Skip to main content
Log in

Incorporating under European Law: The Societas Europaea as a Vehicle for Legal Arbitrage

  • Articles
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

After a slow start, the European Company (Societas Europaea — SE) has become increasingly popular. Besides documenting the growth of this new company type, we examine whether firms choose to incorporate in the SE corporate form because they engage in ‘legal arbitrage’ by exploiting differences in legal rules between jurisdictions. We specify a number of hypotheses on particular legal arbitrage motives. To validate our hypotheses, we use a broad telephone survey among SE users in Germany as well as a simple country-level regression model based on a unique, hand-collected dataset on SE incorporations. We find strong evidence that firms use the SE to mitigate the effect of mandatory co-determination rules. Establishing a one-tier board structure (in jurisdictions that impose a two-tier structure on their national public companies) and taking advantage of the SE’s mobility for tax purposes also seem to be driving SE formations. By contrast, our analysis fails to support the suggestion that firms use the SE to shop for the most favourable national company law to fill the gaps in the SE Regulation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. See infra sections 4.1. and 5.1.1.

  2. By transferring the registered office to another Member State, the SE can also be used to shop for the most favourable gap-filling company law, see infra our hypothesis H3.2 in section 3.

  3. L. Enriques, ‘Silence is Golden: The European Company Statute As a Catalyst for Company Law Arbitrage’, 4 Journal of Corporate Law Studies (2004) p. 77, at pp. 77–80; J. Reichert, ‘Experience with the SE in Germany’, 4 Utrecht Law Review (2008) p. 22, at pp. 24–31.

    Google Scholar 

  4. J. McCahery and E. Vermeulen, ‘Does the European Company Prevent the “Delaware Effect”?’, 11 European Law Journal (2005) p. 785, at p. 799; W. Bratton, J. McCahery and E. Vermeulen, How Does Corporate Mobility Affect Lawmaking? A Comparative Analysis, Law Working Paper No. 91 (European Corporate Governance Institute 2008) p. 15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. See infra section 4.2.

  6. Note that legal arbitrage is not sufficient for charter competition (see Enriques, supra n. 3, at p. 78, n. 11): despite arbitrage activity, jurisdictions can still choose not to compete, e. g., because they lack incentives to attract incorporators or due to interest group pressure. Moreover, while ‘legal arbitrage’ is sometimes employed in a pejorative sense, we use it as a purely descriptive term.

  7. W. Cary, ‘Federalism and Corporate Law: Reflections upon Delaware’, 83 Yale Law Journal (1974) p. 663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. R. Winter, ‘State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation’, 6 Journal of Legal Studies (1977) p. 251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. W. Bratton, ‘Corporate Law’s Race to Nowhere in Particular’, 44 University of Toronto Law Journal (1994) p. 401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. M. Klausner, ‘Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts’, 81 Virginia Law Review (1995) p. 757, at pp. 843–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. See R. Romano, The Genius of American Corporate Law (Washington, AEI Press 1993) p. 20 (citing event studies); R. Daines, ‘Does Delaware Law Improve Firm Value?’, 62 Journal of Financial Economics (2001) p. 525 (using a different methodology); but see G. Subramanian, ‘The Disappearing Delaware Effect’, 20 Journal of Law Economics & Organization (2004) p. 32.

    Google Scholar 

  12. L.A. Bebchuk and A. Cohen, ‘Firms’ Decisions Where to Incorporate’, 46 Jourmal of Law & Economics (2003) p. 383, at pp. 411–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. See McCahery and Vermeulen, supra n. 4, at pp. 787–788.

  14. W. Carney, ‘The Political Economy of Competition for Corporate Charters’, 27 Journal of Legal Studies (1997) p. 303, at p. 311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. L. Enriques, ‘EC Company Law and the Fears of a European Delaware’, 15 European Business Organization Law Review (EBOR) (2004) p. 1259, at pp. 1260–1261.

    Google Scholar 

  16. H. Eidenmüller, ‘Die GmbH im Wettbewerb der Rechtsformen’, 36 Zeitschrift für Unternehmens- und Gesellschaftsrecht (ZGR) (2007) p. 168.

