The accessions often entail reforms that go beyond narrowly defined trade liberalization, and have to overcome fierce resistance in the acceding countries, as reflected in protracted negotiations. We study the growth and investment consequences of WTO/GATT accessions, with attention to a possible selection bias. We find that the accessions tend to raise income, but only for those countries that were subject to rigorous accession procedures. Policy commitments associated with the accessions were helpful, especially for countries with poor governance.

Introduction

One way a country can acquire strong commitment to pro-growth policy reforms and convince investors that it has done so is by making the commitment a part of its international obligations. Examples of such external commitment include tariff reductions in a treaty that governs the terms of a country's accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO), foregoing the right to impose capital controls in the future in a free trade agreement (FTA), a privatization scheme made as a part of the conditionality in a World Bank loan, or a tax reform plan made as a part of the conditionality in an International Monetary Fund (IMF) supported program. The value of such an external commitment is intuitive. While a government's unilateral announcement or implementation of a policy reform can be reversed or undone unilaterally, a policy reform embedded in an international treaty would involve a much higher cost of reversal. Non-fulfillment of an external commitment could trigger termination of loan disbursement from the World Bank or the IMF, or sanctions from the dispute settlement mechanism at the WTO or the FTA. In political economy terms, the benefits conferred by the multilateral organization (e.g., more secured access to foreign markets through the WTO, or loans from the IMF) can be used by the reform-minded government to buy political support from the originally anti-reform interest groups.

However, it is not a foregone conclusion that the value of such external commitment is positive. For example, some have accused IMF supported programs of having made some countries economically worse off, as they might advocate a rigid recipe of policy changes that may not be suitable for the countries (see, for example, views by Feldstein, 1999, Stiglitz, 2002). A rigorous analysis by Barro and Lee (2005) that incorporates a clever strategy to model which countries receive IMF supported programs suggests that participation in IMF programs does not generally enhance a country's growth prospect and may have reduced it. So there is certainly room for the possibility of making external commitment to a wrong set of policies. This can be the case when the negotiating partners of the treaties do not necessarily have the country's best interest as their objective or simply misunderstand what is good for the country. Moreover, even if the commitments are good, there is a separate question of whether they can be enforced or sustained in the long run. In the case of IMF programs, the countries might reverse the prescribed reforms once the programs expire.

In this paper, we study the case of accessions to the WTO (or its predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, GATT). Unlike policy commitments made in an IMF program, policy reforms mandated in an WTO accession agreement are legally binding as long as the country remains a member of the WTO. The accessions are sometimes reported with fanfare, as was the case for China in 2001. In recent years, the applicant countries are typically required by existing members to undertake a wide range of policy changes before membership can be granted and to promise to do more within a certain timeframe after the start of membership. The required policy changes typically go beyond a reduction in tariff rates, and can encompass termination of state monopoly, greater transparency in policy making process generally, reduction in restrictions on payment and foreign exchange arrangement, and better protection of intellectual property rights.2 As the second quote at the beginning of the paper indicates, WTO accession is thought to make it less likely for governments to reverse market-oriented reforms. Many of these policy changes would have to overcome fierce resistance from anti-reform interest groups within the acceding countries. This is reflected in lengthy and often contentious negotiations between the acceding countries and the existing members. For example, for countries that acceded to the WTO during 1995–2001, the median time it took between the initial application and the final accession was 71 months. The view that WTO accession brings about pro-growth reforms even if they may be politically difficult can be summarized by a Chinese adage: beneficial medicine may be bitter in one's mouth.

This view, however, is not universally shared. Some think that the membership is completely irrelevant. For example, Rose (2004) reports that WTO/GATT member countries do not appear to trade any more than non-members do. As Subramanian and Wei (2007) point out, since most developing-country members of the GATT/WTO acceded to the trade body at a time when very few reforms were required of them, it is not difficult to understand the irrelevance results. If WTO membership does not even lead to a more open trade regime, then it is hard to see how it could deliver beneficial reforms in other ways. So, in this case, the medicine is neither bitter nor effective.

According to some, accession to the WTO may even mean making counterproductive external commitments. The policy changes demanded by existing members of the WTO/GATT might narrow the “policy space,” and force the acceding countries to choose inferior policies that they otherwise would not have chosen. In a book entitled, “Behind the Scenes at the WTO: the Real World of International Trade Negotiations,” the authors Fatoumata Jawara and Aileen Kwa suggested that WTO negotiations place the interests of powerful developed countries ahead of everyone else and often coerce developing countries into signing something that they profoundly disagree with. By this view, the medicine is not only bitter but also poisonous.

