Skip to main content
Log in

Macroeconomic Policy in Argentina During 2002–2013

  • Symposium Article
  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze Argentina’s macroeconomic policy and performance between 2003 and 2013. The period began with a rapid recovery following the 2001–02 crisis. Recovery then turned into strong and sustained growth. By late 2011, despite a very favorable external context, Argentina entered a stagflationary trap. Facing a visible lack of foreign exchange, the authorities introduced and reinforced a series of controls, which did not prevent a currency crisis in late 2013 and early 2014. We argue that macroeconomic performance during the whole period was closely related to the way macroeconomic policy was conducted. More specifically, we claim that the shift from high growth to stagflation was due to a change in the approach to macroeconomic policy: from one aiming to preserve a stable and competitive real exchange rate and twin surpluses, to another one of populist orientation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7
Figure 8
Figure 9
Figure 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We follow the Latin American tradition of defining the exchange rate as the domestic price of a foreign currency. Consequently, a rise (fall) of both the nominal and the real exchange rate implies a nominal or real depreciation (appreciation).

  2. By ‘competitive’ RER we mean one that is above its equilibrium level. Equilibrium RER is a concept that generates no few confusions and debates. For simplicity, we define it here as the one at which the economy is at macroeconomic equilibrium (ie, full employment with low and non-accelerating inflation and external balance). Conceptually, a developing economy has a ‘competitive’ RER level when the modern (or non-traditional) tradable sector reaches a risk-adjusted profit rate that is at least equal to that of the same sector in a developed economy. See Rapetti (2013a) for further details.

  3. See Rodrik (2008), Razmi et al. (2012) and Rapetti et al. (2012), among others.

  4. See Polterovich and Popov and Polterovich (2002), Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2007) and Prasad et al. (2007).

  5. A debt restructuring was carried out between January and May 2005. About 76% of the defaulted debt involving 82 billion dollars was exchanged for new bonds. The debt swap implied a nominal haircut of 40% of Argentina’s GDP. See Damill et al. (2010) for an analysis and description of the debt restructuring process. A second debt swap occurred in 2010, in which another 17% accepted a similar offer to the one of 2005.

  6. The manipulation of the CPI affected the elaboration of other statistics, in particular real and nominal GDP and poverty and extreme poverty rates. In all figures and tables in this article that involve variables affected since January 2007, we use the CPI calculated by ECOLATINA, a private consultancy firm, and the real GDP estimated by ARKLEMS+LAND, a research center at the University of Buenos Aires.

  7. Canitrot (1975) is a seminal contribution to the study of macroeconomics populism. Dornbusch and Edwards (1991) and Bresser-Pereira and Dall’Acqua (1991) are other relevant contributions to this literature.

  8. A more comprehensive description and analysis of the measures taken during the emergency period can be found in Frenkel and Rapetti (2006).

  9. Table A1 in the Appendix summarizes the main modifications of the legal and institutional characteristics of central banking in Argentina between 2002 and 2013.

  10. Frenkel and Rapetti (2008) analyze in greater detail monetary and exchange rate policies during the 2002–2007 period.

  11. See Frenkel (2007) for the conditions for sterilized foreign interventions to be sustainable.

  12. In a managed-floating exchange rate regime there is no need to establish any specific relation between the monetary base and international reserves. However, since Argentina had lived more than a decade with a currency board demanding a stock of international reserves at least equal to the monetary base at the official exchange rate, the authorities believed that the decision of maintaining enough reserves to back the monetary base would generate confidence in the private sector and support their demand for money.

  13. We calculate the ex-ante real interest rate as the nominal interest rate in period t minus the yearly inflation rate between t−1 and t. We assume adaptive expectations because of the lack of a reliable measure of private sector’s expected inflation since the manipulation of official statistics.

  14. We keep assuming adaptive expectations and calculate Badlar U$ as the peso interest rate of time deposits of 1 million pesos or above in period t discounted by the variation of the nominal exchange rate between t−1 and t.

  15. See Frenkel (2008) and Rapetti (2013b) on the theoretical aspects of macroeconomic policy coordination in a SCRER regime.

References

  • Bresser-Pereira, LC and Dall’Acqua, F . 1991: Economic populism versus keynes: Reinterpreting budget deficit in Latin America. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 14 (1): 29–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canitrot, A . 1975: La experiencia populista de redistribución de ingresos. Desarrollo Económico 15 (59): 331–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damill, M, Frenkel, R and Rapetti, M . 2010: The Argentinian debt: History, default, and restructuring. In: Herman, B, Gaviria, JAO and Spiegel, S (eds). Overcoming Developing Country Debt Crises. Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, pp. 179–230.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, R and Edwards, S . 1991: The macroeconomics of populism in Latin America. University of Chicago Press: Chicago.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, R . 2007: The sustainability of monetary: Sterilization policies. Cepal Review 93: 29–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, R . 2008: The competitive real exchange-rate regime, inflation and monetary policy. Cepal Review 96: 191–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, R and Rapetti, M . 2006: Argentina’s monetary and exchange rate policies after the convertibility regime collapse. Political Economy Research Institute (PERI), University of Massachusetts: Amherst, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, R and Rapetti, M . 2008: Five years of competitive and stable real exchange rate in Argentina, 2002–2007. International Review of Applied Economics 22 (2): 215–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, R, Rapetti, M and Sigaut, L . 2015: Dinámica inflacionaria en Argentina 2002–2013. Centro de Estudio de Estado y Sociedad (CEDES) (mimeo). Buenos Aires, Argentina.

  • Guadagni, A . 2012: Presente y Futuro del Gas en la Argentina, economic and research forecasts. Econométrica: Buenos Aires.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P . 1979: A model of balance-of-payments crises. Journal of money, credit and banking 11 (3): 311–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy-Yeyati, E and Sturzenegger, F . 2007: Fear of floating in reverse: Exchange rate policy in the 2000s. unpublished. World Bank: Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, V and Polterovich, V . 2002: Accumulation of foreign exchange reserves and long term growth. New Economic School, Moscow, Russia, unpublished paper.

  • Prasad, E, Rajan, R and Subramanian, A . 2007: Foreign capital and economic growth. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1): 153–230.

  • Rapetti, M . 2013a: The real exchange rate and economic growth: Some observations on the possible channels. Working Paper 2013-11, Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts: Amherst.

  • Rapetti, M . 2013b: Macroeconomic policy coordination in a competitive real exchange rate strategy for development. Journal of Globalization and Development 3 (2): 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapetti, M, Skott, P and Razmi, A . 2012: The real exchange rate and economic growth: Are developing countries different? International Review of Applied Economics 26 (6): 735–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razmi, A, Rapetti, M and Skott, P . 2012: The real exchange rate and economic development. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 23 (2): 151–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redrado, M, Carrera, J, Bastourre, D and Ibarlucia, J . 2006: The economic policy of foreign reserve accumulation: New international evidence. Central Bank of Argentina, Economic Research Department: Buenos Aires, Argentina.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D . 2008: The real exchange rate and economic growth. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2): 365–412.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Ramiro Albrieu and Oscar Cetrángolo for their helpful comments and to Diego Friedheim for his assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Table A1

Table A1 Main legal and institutional characteristics of central banking in Argentina, selected periods

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Damill, M., Frenkel, R. & Rapetti, M. Macroeconomic Policy in Argentina During 2002–2013. Comp Econ Stud 57, 369–400 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2015.3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2015.3

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation