Skip to main content
Log in

Measuring and Analyzing Sovereign Risk with Contingent Claims

  • Published:
IMF Staff Papers Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a comprehensive new framework to measure and analyze sovereign risk. Contingent claims analysis is used to construct a marked-to-market balance sheet for the sovereign and derive a set of forward-looking credit risk indicators that serve as a barometer of sovereign risk. Applications to 12 emerging market economies show the approach to be robust, and the risk indicators are a significant improvement over traditional macroeconomic vulnerability indicators and accounting-based measures. The framework can help policymakers design risk mitigation strategies and rank policy options using a calibrated structural model unique to each economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Buiter (1993) for a discussion of the many items on the balance sheet of the public sector, including nonmarketable items such as social overhead capital.

  2. Xiao (2007) shows that an increase in volatility dampens demand for sovereign bonds.

  3. Volatility of sovereign assets can differ across countries for many reasons, including, but not limited to, the level of international reserves on the government's balance sheet, the exchange rate, and variations in government revenue and expenditures. Countries with lower asset volatility are generally able to use larger amounts of leverage with relative comfort whereas countries with higher asset volatility would be better off taking on less leverage.

  4. Foreign currency debt in global markets is predominantly fixed-rate, “bullet” maturity debt that results in easily defined contractual flows. Some global debt is amortizing, but these payments are usually well specified. The main difficulties in estimating debt payments arise when the debt payments are linked to changes in interest rates, exchange rates, or inflation. These forms are more often found in domestic as opposed to global capital markets.

  5. Measuring the balance sheet in U.S. dollars results in variable sovereign assets vs. a fixed distress barrier. Measuring the balance sheet in domestic currency will result in both variable sovereign assets and a variable distress barrier. In either configuration, the contingent claim formulas will produce the same results.

  6. The implicit guarantees to the financial sector, or other entities, could remain on the liability side of the consolidated public sector balance sheet and modeled as implicit put options. For more details, see Merton (1977); Gray, Merton, and Bodie (2002, 2006); Gapen and others (2004); and Van den End and Tabbae (2005). These papers link the sovereign to the contingent claim balance sheets of the banking or corporate sectors. The detailed analysis of the links to other sectors is beyond the scope of this paper.

  7. Support for viewing foreign currency debt as senior can also be found in the literature on “original sin” in Eichengreen, Hausmann, and Panizza (2002).

  8. The analysis also holds in the case of large developed markets such as the United States. While the balance sheet is already measured in dollars, the domestic bondholder is subject to (1) increased debt issuance that dilutes existing bondholders' claims on sovereign assets and (2) an increase in base money, or unexpected inflation risk, which reduces the real value of domestic currency debt. Even though developed markets are not thought to exhibit problems of “original sin” and currency mismatches, domestic currency liabilities of developed countries exhibit equity-like properties through dilution risk.

  9. See Cossin and Pirotte (2001) for a discussion on how the framework can handle multiple layers of liabilities or default sequences. The use of two layers of sovereign liabilities is a reasonable approximation given the observed robustness of the model and the behavior of spreads during periods of stress. Assuming that all money and local currency debt are senior and all foreign currency debt is junior leads to inconsistencies. Crises resulting in depreciation of the exchange rate would cause the “foreign currency junior claim” to grow large compared to domestic currency debt. This is inconsistent with the observation that credit default swap spreads on foreign currency debt increase with sharp depreciations. In situations of large exchange rate appreciation, usually considered beneficial from a credit risk perspective, the value of the “foreign currency debt junior claim” would be very small relative to domestic currency debt, indicating a large expected loss is associated with the domestic currency debt.

  10. This definition of the distress barrier is identical to that used by Moody's KMV in corporate sector default risk analysis (Crosbie and Bohn, 2003). Short-term is defined as one year or less by residual maturity. See Sobehart and Stein (2000) and Sobehart, Keenan, and Stein (2000) for evidence that this approach outperforms other models in estimation of corporate sector credit risk.

  11. See Hull (1993) and Baxter and Rennie (1996) for discrete-time representations.

  12. Here, N(d 1) is the change in the price of domestic currency liabilities with respect to a change in sovereign assets, or ∂V DCL /∂V A . This ratio is also referred to as the option delta. See Hull (1993, p. 38).

