Skip to main content
Log in

Semiglobalization and international business strategy

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

If markets were either completely isolated by or integrated across borders, there would be little room for international business strategy to have content distinctive from ‘mainstream’ strategy. But a review of the economic evidence about the international integration of markets indicates that we fall in between these extremes, into a state of incomplete cross-border integration that I refer to as semiglobalization. More specifically, most measures of market integration have scaled new heights in the last few decades, but still fall far short of economic theory's ideal of perfect integration. The diagnosis of semiglobalization does more than just supply a relatively stable frame of reference for thinking about the environment of cross-border operations. It also calls attention to the critical role of location-specificity in the prospects of distinctive content for international business strategy relative to mainstream business and corporate strategy. In addition, it flags factors/products subject to location-specificity as being salient from the perspective of international business. Finally, it highlights the scope for strategies that strive to capitalize on the (large) residual barriers to cross-border integration, as well as those that simply try to cope with them.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. While location-specificity can also operate at the local or (intranational) regional level, a full treatment of it at all these levels of analyses is beyond the scope of this paper, even though many of the analytical issues that arise are similar.

  2. The disparity is even greater if one recognizes that the denominator of the ratio should really be a measure of gross sales rather than a value-added measure like GDP.

  3. Foreign direct investment currently accounts for roughly one-half of total foreign investment, but its share was significantly smaller at the start of the 20th century. See Bloomfield (1968, 3–4), cited in Bordo et al. (1999).

  4. Note that the spread of domestic safety nets does increase the likelihood that banking crises will turn into currency crises.

  5. For further discussion of currency risk, see Frankel (1992).

  6. Note the caveat that the extent of catch-up by the Asian tigers would look somewhat less remarkable if the data in Figure 5 were updated to take account of the Asian currency crisis.

  7. The other (overlapping) reasons for the localization of international competitiveness identified by Porter (1990) are sophisticated local demand and the local availability of specialized inputs and complements as well as basic factors of production.

  8. This point can be demonstrated formally in the context of standard supply–demand analysis. To start at one extreme, with complete insulation between two country markets, the price and quantity outcomes can be pinned down (under the assumption of atomistic competition) at the intersection of supply and demand curves in each market. At the other extreme, with complete integration – that is, zero extra costs of trading, transporting, transacting and so on across national boundaries – one could still add up the supply curves for the two markets on the one hand and their demand curves on the other and use the point of intersection of the two aggregate curves to determine the (common) prices and the quantities in the unified market. But the continuum of situations between zero and complete economic integration that I refer to as semi-globalization creates additional challenges. Given semi-globalization, the analysis of prices and quantities in the two markets cannot be reduced to supply–demand analysis of an individual market. Instead, attention has to be paid to distinct markets that are neither totally segmented nor totally integrated – an intrinsically more complex, and interesting, setup.

  9. For further discussion along these lines, see Caves (1998).

  10. Such integration would make access to a global pool of capital a ‘given’ for any worthy enterprise and thereby limit the scope for purely financial sources of advantage or disadvantage.

  11. Caves (1996) also identifies a third, residual category of multinational enterprise: international diversifiers whose operations in different countries are neither horizontally nor vertically related to each other. These can be thought of as falling in domain 4 of Table 5 rather than domain 3.

References

  • Alcacer, J. and Chung, W. (2001) ‘Knowledge seeking, human capital and location choice of foreign entrants in the United States’, Working Paper, Stern School of Business, New York University.

  • Baldwin, R.E. and Martin, P. (1999) Two Waves of Globalization: Superficial Similarities, Fundamental Differences, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBER Working Paper No. 6904.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, G. and Harvey, C.R. (1995) ‘Time-varying world market integration’, Journal of Finance 50(2): 403–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B.A. (1997) ‘Firm-specific assets and the link between exchange rates and foreign direct investment’, American Economic Review 87(3): 447–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloomfield, A.I. (1968) Patterns of Fluctuation in International Finance Before 1914, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 21, International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

  • Bordo, M.D., Eichengreen, B. and Irwin, D.A. (1999) Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBER Working Paper 7195 (Prepared for the Brookings Trade Policy Forum on Governing in a Global Economy, Washington, DC, 15–16 April 1999. Published: shorter version in Austrian Economic Papers, Vols. 1 and 2, 2000).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P.J. (2002) ‘Is the international business agenda running out of steam’, Journal of International Business Studies 33(2): 365–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M. (1976) The Future of the Multinational Enterprise, Macmillan: London.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1996) Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1998) ‘Research on international business: problems and prospects’, Journal of International Business Studies 29(1): 5–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1937) ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4(16): 396–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, K.W. and Eckstein, A. (1961) ‘National industrialization and the declining share of the international economic sector, 1890–1959’, World Politics 13(2): 267–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dune, N. (2001) ‘US population is now more than 10% foreign-born’, Financial Times, 4 January 2001, The Americas, p. 4.