    Google Scholar 

  17. T. Tröger, ‘Choice of Jurisdiction in European Corporate Law — Perspectives of European Corporate Governance’, 6 EBOR (2005) p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  18. M. Becht, C. Mayer and H. Wagner, ‘Where Do Firms Incorporate’, 14 Journal of Corporate Finance (2008) p. 241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. See, e. g., W. Niemeier, ‘Die “Mini-GmbH” (UG) trotz Marktwende bei der Limited?’, 38 Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht (2007) p. 1794; Eidenmüller, supra n. 16.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Enriques, supra n. 3, at pp. 81–83; Reichert, supra n. 3, at p. 25.

  21. See Reichert, supra n. 3, at pp. 24–31.

  22. See Bratton, McCahery and Vermeulen, supra n. 4, at p. 2.

  23. W. Bayer and J. Schmidt, ‘“Going European” continues — die Zahl der SE steigt weiter’, 53 Die Aktiengesellschaft (AG) (2008) p. R31, at p. R32; H. Eidenmüller, A. Engert and L. Hornuf, ‘Die Societas Europaea: Empirische Bestandsaufnahme und Entwicklungslinien einer neuen Rechtsform’, 53 AG (2008) p. 721, at pp. 724–725.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See http://www.worker-participation.eu.

  25. B. Keller and F. Werner, ‘Arbeitnehmerbeteiligung in der Europäischen Aktiengesellschaft (SE) — Eine empirische Analyse der ersten Fälle’, 60 WSI-Mitteilungen (2007) p. 604; B. Keller and F. Werner, ‘The Establishment of the European Company: The First Cases from an Industrial Relations Perspective’, 14 European Journal of Industrial Relations (2008) p. 153.

    Google Scholar 

  26. We define ‘incorporation costs’ as the expenses, delay, risk and loss in flexibility incurred for setting up a company. A minimum capital requirement imposes incorporation costs in the sense that it restricts the company’s flexibility. Of course, the amount of the minimum capital as such does not constitute a cost as it can be invested by the company.

  27. See S. Djankov, et al., ‘The regulation of entry’, 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics (2002) p. 1 (providing evidence that a higher regulatory burden on firm entry results from rentseeking by politicians and bureaucrats rather than from an attempt to remedy market failures).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. In the case of Allianz SE it should be noted that the conversion was consummated as part of a major cross-border merger, which would always entail considerable transaction costs.

  29. See Becht, Mayer and Wagner, supra n. 18, at pp. 250–255.

  30. Of course, incorporation costs can be reduced by registering the SE in another (low-cost) Member State. However, this would require (re)locating the company’s head office in the state of incorporation, see SE Regulation, Arts. 7 and 64. Also, an existing company cannot be merged into an SE without the involvement (and hence the regulatory cost burden) of its home state, cf., SE Regulation, Art. 25. If the company is converted into an SE under SE Regulation, Arts. 2(4) and 37, it cannot, at the same instance, transfer its registered office to another Member State, SE Regulation, Art. 37(3). For all of these reasons, we only consider domestic SEs as an alternative to domestic national companies.

  31. Council Directive 2001/86/EC supplementing the Statute for a European company with regard to the involvement of employees.

  32. This follows from the SE Employee Involvement Directive, Art. 13(2), which precludes the general Member State rules on employee representation at board level.

  33. D. Charny, ‘Competition among Jurisdictions in Formulating Corporate Law Rules: An American Perspective on the “Race to the Bottom” in the European Communities’, 32 Harvard International Law Journal (1991) p. 423, at p. 454.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Furthermore, companies using the legal form of the SE should tend to have less stringent co-determination rules than comparable national corporations.

  35. W.-G. Ringe, ‘The European Company Statute in the Context of Freedom of Establishment’, 7 Journal of Corporate Law Studies (2007) p. 185, at p. 211.

