Skip to main content
Log in

Thinning and Thickening: Productive Sector Policies in The Era of Global Value Chains

  • Original Article
  • Published:
The European Journal of Development Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Effective insertion into global export markets offers the potential for sustainable income growth. However, inappropriate positioning in global markets may well lead to immiserising growth. The key to achieving the beneficial outcome lies in the capacity to identify, appropriate and protect rents, and in the context of intense global competition, to develop the capacity to master dynamic capabilities in order to generate rents on a sustainable basis. This rent policy agenda is necessarily contextual. We argue that the current temporal context is one in which an increasing share of global trade occurs within global value chains (GVCs), and that this is widely recognised. Less widely recognised (and we believe that this is the value added in this article) is the key sectorial distinction between vertically specialised GVCs and additive GVCs. These two families of GVCs require different corporate strategies and different forms of policy support. We refer to the two strategic agendas as ‘thinning’ (in the case of vertically specialised GVCs) and ‘thickening’ (in the case of additive GVCs). The additive GVCs tend to be relatively more important in low- and middle-income economies, particularly in Africa and Latin America and parts of South and East Asia. Critically, since effective policy support applies to the agricultural, resource, manufacturing and services sectors (and to the interconnections between them), we argue that ‘industrial policy’ is a misnomer, and instead we conceive of the policy agenda as one that addresses the ‘productive sector’.

Abstract

Pour récolter les bénéfices de la mondialisation, il faut la capacité d’identifier, de s’approprier et de protéger les loyers, et dans le contexte d’une concurrence mondiale intense, de développer la capacité à maîtriser les dynamiques afin de générer des loyers de façon durable. Cet ordre du jour politique des loyers est forcément contextuel. Le contexte temporel actuel est tel qu’une part croissante du commerce mondial se produit dans les chaînes de valeur mondiales (CVM). Au sein des secteurs, nous distinguons les CVM spécialisées verticalement et les CVM additives. Ces deux familles de chaînes de valeur mondiales exigent des stratégies d’entreprise et un soutien politique différents. Pour nous référer aux deux agendas stratégiques, nous utilisons les mots ‘éclaircissement ’ (dans le cas des chaînes de valeur mondiales spécialisées verticalement) et «épaississement » (dans le cas des chaînes de valeur mondiales additives). Les CVM additives ont tendance à être relativement plus importantes dans les pays à revenus faibles et moyens. Nous soutenons que «politique industrielle» est un terme impropre, et qu’à la place, nous estimons que l’ordre du jour politique se doit de traiter du ‘ secteur productif ’.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Schumpeter defined entrepreneurship as the commercial exploitation of inventions (Schumpeter, 1934). However, not all created rents are driven by the quest for profit, since many social actors apply knowledge-based inputs in order to achieve social objectives, for example, in socialised health-care and educational systems.

  2. For example, in the apparel sector, Nike outsources all production and operates as a buyer-driving governor, whereas Zara’s command over its chain arises from its competences in production and logistic organisation.

  3. For example, whereas Walmart and Tesco exert meta-governance in their fruit and vegetable GVCs, there is also a degree of countervailing producer-driven power by the firms governing logistics in these sectors.

  4. An important caveat needs to be made to this oft-cited example. This is that these numbers only reflect the first round of disaggregation. However, many of the inputs imported into China are themselves a product of vertically specialised sub-chains, so that the overall value added in China (and indeed in all the countries reflected in Figure 1) is likely to be rather different from those reported by Xing and Detert. Rather than undermining the analysis by Xing and Detert, this caveat reinforces their central observation of the fracturing of GVCs.

  5. For other examples of contrasting patterns of geographical dispersion in additive GVCs, see Kaplinsky and Morris (2014) and Morris and Fessehaie (2012).

  6. The recognition in mainstream economics of the need for industrial policy to respond to market failures began to receive prominence more than two decades ago in a response to the role played by the state in Japan and the east Asian newly industrialised countries (Page, 1994).

  7. Strategic support for the military sector is clearly evident across many economies and this has spawned a number of technologies of commercial importance (including the internet) (Mazzucato, 2013). Other examples of sectoral incentives are the UK support for the automotive sector, the United States for the hydrocarbon and processing sectors and Germany for renewable energy.

  8. Unfortunately, space constraints do not allow us to extend this analysis of rent exploitation, generation and protection in GVCs. Reference is, however, made in the text to the wider literature from which these insights are drawn.

  9. The innovation literature distinguishes between innovations that are new to the firm, new to the economy, new to the sector and new to the world.

  10. For example, selling furniture into smaller retail outlets offers greater scope for producers to design and brand their own products, although with much smaller volumes than those involved in serving IKEA and other global multiples.