  • Feenstra, RC (1998) ‘Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(4): 31–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M (1995) ‘The Effects of Outbound Foreign Direct Investment on the Domestic Capital Stock’, in M. Feldstein, J. Hines and R.G. Hubbard (eds.) The Effects of Taxation on Multinational Corporations, University of Chicago Press: Chicago, pp: 43–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. and Horioka, C. (1980) ‘Domestic savings and international capital flows’, Economic Journal 90(358): 314–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. (1992) ‘Measuring international capital mobility: a review’, American Economic Review 82(2): 197–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, Jeffrey, A. (2001) ‘Assessing the Efficiency Gain from Further Liberalization’, in Porter, Roger B., Pierre Sauvé, Arvind Subramanian & Americo Beviglia Zampetti, (eds.) Efficiency, equity, and legitimacy: the multilateral trading system at the millennium, Brookings Institution Press: Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. (2000) ‘Global advantage: arbitrage, replication, and transformation’, unpublished note, Harvard Business School, December.

  • Giddens, A. (1996) ‘Keynote address at the United Nations Research Institute for Social Development, as excerpted in ‘Essential matter’’, UNRISD News, No. 15.

  • Held, D., McGrew, A.G., Goldblatt, D. and Perraton, J. (1999) Global Transformations: Politics, Economics, and Culture, Stanford University Press: Stanford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J.F. (1998) How Much Do National Borders Matter?, Brookings Institution Press: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, D.A. (1996) ‘The United States in a new global economy? A century's perspective’, American Economic Review 86(2): 41–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A.B. and Trajtenberg, M. (1999) ‘International knowledge flows: evidence from patent citations’, Economics of Innovation and New Technology 8(1–2): 105–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller, W. (2000) Geographic Localization of International Technology Diffusion, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBER Working Paper No. 7509.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kenwood, A.G. and Lougheed, A.L. (1989) The Growth of the International Economy, 1920–1960, Allen & Unwin: London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, K.K. (1995) ‘Puzzles in International Financial Markets’, in G. Grossman and K. Rogoff (eds.) Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III, Elsevier Science: Amsterdam. pp: 1913–1971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoring the World Economy: 1820–1992, Development Centre of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, S.F. (ed.) (2000) World Migration Report: 2000, Copublished by the International Organization for Migration and the United Nations.

  • McCallum, J. (1995) ‘National borders matter: Canada–US regional trade patterns’, American Economic Review 85(3): 615–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Micklethwait, J. and Wooldridge, A. (2000) A Future Perfect: The Challenge and Hidden Promise of Globalization, Crown Business: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M. and Taylor, A. (1997) The Great Depression as a Watershed: International Capital Mobility over the Long Run, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, NBER Working Paper 5960.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. (1994) National Innovation Systems: Why they are Important and How they Might be Measured and Compared, Mimeo, Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E.T. (1959) The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Basil Blackwell, Wiley: Oxford, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M.E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Prahalad, C.K. and Doz, Y. (1987) The Multinational Mission: Balancing Local Demands and Global Vision, Free Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1996) ‘The purchasing power parity puzzle’, Journal of Economic Literature 34(2): 647–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, B. (2000) Economic Strategies of Nations, Mimeo, Harvard Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D.J. (1977) ‘Technology transfer by multinational firms: the resource cost of transferring technological know-how’, The Economic Journal 87(346): 242–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN Center on Transnational Corporations, World Investment Report (various issues).

  • World Economic Forum, Global Competitiveness Report (various issues).

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper has benefited from research assistance by Jamie Matthews and Raluca Lupu, helpful comments by David Collis, Beulah D'Souza, Vijay Govindarajan, Mauro Guillen, Tarun Khanna, Walter Kuemmerle, Christos Pitelis, Ravi Ramamurti, Louis T. Wells Jr., George S. Yip and, especially, Bernard Y. Yeung, as well as from presentation of material at the AIB Panel Session, in summer 2002, celebrating Buckley and Casson (1976). The Division of Research at the Harvard Business School provided financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pankaj Ghemawat.

Additional information

Accepted by Tom Brewer; outgoing Editor, August 2002.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ghemawat, P. Semiglobalization and international business strategy. J Int Bus Stud 34, 138–152 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400013

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400013

Keywords

Navigation