In the first four decades of the GATT, developing countries were not asked to do much reform if they wanted to join the club. Indeed, many of them retained very high bound tariff rates even after becoming GATT members. However, the Uruguay Round of the GATT negotiations signifies a drastic change. One objective of the Uruguay Round was to bridge the gap between the developed and developing countries in terms of their degree of liberalization and obligations. New acceding countries are subject to much more stringent accession requirements. For instance, under the old GATT rules, an existing member might be able to invoke nonapplication only on the condition that it had never entered bilateral negotiations with the acceding country; however, under the new WTO regime, an existing member could opt to not extend its WTO-related benefits to the new member even after they had held bilateral negotiations. For example, the United States had invoked the nonapplication clause against the Kyrgyz Republic, Mongolia, and Georgia, even after it had held bilateral negotiations with them. The United States would not have been allowed to exercise nonapplication in such a situation in the GATT era (Drabek and Bacchetta, 2004). Such threat of ex-post nonapplication potentially strengthens the leverage of existing members over an acceding country during the bilateral negotiations, and thus enable them to extract more concessions from the new member.

Subramanian and Wei (2007) document that these new (i.e., post-Uruguay) members tend to be systematically more open than old developing country members of the GATT. On average, new developing country members of the WTO/GATT trade about 30% more than the old developing members. Thus, accessions to the WTO/GATT after the Uruguay Round offer an opportunity to empirically study the value to a country of making policy commitments externally.

Specifically, in this paper we investigate whether and how WTO/GATT accession between 1990 and 2001 alters a country's growth trajectories. The empirical method we employ is in spirit a difference-in-differences strategy: comparing the change in the growth rate of the acceding countries before and after accessions with the change in the growth rate of nonacceding developing countries. Our results show that, relative to other developing countries, countries that became WTO members did generally grow faster than before, and the increments in their ratios of investment to GDP were greater as well.3

Any good economist would instinctively ask whether there is any endogeneity bias in this result. Specifically, is it possible that only countries that would pursue pro-growth, open-trade policies anyway would apply for GATT/WTO membership? Researchers might find a positive association between accession and an increase in the growth rate even though the former may not cause the latter. In some sense, we are just as happy with the possible result that reforms designed to promote trade openness rather than WTO accession per se have increased growth. In this scenario, application for GATT/WTO membership is simply a demonstration of a government's resolve to switch to a more open trade regime. Our exercise can be seen simply as a new angle to check the consequence of trade reforms for growth.

We, however, document a number of patterns in the data that enhance our confidence that the WTO commitments may causally improve investment climate and help to raise the growth rate. Besides implementing a Heckman procedure that explicitly models the selection issue, we also make use of a number of economic and institutional features of the WTO accession process that turn out to be informative. We summarize these features below.

  • 1.

    Accessions with and without extensive reforms. If accession involves no binding commitments, then the endogeneity bias is highly plausible. However, plenty of evidence shows that the accession negotiations can be very demanding on the acceding countries, often with anti-reform interest groups resisting strenuously the reform requirements from the existing members. The long accession negotiations (with an average of about five years) indicate the immense political difficulty many acceding countries have in implementing various reforms required of them. In fact, an interesting difference among the accession countries is informative about whether accession-related reforms have helped to change the domestic investment climate. Up to the end of 1994, a subset of developing countries were eligible to join the GATT under Article XXVI 5(c) by essentially sending a notification to the GATT without having to promise reforms. Existing members could not block the accession and therefore could not impose demands that the acceding countries would feel reluctant to fulfill. In contrast, the rest of the developing countries would have to undergo rigorous negotiations with existing members because any of the latter countries could block the accession. Almost all Article XXVI 5(c)-eligible countries joined the GATT by 1994 without making extensive reform commitments. We will show that the positive impact of WTO/GATT accession comes entirely from countries that were required to undergo more rigorous accession negotiations.

  • 2.

    Application vs. actual accession. It is possible that an application for membership may signal that the government has become reform-minded and may pursue pro-growth reforms regardless of the membership. Because a long and variable lag typically exists between the date of application and that of the eventual accession, we can exploit this gap to isolate the effect of accession-induced reforms from the effect of reforms that a government wants to implement anyway. We find that there is a (temporary) pickup in the growth rate subsequent to the initial application. However, even after accounting for this pattern, we continue to find a distinct growth spurt after the actual accession.

  • 3.

    Modeling the selection effect. We also explicitly test for and quantify the effects of self-selection on economic performance by employing a two-stage procedure a la Heckman (1979). We do not find evidence of a strong selection bias that drives our result.

  • 4.

    Effects of reform commitments on countries of different governance quality. If accession has no additional economic impact beyond signaling a government's resolve to pursue reforms unilaterally, then the association of accession with growth does not have to vary with the quality of public governance. We look at whether and how accession-induced policy reforms have differential impacts on countries of different governance quality. We find that the policy commitments through WTO accession appear to be more beneficial in countries with weak governance. This suggests that the external policy commitments may serve as a (partial) substitute for governance in promoting economic development.