  11. In Henry Ford’s mass production River Rouge plant constructed in 1927, virtually the whole value of the car was added in a single plant from the unloading of iron ore, through the manufacture of steel and the manufacture and assembly of the components into the final vehicle.

  12. Much of the international financial institution’s policy agenda relating to GVCs focuses almost exclusively on trade policy and fails to address the importance of these complementary policies (World Economic Forum, 2012; OECD Trade and Agricultural Directorate Trade Committee, 2014).

  13. For example, between 2011 and 2013, the number of firms supplying batteries for the iPhone in China doubled from 8 to 16, and local firms began to produce formerly imported inputs such as acoustic components (Mishkin, 2013). Although undocumented, the value added in China in the production of the iPhone5 is almost certainly much greater than the $6.50 incorporated in the early versions of the iPhone4.

  14. Examples of such complementary polices can be found in Morris et al (2012) and Kaplinsky and Morris (2014).

References

  • Adewuyi, A.O. and Oyejide, T.A. (2012) ‘Determinants of backward linkages of oil and gas industry in the Nigerian economy’, Special issue making the most of commodities: The determinants of linkages in Africa. Resources Policy 37(4): 4512–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.E. and Martin, P. (1999) Two waves of globalization: superficial similarities, fundamental differences. In: H. Siebert (ed.) Globalization and Labour. Tubingen, Germany: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, R. and Owusu, G. (2012) Linkages in Ghana’s gold mining industry: challenging the enclave thesis. Resources Policy 37(4): 434–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A.D. (1977) The Visible Hand, Cambridge. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H. (2014) Economics: The User’s Guide. London: Pelican, Bloomsbury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cusumano, M.A. (1985) The Japanese Automobile Industry: Technology and Management at Nissan and Toyota. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R.E. and Hamilton, G. (2006) Emergent Economies, Divergent Paths: Economic Organization and International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fessehaie, J. and Morris, M. (2013) Value chain dynamics of Chinese copper mining in Zambia: Enclave or linkage development? European Journal of Development Research 25(4): 537–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G. (1999) ‘A commodity chains framework for analysing global industries’, in Institute of Development Studies, 1999, Background Notes for Workshop on Spreading the Gains from Globalisation, www.ids.ac.uk/ids/global/conf/wkscf.html.

  • Gereffi, G. (2014) A Global Value Chain Perspective on Industrial Policy and Development in Emerging Markets, mimeo, Raleigh, North Carolina: Raleigh’ Duke University.

  • Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J. and Sturgeon, T. (2005) The governance of global value chains. Review of International Political Economy 12(1): 78–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G., Korzeniewicz, M. and Korzeniewicz, R.P. (1994) Introduction. In: G. Gereffi and M. Korzeniewicz (eds.) Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism. London: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbon, P. and Ponte, S. (2005) Trading Down: Africa, Value Chains and Global Capitalism. Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G. and Prahalad, C.K. (1994) Competing for the Future. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A.O. (1981) Essays in Trespassing: Economics to Politics and Beyond. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, J. and Schmitz, H. (2000) Global Governance and Upgrading: Linking Industrial Cluster and Global Value Chain Research, IDS Working Paper 120, Brighton, UK: Institute of Development Studies.

  • Kaplan, D. (2012) South African mining equipment and specialist services: Technological capacity, export performance and policy. Resource Policy 37(4): 425–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (1993) (§)Export processing zones in the dominican republic: Transforming manufactures into commodities. World Development 21(11): 1851–1865.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (2005) Globalization, Poverty and Inequality: Between a Rock and a Hard Place. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press, (Reprinted 2008). (Chinese translation Intellectual Property Publishing House, Beijing, 2008).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (2010) The Role of Standards in Global Value Chains and their Impact on Economic and Social Upgrading, Policy Research Working Paper 5396, Washington DC: World Bank.

  • Kaplinsky, R. and Morris, M. (2001) A handbook for value chain research, http://asiandrivers.open.ac.uk/documents/Value_chain_Handbook_RKMM_Nov_2001.pdf, accessed 15 March 2015.

  • Kaplinsky, R. and Morris, M. (2014) Developing Industrial Clusters and Supply Chains to Support Diversification and Sustainable Development of Exports in Africa, Report for the AfrEximBank, Cape Town: University of Cape Town.