  13. The main difficulty in applying Equations (1) and (3) lies in the computation of the cumulative normal distribution. Numerical integration methods can be used to evaluate the distribution directly, computing a finite number of evaluations of the integrand and then summing over these values. Judd (1998) provides a menu of available integration methods, including the Gauss-Hermite quadrature that is often used in conjunction with normally distributed random variables. Alternatively, the distribution can be approximated using a high-order polynomial approximation, as is done in Hull (1993, pp. 226–27). Standard prepackaged routines in Matlab can then be implemented to find the zero roots of the nonlinear equations using iterative methods. A sample Matlab program can be found in Miranda and Fackler (2002, pp. 382–85). Using either of these techniques, Equations (1) and (3) can be solved for the implied value of sovereign assets and sovereign asset volatility.

  14. Risk-neutral valuation is an important factor underlying the derivation of the Black-Scholes option pricing formula whereby the value of the option can be derived by forming a riskless hedge portfolio. Thus, option values do not depend on the investor's or decision maker's attitude toward risk, which is a major benefit of this approach. Alternative balance sheet approaches based on discounted cash flows are subject to serious error not only from errors in cash flow projections but also from errors in choosing the discount rate. See Hull (1993, pp. 221–22) and Chriss (1997, pp. 190–93) for additional discussion of risk-neutral valuation.

  15. Merton (1974) derives similar measures for the pricing of corporate debt. The value of senior foreign currency liabilities can also be obtained using the implicit put option in risky debt (Gapen and others, 2004; Gray, 2004; Chacko and others, 2006; and Gray, Merton, and Bodie, 2006), or .

  16. Variations in the derivative asset price with respect to changes in the underlying parameters that enter the option formula are known as Greek-letter risk measures. Frequently used measures are the option delta, gamma, and vega. See Briys and others (1998, pp. 124–28) for these and other measures of option sensitivities that are used in managing exposures.

  17. Mapping of risk-neutral default probability into actual default probabilities is necessary for rating agencies in the ratings process but is not necessary for valuation purposes. The Merton framework substitutes the risk-free interest rate for the actual expected return in the asset-probability distribution. Because the actual expected return is greater than the risk-free return, the risk-neutral probability of default is higher than the actual probability of default. However, expected returns are not necessary for valuation purposes. The relationship between the risk-neutral spreads and risk-neutral default probability and actual spreads and market-implied default probability, as undertaken in this paper, is examined mainly for robustness purposes. See Merton (1990) for additional discussion.

  18. The historical data for the sovereign risk indicators in Equations (3), (4), (5) to (6) were obtained from the Macrofinancial Risk (MfRisk) model, which applies the contingent claims methodology as described in this paper. The model was developed under a joint research effort between Moody's and Macro Financial Risk, Inc., and applied to 17 countries. At the time of the writing of this paper, access to MfRisk was available only through subscription.

  19. Reported output in Figure 3 is limited to the 12 countries for which credit default swap data were available.

  20. The reported correlations in Table 1 were computed using Spearman's rank correlation instead of conventional correlation. Conventional correlation is inappropriate in this case because it implicitly assumes linear relationships among variables, an assumption that contradicts the nonlinear relationship between variables as found in this paper. Spearman's rank correlation is a less restrictive measure to gauge relationships among variables because it does not impose any linearity assumptions.

  21. The JPMorgan EMBIG index has replaced the EMBI+ index as the preferred index for tracking emerging market credit spreads, but historical EMBIG index data were not available at the time of the writing of this paper.

  22. The countries in the sample include Brazil, Colombia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, Turkey, and Venezuela.

  23. MIDP can be obtained from CDS spreads through the following equation: , where spread is the net one-year credit default swap spread, t is the time horizon (equal to 1 in this case), and R=30 percent is the recovery rate. If the one- year CDS spread is 180 basis points, the implied default probability is 2.5 percent.

  24. The countries in the sample include Brazil, Colombia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, Turkey, and Venezuela.