These four features are based on economic as well as statistical arguments. Taken together, they suggest that WTO/GATT accessions, when rigorous reforms are required of, have led countries to engage in a wide range of reforms, improve the general investment climate beyond narrowly defined trade areas, resulting in an acceleration of their growth rates around the time of the accession.

Note that the accession may lead only to a one-off increase in the income level (though with a transition period of several years), not necessarily to a permanent increase in the growth rate. Of course, a temporary increase in growth rates for a few years implies a permanently larger economy and a permanently higher living standard in the end. So it is still economically significant. In any case, given that WTO accession cases are relatively recent, available data would not allow us to discriminate between a growth effect and a level effect that spreads over several years.

Besides studying the value of commitments, this paper contributes to the literature on the effects of the WTO/GATT. Rose (2004), Subramanian and Wei (2007), and Goldstein, Rivers and Tomz (2007), among others, study the trade volume effects of the WTO (with different conclusions). Li and Wu (2004) explore the average effects of WTO/GATT accessions on growth during 1960 and 1998, but do not take into account the qualitative change in the nature of the accession process since the Uruguay Round, the role of Article XXVI 5(c), and the difference between applications and actual accessions. Ferrantino (2006) examine association between the accessions (and free trade agreements) and governance.

In the following section, we briefly describe the data and our empirical methodology before presenting our results. We discuss the selection issue in greater detail in section 3. Section 4 explores the role of policy commitments as a substitute for good governance. We conclude in Section 5.

Section snippets

Data and empirical specifications

The main variables employed in our regressions include per capita GDP, private investment, total investment, exports and imports of all the developing countries between 1981 and 2003. All these data, at annual frequency, are obtained from the IMF's World Economic Outlook. The panels are not always balanced, since some smaller countries might not have data for earlier years. The years the countries formally acceded to WTO/GATT are taken from WTO's website. We exclude all OPEC and industrial

The selection issue and other robustness checks

One might cast doubt on the exogeneity of accessions. In particular, do our results for the non-Article XXVI 5(c) countries simply reflect the possibility that countries more likely to experience stronger future growth anyway self-select to accede to WTO/GATT? In this section, we tackle this issue with economic as well as statistical arguments.

Is external commitment a partial substitute for better governance?

Poor public governance including corruption and deviation from rule of law appears to inhibit economic development in many countries. We now examine the interactions between policy commitments made under WTO accessions and the quality of a country's public governance. Ex ante, there are two opposing possibilities. The first hypothesis posits that poor-governance countries benefit more from the external commitment. These countries are least likely to enact and carry through reforms unilaterally.

Conclusions

Using WTO accessions as a case study, this paper investigates the value of making policy reform commitments externally. Some developing countries were eligible to obtain membership without serious reforms; most others would have to undertake wide-ranging policy changes that go beyond narrowly defined trade areas, including competition policy, price controls, investment policy, privatization plans, and transparency requirement.

Our empirical results show that WTO/GATT accessions are often

References (22)

  • BarroRobert et al.

    IMF programs: who is chosen and what are the effects?

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2005)
  • SubramanianArvind et al.

    The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly

    Journal of International Economics

    (2007)
  • WooldridgeJeffrey

    Selection corrections for panel data models under conditional mean independence assumptions

    Journal of Econometrics

    (1995)
  • BagwellKyle et al.

    An economic theory of GATT

    American Economic Review

    (1999)
  • BeraAnil K. et al.

    Testing the normality assumption in limited dependent variable models

    International Economic Review

    (1984)
  • DrabekZdenek

    The stability of trade policy in the countries in transition and their integration in the multilateral trading system

    World Economy

    (1996)
  • DrabekZdenek et al.

    Tracing the effects of WTO accession on policy-making in sovereign states: preliminary lessons from the recent experience of transition countries

    World Economy

    (2004)
  • DrukkerDavid

    Testing for serial correlation in linear panel-data models

    The Stata Journal

    (2003)
  • FeldsteinMartin

    A self-help guide for emerging markets

    Foreign Affairs

    (1999)
  • Ferrantino, Michael, 2006. “Policy Anchors: Do Free Trade Agreements Serve as Vehicles for Developing Country Policy...
  • GoldsteinJudith et al.

    Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? Comment

    American Economic Review

    (2007)
  • Cited by (73)

    • Trade reforms and current account imbalances

      2021, Journal of International Economics
    • The WTO is not passé

      2020, European Economic Review
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    A longer version by the same title is available as an NBER working paper. We would like to thank Yuanyuan Chen, Tubagus Feridhanusetyawan, Will Martin, Phil McCalman, Sara Maioli, Ilia Rainer, Arvind Subramanian, Zhiwei Zhang, seminar and conference participants at the IMF, WTO, UNCTAD, ERWIT and EIIE, and especially Zdenek Drabek, Nuno Limao, Anna Maria Mayda, Andy Rose, and two referees for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.

    View full text