Skip to main content
Log in

Cross-border banking supervision: Incentive conflicts in supervisory information sharing between home and host supervisors

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Banking Regulation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Basel Committee has been active in the area of cross-border banking supervision since its establishment now more than 30 years ago. Despite its longstanding efforts to promote better cooperation among prudential banking supervisors, the crisis has confirmed that individual supervisors ignore the impact of their decisions on financial stability in other jurisdictions. It has also highlighted the systemic risks host supervisors whose financial systems are dominated by foreign banks face. Many of these risks originate from the numerous incentive distortions between home and host supervisors. International bodies such as the G20, the Financial Stability Board and the Basel Committee have responded in a concerted effort and publicly promoted better cooperation, particularly through the use of supervisory colleges and the establishment of cross-border crisis management groups. However, improving supervisory cooperation alone is not sufficient. What is needed is a rigorous analysis to ensure the right incentives for home and host supervisors are in place at every stage of the supervision and resolution process. For this purpose, it is essential that policymakers integrate and harmonize the current debates on crisis management, resolution policy and good supervisory practice for cross-border banking supervision.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7

Similar content being viewed by others

References and Notes

  • This article focuses on prudential banking supervision in an international context. Consumer protection, other aspects of regulation and supervisory arrangements in the European Union (EU) lie outside of the scope of this article.

  • Financial Stability Board. (2010) Progress Since the St. Andrews Meeting on Implementing the G-20 Recommendations for Strengthening Financial Stability. Bank for Basel: International Settlements, p. 17, section VII.5, April. Report of the Financial Stability Board to G-20 Finance Ministers and Governors..

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2010) Good practice principles on supervisory colleges. Bank for Basel: International Settlements. November, www.bis.org/publ/bcbs177.pdf.

  • International Monetary Fund. (2009) Initial lessons of the crisis. Washington DC, February. Staff paper.

  • Turner, A. (2009) A regulatory response to the global banking crisis. In: FSA (ed.), www.fsa.gov.uk/library/corporate/turner.

  • On 20 December 2011 the Basel Committee consulted on an updated version of the Core Principles that takes into account the lessons learnt and new regulations issued since the global financial crisis.

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2006) Core principles for effective banking supervision – Methodology. Bank for International Settlements. Basel, October, www.bis.org/publ/bcbs130.pdf.

  • Financial Stability Board. (2011) Key attributes of effective resolution regimes for financial institutions. Basel, November, www.financialstabilityboard.org/publication/M_111104cc.pdf.

  • Pistor, K. (2010) Host's Dilemma: Rethinking EU Banking Regulation in the Light of the Global Crisis. Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper nr 378.

  • Rosengren, E. (2007) Challenges in cross border supervision and regulation. International financial instability. In: D. Evanoff, J. LaBrosse and G. Kaufman (eds.) Global Banking and National Regulation. New Jersey: World Scientific, pp. 233–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Claessens, S., Herring, R. and Schoenmaker, D. (2010) A Safer World Financial System: Improving the Resolution of Systemic Institutions. Geneva, July. Geneva Report on the World Economy, International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies.

  • Kane, E.J. (1989) Changing incentives facing financial services regulators. Journal of Financial Services Research 2 (3): 265–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, E.J. (1989) The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did It Happen? Washington DC: Urban Institute Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kane, E.J. (1990) Principal-agent problems in S&L salvage. Journal of Finance 45 (3): 755–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, E.J. (2002) Using deferred compensation to strengthen the ethics of financial regulation. Journal of Banking and Finance 26 (9): 1919–1933.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, R.J. (2010) Accountability of financial supervisory agencies: An incentive approach. Journal of Banking Regulation 11 (2): 115–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • For example, most relevant information is known only to the supervisory agency. Prudential supervisors receive confidential and propriety information from supervised institutions that they do not share with the government. This creates information asymmetry.

  • The Community Reinvestment Act is a United States federal law designed to encourage commercial banks and savings associations to help meet the needs of borrowers in all segments of their communities, including low- and moderate-income neighborhoods.

  • Stolz, S. (2002) Banking Supervision in Integrated Financial Markets: Implications for the EU. CESifo Economic Studies, Working Paper Series No 812.

  • Schűler, M. (2003) Incentive Problems in Banking Supervision – The European Case. Discussion Paper No 03-62, Center for European Economic research, Mannheim.