  25. The solid line in the figure represents the line of best fit, y=4597.3 exp(–2.3743x), with R 2=0.7957.

  26. Since the scenario and Monte Carlo simulations are based on this hypothetical sovereign balance sheet, we use the results from a panel regression between risk-neutral spreads and EMBI+ spreads applied to the countries in Table 3. The estimated equation between risk-neutral spreads and market credit spreads is ln(EMBI t ) =2.97+0.61 ln (RNS t ).

  27. Although Monte Carlo simulations are able to handle many thousand possible events, they produce a random set of outcomes based on the market characteristics assumed, which may or may not predict potential shocks. The simulation process will only produce as many extreme events as dictated by the distribution assumption of the market variables. To be comprehensive, simulation procedures should be combined with various scenario assumptions to produce a set of stress outcomes.

  28. As discussed in the previous section regarding the computation of implied sovereign assets and volatility, the calibrated inputs of the distress barrier and volatility of domestic currency liabilities are estimates. That is, ς̂ is an estimate of the true volatility of domestic currency liabilities, ς̂, and as such will contain standard error, leading to possible model risk. The presence of standard error otherwise results in confidence intervals around the point estimates of risk for each risk indicator. However, the traditional practices used to compute such estimates in the finance literature as described in this paper do not involve empirical regression estimation, making the construction of standard error bounds problematic. Instead of computing a confidence interval around the expected value of the risk indicator given standard error in ς̂, the construction of probability distributions using Monte Carlo analysis is equivalent to confidence intervals around the expected value of the risk indicator given the estimate of ς̂. The issue is further complicated by the fact that introducing standard errors on ς̂ would result in error bands on the entire distribution of the risk indicators in the Monte Carlo simulation, greatly complicating the exercise.

  29. See Jorion (2000). VaR models estimate the exposure of a portfolio, or the equivalent set of positions, to market risk. The measure captures the expected maximum loss and is usually expressed within a confidence interval.

  30. Two other sovereign VaR measures can be calculated. The first, sovereign capital-at-risk, is an extension of sovereign VaR for the central bank. The probability distribution of the residual value of “capital” or junior claim of the monetary authority is calculated and a confidence level attached to the risk that the monetary authority cannot meet its commitments. Blejer and Schumacher (1999) use a similar construction. The second, sovereign credit-at-risk, is the upper bound on gains or losses due to credit risk, which in this case is the value of the guarantee to the banking system. See Gapen and others (2004) for an example of how this could be modeled.

  31. See Gapen and Papaioannou (2007) for the various motives and implications of reserve accumulation throughout the Asian region.

  32. Simulating the adjusted sovereign balance sheet under the same exchange rate and interest rate distributions and correlation is subject to the critique that these distributions and correlations are derived from market expectations that are likely to change with the shift in policy. The simulations conducted in this paper should be viewed only as illustrating potential impacts from policy changes.

  33. IMF (2000) examines three ratios: reserves to imports, reserves to monetary aggregates, and reserves to public and private short-term foreign currency debt by residual maturity. The report concludes that reserves to short-term foreign currency debt is a superior measure and recommends that a ratio of 1 be a lower bound for adequate reserve coverage.

  34. See Gray (2007) for applications to sovereign wealth management and Gray and Malone (forthcoming) for additional examples. Caballero and Panageas (2005) also examine various instruments and risk mitigation strategies that policymakers could implement in addition to traditional reserve accumulation in a model of sudden stops in capital flows.

  35. This is true whether one uses the simplified distress barrier in this paper (short-term foreign currency debt and interest plus one-half long- term foreign currency debt) or a more sophisticated approach (short-term foreign currency debt and interest plus the present discounted value of long-term foreign currency debt and interest). Both approaches would reflect an increase in sovereign risk if long-term foreign currency debt was traded for equal book value amounts of short-term foreign currency debt. The distress barrier under the second approach, however, would be more sensitive to near-term repayment humps that would carry a higher weight in the distress barrier than a similar payment profile further out on the maturity scale.