    Google Scholar 

  36. The home state can prevent its companies from shifting their head office abroad, see ECJ, Case C-210/06 Cartesio Oktató és Szolgáltató bt [2008].

  37. Cf., Art. 4(3) of the OECD Model Convention with Respect to Taxes on Income and Capital (as it reads on 15 July 2005).

  38. For instance, German companies still run a considerable risk of forced dissolution when shifting their head offices abroad. The issue is being addressed by § 4a GmbHG, § 5a AktG as amended by the 2008 Act to Modernise Private Company Law and to Combat Abuses (Gesetz zur Modernisierung des GmbH-Rechts und zur Bekämpfung von Missbräuchen — MoMiG). On the European level, Art. 3(1), sentence 2 of Council Regulation (EC) No. 1346/2000 on insolvency proceedings establishes a presumption that the centre of a (company) debtor’s main interests coincides with its registered office.

  39. See Bratton, McCahery and Vermeulen, supra n. 4, at p. 15; Enriques, supra n. 3, at p. 79.

  40. Cf., the general reference in SE Regulation, Art. 9(1)(c)(ii).

  41. P. Hemeling, Die Societas Europaea (SE) in der praktischen Anwendung, Zentrum für Europäisches Wirtschaftsrecht, Vorträge und Berichte No. 168 (Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität Bonn 2008) p. 3.

  42. See generally P. Swann, Putting Econometrics in Its Place — A New Direction in Applied Economics (Cheltenham, Edward Elgar 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  43. An up-to-date overview of SEs is maintained by the European Trade Union Institute and the Hans Böckler Foundation, see supra n. 24.

  44. See Bayer and Schmidt, supra n. 23, at p. R31.

  45. The recent Commission proposal for a Council Regulation on the Statute for a European Private Company provides for such a requirement, see COM (2008) 396 final, Art. 46(1).

  46. The sample represents 74 percent of active (i. e., non-shelf.) SEs in Germany.

  47. We define a ‘shelf company’ as a company which is to be sold to a firm or entrepreneur and which does not yet carry out any business activity. Companies that are used as a vehicle for holding assets, such as investment companies, are considered ‘active’, not ‘shelf.’ companies.

  48. This is in line with the reasoning behind our Hypothesis 3.1 that firms choose the SE corporate form with a view to moving to another Member State later on.

  49. The OECD defines a firm (‘enterprise’) as ‘a legal entity possessing the right to conduct business on its own; for example to enter into contracts, own property, incur liabilities for debts, and establish bank accounts. It may consist of one or more local units or establishments corresponding to production units situated in a geographically separate place and in which one or more persons work for the enterprise to which they belong.’

  50. As the first incorporations occurred already in the year 2004 and the year 2008 has not ended yet, we tried different intervals without obtaining a significant impact on the results.

  51. World Bank, Doing Business (Washington, July 2008), available at http://www.doingbusiness.org.

  52. For the definition of the ‘standardised company’ see Djankov, et al., supra n. 27, at p. 7. The minimum capital requirement was included as one of several proxies for the regulatory burden. The SE uniformly requires a minimum capital of €120,000 (SE Regulation, Art. 4(2)).

  53. N. Kluge and M. Stollt, The European Company — Prospects for Worker Board-Level Participation in the Enlarged EU (Brussels, February 2006), available at http://www.seeurope-network.org, at pp. 64–65.

  54. European Commission, Directorate General Taxation and Customs Union, Structures of the Taxation Systems in the European Union (Brussels, 2006).

