Willingness to pay for green electricity: A review of the contingent valuation literature and its sources of error

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2016.08.054Get rights and content

Abstract

Contingent valuation is widely used due to its flexibility in valuing a wide variety of non-market goods. Although this method has important benefits, its validity and reliability are often criticised. This paper reviews the literature on the use of contingent valuation for measuring willingness to pay (WTP) for electricity generated from renewable energy sources (green electricity). A literature review, conducted on a sample of 57 peer-reviewed studies, shows that the vast majority of contingent evaluation studies stems from developed economies. Furthermore, most frequently used WTP elicitation techniques are open-ended and dichotomous choice approaches, which tend to produce varying levels of WTP. Studies dealing with the antecedents of WTP are predominantly inspired by the theory of reasoned action or by its extension, the theory of planned behaviour. This paper identifies six common errors in contingent valuation methods and discusses a number of remedies to deal with these errors in WTP research.

Introduction

This paper provides the results of a literature review of the frequently used contingent valuation method and its sources of error in the context of willingness to pay (WTP) for green electricity. There is an increasing number of studies that focus on people's WTP for certain (public) goods in general and for “green” goods in particular. For example, between 2000 and 2014,1 the number of studies with “willingness to pay” in the title increased by about 290%. A large proportion of WTP studies used the so-called contingent valuation method to determine certain economic characteristics of the goods or services under study. Sundt and Rehdanz [1], for instance, reported that almost two-third applied this valuation method in a sample of studies published between 2000 and 2011.

The contingent valuation (CV) method estimates standard economic values such as willingness to accept or to pay using responses to survey questions. The contingent valuation method is part of a wider family of approaches labelled as stated preference methods. The latter methods build on actors' responses to questions about changes in the quality of goods. Because a researcher designed the questions about the characteristics of the goods, the changes investigated are often hypothetical. At the end of WW II, the CV method started its development, when it was proposed to use surveys as a tool to value social goods. Early empirical applications can be found in the valuation of outdoor recreation and cost-benefit analyses of public water infrastructures. In the early seventies, the CV method was applied outside the environmental field, especially in the health care and transportation sector. A major boost for the CV method was the Exxon Valdez oil spill. The state of Alaska's damage claim was to a large extent informed by the loss of so-called passive use value. The use of this latter value for determining the size of environmental damages was heavily debated by the oil industry. This led to the organization of a panel initiated by the U.S. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) co-chaired by two Nobel-prize winners. The panel listed a set of good practices for CV and concluded that passive use values can be used.

The contingent valuation method attracted lively academic debate between opponents and proponents. Its proponents argued that the contingent valuation method had three distinct advantages [2]: (1) with the CV method, one can collect useful information in cases where consumer information was not collected; (2) the application of the CV method allows for the development of scenarios in which (re)new(ed) goods are presented that are outside the realm of current user experiences, and (3) the CV method makes it possible to use the Hicksian consumer surplus instead of its Marshallian proxy. In contrast, some opposing scholars [3] argued that the contingent valuation method developed from “dubious to hopeless”. They conclude (also see: [4]) that the contingent valuation method has a number of serious problems, making “the resulting data useless for serious analysis” [3]: pp.43. In this debate, the focus is predominantly on three problems. The first is hypothetical bias, where what people say is different to what they do. Consequently, WTP values are often (very) different from what is called the “true” economic price. The second problem is the gap between what actors are willing to pay and what they are willing to accept. It is argued that economic theory predicts that both values should be the same. Because many empirical studies find differing values, this is regarded as a serious flaw of the contingent valuation method. The third problem is the scope or embeddedness problem, which implies that WTP values for the same goods vary depending on whether the goods are valued separately or as a part of a more inclusive package.

This paper reviews the contingent valuation literature dealing with WTP for green electricity by sampling a number of studies, showing that the contingent valuation method is plagued by a wider range of errors than merely the three identified above. These errors are identified and described and, where appropriate and possible, remedies are suggested. In this review, the focus is especially on elicitation techniques. These are an understudied potential source of error on the one hand, while they have high practical relevance on the other, as they are the actual means whereby WTP data is collected, thus informing policy makers and practitioners. Furthermore, the paper investigates what the contingent valuation literature regards as the main antecedents that influence WTP for green electricity. In this study, antecedents of WTP are defined as factors affecting a person's WTP for green electricity. In an abstract sense, an antecedent can be regarded as a cause of a phenomenon, in this paper an individual's willingness to pay. Combined, it provides the opportunity to reach the three main objectives of this paper. These objectives are to provide a state-of-the-art review of contingent valuation literature and an overview of the possible errors in contingent valuation studies, which result in varying WTP estimates together with their remedies. It also wishes to provide an overview of antecedents of WTP in contingent valuation studies, which helps one explore to what extent a general theoretical framework can be traced in these studies. More broadly, the researchers concur with Haab, Interis, Petrolia and Whitehead [5]: pp. 608, who stated: “The time has come to move beyond endless debates that seek to discredit contingent valuation and to focus instead on making it better.” This statement voices the overall aim of this study.