References

  • Ariyoshi, Akira, Karl Habermeier, Bernard Laurens, Inci Ötker-Robe, Jorge Iván Canales-Kriljenko, and Andrei Kirilenko, 2000, Capital Controls: Country Experiences with Their Use and Liberalization, IMF Occasional Paper No. 190 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

  • Baxter, Martin, and Andrew Rennie, 1996, Financial Calculus: An Introduction to Derivative Pricing (Cambridge, United Kingdom, Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Black, Fischer, and Myron S. Scholes, 1973, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81, No. 3, pp. 637–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blejer, M., and L. Schumacher, 1999, “Central Bank Vulnerability and the Credibility of Its Commitments: A Value-at-Risk Approach,” Journal of Risk, Vol. 2 (fall), pp. 37–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohn, Jeffrey, Navneet Arora, and Irina Korablev, 2005, Power and Level Validation of the EDF Credit Measure in the U.S. Market (San Francisco, Moody's KMV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Briys, Eric, Mondher Bellalah, Huu Minh Mai, and François de Varenne, 1998, Options, Futures, and Exotic Derivatives: Theory, Application, and Practice (New York, John Wiley and Sons).

    Google Scholar 

  • Buiter, Willem H., 1993, “Measurement of the Public Sector Deficit and Its Implications for Policy Evaluation and Design,” in How to Measure the Fiscal Deficit, ed. by Mario I. Blejer and Adrienne Cheasty (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Stavros Panageas, 2005, “Insurance and Reserves Management in a Model of Sudden Stops,” paper presented at the IMF Institute seminar, “Emerging Markets Macroeconomics: An Insurance Perspective,” Washington, February 7–9.

  • Chacko, George, Anders Sjöman, Hideto Motohashi, and Vincent Dessain, 2006, Credit Derivatives: A Primer on Credit Risk, Modeling, and Instruments (Philadelphia, Wharton Book Publishers).

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan-Lau, J., A. Jobert, and Janet Kong, 2004, “An Option-Based Approach to Bank Vulnerabilities in Emerging Markets,” IMF Working Paper 04/33 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

  • Chriss, Neil A., 1997, Black-Scholes and Beyond: Option Pricing Models (New York, McGraw-Hill Professional).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cossin, D., and H. Pirotte, 2001, Advanced Credit Risk Analysis (New York, John Wiley and Sons).

    Google Scholar 

  • Crosbie, Peter J., and Jeffrey R. Bohn, 2003, Modeling Default Risk: Modeling Methodology (San Francisco, Moody's KMV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Crouhy, Michel, Dan Galai, and Robert Mark, 2000, “A Comparative Analysis of Current Credit Risk Models,” Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 24 (January), pp. 59–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, Barry, Ricardo Hausmann, and Ugo Panizza, 2002, “Original Sin: The Pain, the Mystery, and the Road to Redemption,” paper presented at Inter-American Development Bank conference, “Currency and Maturity Matchmaking: Redeeming Debt from Original Sin,” Washington, November 21–22. Available via the Internet: www.iadb.org/res/publications/pubfiles/pubS-158.pdf.

  • Gapen, Michael T., Dale F. Gray, Cheng Hoon Lim, and Yingbin Xiao, 2004, “The Contingent Claims Approach to Corporate Vulnerability Analysis: Estimating Default Risk and Economy-Wide Risk Transfer,” IMF Working Paper 04/121 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

  • Gapen, and Michael Papaioannou, 2007, “International Reserves Accumulation: Some Lessons from Asia,” in Information Technology and Economic Development, ed. by Yutaka Kurihara and others (Hershey, Idea Group, Inc.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, and Dale F., 2004, “Modeling Sovereign Default Risk and Country Risk Using Moody's-MfRisk Framework with Specific Country Applications,” Unpublished MfRisk Working Paper No. 1–04.

  • Gray, and Dale F., 2007, “A New Framework for Risk and Sovereign Wealth Management,” in Sovereign Wealth Management, ed. by Jennifer Johnson-Calari and Malan Rietveld (London, Central Bank Publications).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, Dale F., Samuel Malone, forthcoming, Macrofinancial Risk Analysis (London, Wiley).

  • Gray, Dale F., Robert C. Merton, and Zvi Bodie, 2002, “A New Framework for Analyzing and Managing Macrofinancial Risks,” presented at NYU C.V. Starr Conference on Finance and Macroeconomics, October 11–12.