  55. KPMG International, KPMG’s Corporate and Indirect Tax Rate Survey 2008 (October 2006).

  56. See Kluge and Stollt, supra n. 53, at pp. 64–65.

  57. See http://www.eurospolecnosti.cz, http://www.czechcompanies.cz/en and http://www.smartcompanies.cz.

  58. Two of the European Companies moved to Luxembourg only to reincorporate from there to the Cayman Islands, thus providing ‘smoking gun’ evidence of legal arbitrage. See on these cases, J. Heuschmid and C. Schmidt, ‘Die europäische Aktiengesellschaft — auf dem Weg in die Karibik? Eine rechtliche Würdigung der Sitzverlagerungen europäischer Aktiengesellschaften von Luxemburg auf die Cayman Islands’, 2 Neue Zeitschrift für Gesellschaftsrecht (2007) p. 54, and J. Schmidt, ‘“Offshore in drei Zügen” — Die Europäische Aktiengesellschaft (SE) als “Fähre” auf die Cayman Islands’, 41 Der Betrieb (2005) p. 2221.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Small enterprises are defined as having up to 9 employees and less than €1 million annual turnover, while medium-sized enterprises have 10 to 499 employees and €1 to 50 million annual turnover. See Definition 01/01/2002 at http://www.ifm-bonn.org/index.php?id=89 (last visited 15 October 2008).

  60. Cf., SE Regulation, Art. 2. An exception is provided for in Art. 3(2), under which an existing European Company can set up subsidiary SEs.

  61. One fairly well-known example is Adi Drotleff, who is both the CEO and controlling shareholder of the IT company Mensch und Maschine SE.

  62. Some European Companies in the United Kingdom have a supervisory board but only because they retained the two-tier structure after having moved to the United Kingdom. In no case did a European Company actively seek a two-tier board structure in a jurisdiction adhering exclusively to the one-tier structure.

  63. See also Keller and Werner, Arbeitnehmerbeteiligung, supra n. 25, at pp. 610–611.

  64. As compared to the size prescribed by the default rule of SE Employee Involvement Directive, Annex, Part 1, lit. e. the Representative Body is the SE equivalent of the European Works Council established by Council Directive 94/45/EC, cf., SE Employee Involvement Directive, Art. 13(1).

  65. For details, see M. Rehberg, ‘Chancen und Risiken der Verhandlungen über die Arbeitnehmerbeteiligung’, in V. Rieble and A. Junker, eds., Vereinbarte Mitbestimmung in der SE (Munich, ZAAR Verlag 2008) p. 45, at p. 56.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Since the unobserved fraction of German SEs consists most likely of investment or shelf companies, we would rather expect to underestimate the importance of tax motives.

  67. We took the natural logarithms of the dependent variable rrse (number of SEs divided by total number of firms) and the two explanatory variables (gdp0508 and corptax), which are measured at the interval level, as this improved the distribution of these variables and helped us to deal with outliers. Since the sample size is already rather small and we are dealing with almost the entire population, we decided to take the data as it is and did not drop the two outliers Germany and the Czech Republic. If a country does not have a single SE, we cannot take the natural logarithm of zero. Instead, we insert a very small number (10-14). Choosing a number closer to the range of positive values of rrse (e. g., 10-8) does not affect the statistical significance of our results whereas an even smaller number would have worsened the distribution of the data. Because all country values of rrse are close to zero, their natural logarithm is negative. For this reason, the constant is not positive and should not receive an economic interpretation.

  68. When interpreting these results, one should keep in mind that we scale our dependent variable (the number of SEs) by the total number of firms. This control should already capture the impact of a country’s incorporation costs on firms generally.

  69. The idea behind the Eurobarometer variables is that the European image of the SE should be more attractive when public opinion is generally in favour of European integration.

  70. We use robust standard errors to account for residual heteroscedasticity.

  71. Supra n. 45.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Horst Eidenmüller LL.M..

Additional information

We would like to thank the 26 interview participants without whom this project would not have been possible. Furthermore, we are indebted to John Armour, Matthias Dischinger, Andreas Haufler, Tobias Tröger, Joachim Winter, Klaus Wohlrabe and participants in the Public Economics Seminar at the University of Munich, the Conference on Changing Perspectives on Corporate Law and Economics at the Erasmus University Rotterdam and the Conference on New Developments in Law and Economics at the University of Innsbruck

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eidenmüller, H., Engert, A. & Hornuf, L. Incorporating under European Law: The Societas Europaea as a Vehicle for Legal Arbitrage. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 10, 1–33 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1017/S1566752909000019

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/S1566752909000019

Keywords

Navigation