This paper builds on and extends the work of other scholars who have assessed the contingent valuation method. In this regard, one can refer to studies by Diamond and Hausman [6], Hanemann [7], Carson, Flores and Meade [8] and Carson [9]. These studies are updated with the latest insights from literature, adding a special focus on elicitation issues. The results of this review of contingent valuation literature can be relevant to scholars and practitioners interested in WTP for green electricity, applying the contingent valuation method, as it helps them to quickly identify major caveats and ways to avoid or mitigate them.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: Section 2 briefly discusses a definition of green electricity and why it is an interesting good from an economic theory point of view. Furthermore, this section introduces the main methods used to economically value environmental (public) goods. Next, contingent valuation literature is reviewed and a number of its characteristics identified. Additionally, we explore those antecedents are that are often used to explain or predict WTP values that are grounded in the contingent valuation approach. Section 4 discusses important errors of contingent valuation methods, as identified in the literature, and possible ways to avoid or mitigate them. In the last section of the paper, the main findings are briefly summarised and discussed.

Section snippets

Green electricity and willingness to pay: definitions

From an economic theory point of view, green electricity is an interesting case because it is a so-called impure public good [10]. Impure public goods are characterised by the joint production of a private good and an environmental public good, the latter being a good that is non-rival and non-excludable. In the case of green electricity, the private good is the individual consumption of electricity. The public good is the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions, from which other consumers cannot

General characteristics of the contingent valuation literature on WTP for green electricity

Given the prominence of the contingent valuation method, this section explores the academic contingent valuation literature with regard to WTP for green electricity. This literature search was conducted using Google Scholar, Science Direct, Swetwise and Proquest as search engines. Key words used were (combinations of) “willingness to pay”, “green electricity”, “renewable energy” and “sustainable energy”. Studies had to be published in academic journals and should focus on WTP for (types of)

Possible errors in the contingent valuation method and their proposed solutions

One of the most important sources of error in the contingent valuation method is the embedding or scope effect (Table 3). Although definitions of this effect differ, scholars agree on the fact that the scope effect can cause serious validity problems, because it is not clear which WTP value to select when comparing WTP for one or a combination of (energy) options. The majority of studies on the scope effect consider comparison of private goods, but several researchers maintain that it also

Conclusions and future study

The contingent valuation method is widely used in valuing public goods, such as green electricity. Recently, there have been more published studies of estimating WTP value for green electricity using the CV method, despite its criticism of errors due to various elicitation techniques. This paper provides a review of the CV literature published in the area of WTP for electricity generated from renewable sources with the aim of exploring the antecedents of WTP, the different elicitation

References (123)

  • M.C. Claudy et al.

    The diffusion of microgeneration technologies - assessing the influence of perceived product characteristics on home owners’ willingness to pay

    Energy Policy

    (2011)
  • K. Arkesteijn et al.

    The early adoption of green power by Dutch households an empirical exploration of factors influencing the early adoption of green electricity for domestic purposes

    Energy Policy

    (2005)
  • D. Hite et al.

    Consumer willingness-to-pay for biopower: results from focus groups

    Biomass Bioenergy

    (2008)
  • J. Kim et al.

    Assessment of Korean customers’ willingness to pay with RPS

    Renew Sustain Energy Rev

    (2012)
  • H. Oliver et al.

    Residential consumers in the Cape Peninsula's willingness to pay for premium priced green electricity

    Energy Policy

    (2011)
  • S. Abdullah et al.

    Willingness to pay for renewable energy: evidence from a contingent valuation survey in Kenya

    Renew Sustain Energy Rev

    (2011)
  • B. Roe et al.

    US consumers’ willingness to pay for green electricity

    Energy Policy

    (2001)
  • J. Ladenburg et al.

    Willingness to pay for reduced visual disamenities from offshore wind farms in Denmark

    Energy Policy

    (2007)
  • R. Scarpa et al.