  • Gray, Dale F., Merton, and Bodie, 2006, “A New Framework for Analyzing and Managing Macrofinancial Risks of an Economy,” NBER Working Paper No. 12637 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Gulde, Anne-Marie, David Hoelscher, Alain Ize, Alfredo Leone, David Marston, and Marina Moretti, 2003, “Dealing with Banking Crises in Dollarized Economies,” in Managing Financial Crises: Recent Experience and Lessons for Latin America, ed. by Charles Collyns and G. Russell Kincaid, IMF Occasional Paper No. 217 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull, John C, 1993, Options, Futures, and Other Derivative Securities (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, Prentice-Hall, 2nd ed.).

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 1999, Ukraine: Recent Economic Developments, IMF Country Report No. 99/42 (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2000, “Debt- and Reserve-Related Indicators of External Vulnerability,” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/debtres/debtres.pdf.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2002, “Sovereign Debt Restructurings and the Domestic Economy Experience in Four Recent Cases,” (Washington). Available via the Internet: www.imf.org/external/NP/pdr/sdrm/2002/022102.pdf.

  • Jorion, Philippe, 1995, “Predicting Volatility in the Foreign Exchange Market,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 50 (June), pp. 507–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorion, Philippe, 2000, Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk (New York, McGraw-Hill).

    Google Scholar 

  • Judd, Kenneth L, 1998, Numerical Methods in Economics (Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kupiec, Paul H, 2002, “Internal Models-Based Capital Regulation and Bank Risk-Taking Incentives,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/125 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

  • Malz, Allan M, 1997, “Estimating the Probability Distribution of the Future Exchange Rate from Option Prices,” Journal of Derivatives, Vol. 5 (winter), pp. 118–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • McQuown, John A, 1993, A Comment on Market vs. Accounting-Based Measures of Default Risk (San Francisco, Moody's KMV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, Robert C, 1973, “Theory of Rational Option Pricing,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4 (spring), pp. 141–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, Robert C, 1974, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 29 (May), pp. 449–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, Robert C, 1977, “An Analytic Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantees: An Application of Modern Option Pricing Theory,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 1 (June), pp. 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, Robert C, 1990, Continuous-Time Finance (Cambridge, Massachusetts, Blackwell Publishers).

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, Robert C, 1998, “Applications of Option-Pricing Theory: Twenty-Five Years Later,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88 (June), pp. 323–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miranda, Mario J., and Paul L. Fackler, 2002, Applied Computational Economics and Finance (Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sims, Christopher A., 1999, “Domestic Currency Denominated Government Debt as Equity in the Primary Surplus,” paper presented at the Latin American meetings of the Econometric Society, Cancun, Mexico, August 19.

  • Sobehart, Jorge, Sean Keenan, and Roger Stein, 2000, Validation Methodologies for Default Risk Models (San Francisco, Moody's KMV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobehart, Jorge, Sean Keenan, Roger Stein, and Roger M. Stein, 2000, Moody's Public Firm Risk Model: A Hybrid Approach to Modeling Short Term Default Risk (San Francisco: Moody's KMV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Van den End, W., and M. Tabbae, 2005, “Measuring Financial Stability; Applying the MfRisk Model to the Netherlands,” DNB Working Paper No. 30 (Amsterdam, De Nederlandsche Bank, March).

  • Xiao, Yingbin, 2007, “What Do Bond Holdings Reveal About International Funds' Preferences,” Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 8 (September), pp. 167–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*Michael Gapen is an economist with the IMF Institute; Dale Gray is a senior economist and Cheng Hoon Lim is a division chief with the IMF Monetary and Capital Markets Department; and Yingbin Xiao is an economist with the IMF European Department. The authors would like to thank Zvi Bodie, Carlos Medeiros, Robert Merton, Linda Tesar, and participants of the JPMorgan Chase seminars at the 2005 Annual Meetings of the Inter-American Development Bank in Okinawa and the Asian Development Bank in Istanbul, the Institute of International Finance Country Risk Workshop, and the IMF Institute for helpful comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank an anonymous referee for helpful suggestions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gapen, M., Gray, D., Lim, C. et al. Measuring and Analyzing Sovereign Risk with Contingent Claims. IMF Econ Rev 55, 109–148 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.imfsp.9450026

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.imfsp.9450026

JEL Classifications

Navigation