  • Kaplinsky, R., Morris, M. and Readman, J. (2002) The globalisation of product markets and immiserising growth: Lessons from the South African furniture industry. World Development 30(7): 1159–1178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. and Readman, J. (2005) Globalisation and upgrading: What can (and cannot) be learnt from international trade statistics in the wood furniture sector? Industrial and Corporate Change 14(4): 679–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R., Terheggen, A. and Tijaja, J.P. (2011) China as a final market: The gabon timber and Thai Cassava value chains. World Development 39(7): 1177–1190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lederman, D. and Maloney, W.F. (2007) Trade structure and growth. In: D. Lederman and W.F. Maloney (eds.) Natural Resources: Neither Curse Nor Destiny. Washington DC: Stanford University Press and The World Bank, pp. 15–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, J.Y. and Monga, C. (2010) Growth Identification and Facilitation: The Role of the State in the Dynamics of Structural Change, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5313, Washington DC: World Bank.

  • Mazzucato, M. (2013) The Entrepreneurial State. London: Demos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mbayi, L. (2015) Turning rough dreams into a polished reality? Investigating the formation of human capital in Botswana’s Diamond Cutting and Polishing Industry, PhD thesis, Open University, Milton Keynes, UK.

  • Mishkin, S. (2013) Chinese companies moving into supply chain for Apple components, Financial Times 29 September.

  • Mjimba, V. (2013) The nature and determinants of backward linkages in emerging minerals commodity sectors: A case study of gold mining in Tanzania, PhD thesis, Open University, Milton Keynes, UK.

  • Morris, M. and Fessehaie, J. (2012) Making the Most of Africa’s Commodities: Linkage Development, Value Addition and Industrialisation, Report for the United Nations Economic Commission on Africa: Economic Report on Africa 2013, Cape Town: University of Cape Town.

  • Morris, M., Kaplinsky, R. and Kaplan, D. (2012) One thing leads to another: Promoting industrialisation by making the most of commodities in Sub Sahara Africa, http://www.Lulu.com or http://tinyurl.com/CommoditiesBook, accessed 15 March 2015.

  • Morris, M. and Staritz, C. (2014) Industrialization trajectories in madagascar’s export apparel industry: Ownership, embeddedness, markets, and upgrading. World Development 56: 243–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2014) Africa Economic Outlook. Paris, France: OECD Development Centre.

  • OECD Trade and Agricultural Directorate Trade Committee (2014) Developing Countries’ Participation in Global Value Chains – Implications for Trade and Trade Related Policies: Draft Report, TAD/TC/WP(2014)12/REV1, 19 September 2014.

  • Page, J.M. (1994) The East Asian miracle: An introduction. World Development 22(4): 615–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poon, D. (2014) China and South-South “Self-Sustaining Growth”: An Opening for Industrial Policy and Catch-up Development. UNCTAD Working Paper. Geneva: UNCTAD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M.E. (1985) Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. (1817) The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London: Dent, (Reprinted 1973).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2004) Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century, RWP04-047, Kennedy School of Government Research Working Paper, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.

  • Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (2001) The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review 45(4–6): 827–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1934) The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singer, H.W. (1950) The distribution of gains between Investing and borrowing countries. American Economic Review 15(2): 473–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776) An Enquiry into the Nature and Cause of The Wealth of Nations. (4th Edition), republished in 1976 by Oxford: Oxford University Press, and edited by R.H. Campbell and A.S Skinner.

  • Sturgeon, T. and Memedovic, O. (2010) Mapping Global Value Chains: Intermediate Goods Trade and Structural, Development Policy and Strategic Research Branch, Working Paper 05/2010, Vienna, Austria, UNIDO.

  • Syrquin, M. and Chenery, H. (1989) Patterns of Development: 1953 to 1983, World Bank Discussion Paper No 41, Washington DC, IBRD.

  • Terheggen, A. (2011) The Tropical Timber Industry in Gabon: A Forward Linkages Approach to Industrialisation, MMCP Discussion Paper No. 10, Milton Keynes, UK.

  • US Census Bureau (2013) A profile of U.S. Importing and Exporting Firms, U.S. Census Bureau News 5 April, Washington DC, US Dept. of Commerce, 2011.

  • UNCTAD (2013) World Investment Report, Geneva: United Nations.

  • Wilkins, M. (1974) The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from 1914 to 1970. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets and Relational Contracting. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, G. and Czelusta, J. (2004) The myth of the resource curse. Challenge 47(2): 6–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Economic Forum (2012) The shifting geography of global value chains: implications for developing countries and trade policy, Global Agenda Council on the Global Trade System, Davos, Switzerland.

  • Xing, Y. and Detert, N. (2010) How the iPhone Widens the United States Trade Deficit with the People’s Republic of China. ADBI Working Paper 257, Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kaplinsky, R., Morris, M. Thinning and Thickening: Productive Sector Policies in The Era of Global Value Chains. Eur J Dev Res 28, 625–645 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.29

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.29

Keywords

Navigation