    Willingness-to-pay for renewable energy: primary and discretionary choice of British households’ for micro-generation technologies

    Energy Econ

    (2010)
  • P. Mozumder et al.

    Consumers’ preference for renewable energy in the southwest USA

    Energy Econ

    (2011)
  • F.J. Amador et al.

    Supplier choice and WTP for electricity attributes in an emerging market: the role of perceived past experience, environmental concern and energy saving behavior

    Energy Econ

    (2013)
  • M. Soliño et al.

    The influence of home-site factors on residents’ willingness to pay: an application for power generation from scrubland in Galicia, Spain

    Energy Policy

    (2009)
  • A. Gracia et al.

    Can renewable energy be financed with higher electricity prices? Evidence from a Spanish region

    Energy Policy

    (2012)
  • D. MacMillan et al.

    Contingent valuation: environmental polling or preference engine?

    Ecol Econ

    (2006)
  • A. Kontogianni et al.

    Renewables portfolio, individual preferences and social values towards RES technologies

    Energy Policy

    (2013)
  • W. Liu et al.

    Rural public acceptance of renewable energy deployment: the case of Shandong in China

    Appl Energy

    (2013)
  • L. Dagher et al.

    Willingness to pay for green power in an unreliable electricity sector: Part 1. The case of the Lebanese residential sector

    Renew Sustain Energy Rev

    (2015)
  • J. Zarnikau

    Consumer demand for “green power” and energy efficiency

    Energy Policy

    (2003)
  • L. Zhang et al.

    Market segmentation and willingness to pay for green electricity among urban residents in China: the case of Jiangsu Province

    Energy Policy

    (2012)
  • A. Longo et al.

    The internalization of externalities in the production of electricity: willingness to pay for the attributes of a policy for renewable energy

    Ecol Econ

    (2008)
  • P. Koundouri et al.

    Valuing a wind farm construction: a contingent valuation study in Greece

    Energy Policy

    (2009)
  • K. Murakami et al.

    Consumers’ willingness to pay for alternative fuel vehicles: a comparative discrete choice analysis between the US and Japan

    Energy Econ

    (2015)
  • I. Ajzen

    The theory of planned behavior

    Orgnizational Behav Hum Decis Process

    (1991)
  • D. Kahneman et al.

    Valuing public goods: the purchase of moral satisfaction

    J Environ Econ Manag

    (1992)
  • G.C. Blomquist et al.

    Resource quality information and validity of willingness to pay in contingent valuation

    Resour Energy Econ

    (1998)
  • M.P. Welsh et al.

    Elicitation effects in contingent valuation: comparisons to a multiple bounded discrete choice approach

    J Environ Econ Manag

    (1998)
  • C.D. Throsby et al.

    Strategic bias and demand for public goods: theory and an application to the arts

    J Public Econ

    (1986)
  • Y.-L. Chien et al.

    A general model of starting point bias in double-bounded dichotomous contingent valuation surveys

    J Environ Econ Manag

    (2005)
  • J.-J. Soon et al.

    Willingly or grudgingly? A meta-analysis on the willingness-to-pay for renewable energy use

    Renew Sustain Energy Rev

    (2015)
  • V.G. Morwitz et al.

    When do purchase intentions predict sales?

    Int J Forecast

    (2007)
  • N. Jacquemet et al.

    Preference elicitation under oath

    J Environ Econ Manag

    (2013)
  • Carson RT, Hanemann WM. Chapter 17 Contingent Valuation. Handb Environ Econ; 2005. 2. p....
  • Hausman J. Contingent valuation : from dubious to hopeless; 2012. 26,...
  • C.L. Kling et al.

    From Exxon to BP: has some number become better than no number?

    J Econ Perspect

    (2012)
  • T.C. Haab et al.

    From hopeless to curious? Thoughts on hausman's “dubious to hopeless” critique of contingent valuation

    Appl Econ Perspect Policy

    (2013)
  • P. Diamond et al.

    Contingent valuation: is some number better than no number?

    J Econ Perspect

    (1994)
  • W.M. Hanemann

    Valuing the environment through contingent valuation

    J Econ Perspect

    (1994)
  • R.T. Carson et al.

    Contingent valuation: controversies and evidence

    Environ Resour Econ

    (2001)
  • R.T. Carson

    Contingent valuation: a practical alternative when prices aren’t available

    J Econ Perspect

    (2012)
  • M.J. Kotchen

    Green markets and private provision of public goods

    J Polit Econ

    (2006)
  • Cited by (101)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text