  • Schoenmaker, D. and Oosterloo, S. (2005) Financial supervision in an integrating Europe; measuring cross border externalities. International Finance 8 (1): 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holthausen, C. and Ronde, T. (2004) Cooperation in International Banking Supervision. Working Paper Series Nr 316, European Central Bank Frankfurt am Main.

  • Baxter, L. (2011) Capture in financial regulation: Can we channel it toward the common good?. Cornell Journal of Law and Public Policy 21: 175–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buiter, W. (2008) Lessons from the North Atlantic financial crisis. Paper prepared for presentation at the conference ‘The Role of Money Markets’ jointly organized by Columbia Business School and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on 29–30 May 2008.

  • Enria, A. and Vesala, J. (2003) Externalities in supervision. In: J.J.M. Kremers, D. Schoenmaker and P.J. Wierts (eds.) Financial Supervision in Europe. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 60–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herring, R. (2007) Conflicts between home and host country prudential supervisors. In: D. Evanoff, J. LaBrosse and G. Kaufman (eds.) Global Banking and National Regulation. New Jersey: World Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • The supervisory authority will still have an incentive to take action domestically, but if the operations are not systemic in the host country, the supervisory intensity will generally be lower and it is likely the authority will take a more balanced approach towards the cost of sharing information (attending colleges and so on) than in the case where the operations were systemic.

  • Financial Stability Board. (2010) Reducing the moral Hazard posed by systemically important financial institutions. Bank for International Settlements, Basel, October. http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_101111a.pdf.

  • Lastra, R. (2011) Cross Border Bank Insolvency. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2010) Resolution of Cross-border Banks – A Proposed Framework for Enhanced Coordination. Washington DC, www.imj.org/external/np/pp/eng/2010/061110.pdf.

  • Alford, D. (2010) Supervisory colleges, the global financial crisis and improving international supervisory coordination. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract, January, pp. 4–5.

  • The responsibility for domestic financial stability may also not lie with the supervisor but with the central bank. In some countries it is even not clear who is accountable for domestic financial stability.

  • For example, Australia requires that a bank's assets in Australia must be equal to or greater than the total amount of its deposit liabilities in Australia.

  • Song, I. (2004) Foreign Bank Supervision and Challenges to Emerging Market Supervisors. Washington DC. International Monetary Fund. Working Paper 04/82.

  • Cerutti, E., Ilyina, A., Makarova, Y. and Schmieder, C. (2010) Bankers without Borders? Implications of Ring-fencing for European Cross-border Banks. Washington DC, November. IMF Working paper 10/247, International Monetary Fund.

  • Lui, A. (2011) Retail ring-fencing of banks and its implications. Journal of Banking Regulation 12 (December): 1750–2071.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayes, D. and Vesala, J. (2000) On the problems of home country control. Bank of Finland – Studies in Economics and Finance, Research Department.

  • Dell'Arciccia, G. and Marquez, R. (2009) Risk and the corporate structure of banks. Journal of Finance 65 (3): 1075–1096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brazil, Malaysia, Mexico and New Zealand require or strongly encourage local subsidiaries. Brazil also has regulations to prevent subsidiaries from returning earnings to the parent bank. In Argentina, Bolivia, India and the Republic of Korea, branches are subject to capital and liquidity requirements similar to local subsidiaries. Albania has established a ‘systemic’ threshold above which the regulation of subsidiaries apply to branches.

  • Fiechter, J., Ötker-Robe, I., Ilyina, A., Hsu, M., Santos, A. and Surti, J. (2011) Subsidiaries or branches, does one size fits all? IMF Staff Discussion Note, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, March.

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2003) High-level principles for the cross-border implementation of the new accord. Bank for International Settlements. Basel, paragraph 16, p. 7, www.bis.org/publ/bcbs100.pdf.

  • Mechanism design or reverse game theory is a field in game theory studying solution concepts for a class of private information games. In layman's terms, mechanism design deals with situations where a planner has to reach a decision when the quality of the decision relies on information spread among a number of people. The main idea is that any solution should take into account the incentives of self-interested agents, that is, the people on whose information the decision relies must find it in their interest to reveal that information.

  • Celik, G. (2004) Mechanism design with collusive supervision. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (1): 69–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Katia D'Hulster.

Additional information

Disclaimer The findings, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this article are entirely those of the author. They do not represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

D'Hulster, K. Cross-border banking supervision: Incentive conflicts in supervisory information sharing between home and host supervisors. J Bank Regul 13, 300–319 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1057/jbr.2012.10

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jbr.2012.10

Keywords

Navigation