Skip to main content
Log in

Knowledge transfer capacity and its implications for the theory of the multinational corporation

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study updates and extends research on foreign entry modes by examining the impacts of knowledge transfer capacity and knowledge tacitness. Research on international corporate expansion has long emphasized that deploying intangible knowledge-based assets is required for successful international expansion. More recently, research from a ‘knowledge-based’ perspective has addressed the role of tacitness in constraining a firm's ability to transfer knowledge internationally. We combine these perspectives to describe how knowledge tacitness affects the relative suitability of four archetypal entry modes: exporting, licensing, establishing an alliance, and wholly owned entry. We then examine and develop conceptually a seldom-studied firm characteristic, knowledge transfer capacity. We offer predictions that describe the combined effects of knowledge tacitness and transfer capacity on entry mode choice. We distinguish between the transfer capacity of the organization that develops knowledge (source transfer capacity) and that of the organization that seeks to access that knowledge (recipient transfer capacity). The discussion addresses how our model generalizes to knowledge-seeking strategies and to the study of ongoing multinational networks. The study enriches and reconciles multiple theoretical perspectives on entry strategy. It brings together the study of knowledge characteristics and firm heterogeneity in the theory of the multinational corporation, and in international and strategic management more generally.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In order for firms to determine the net present value of the costs associated with particular entry modes, we must assume that they have access to the information necessary to assess those costs over time (Rugman, 1981).

  2. Although the licensing and alliance options generally involve the sharing of production costs between source and recipient, we include C* among the costs relevant to the source firm in examining the license and alliance options. We do so because this facilitates comparisons with the export and WOS alternatives (see also Hirsch, 1976; Rugman, 1981). This is analytically convenient and duly recognizes that, if the productive knowledge is used abroad, then the source firm and/or its partner must incur production costs in the host location. Furthermore, these costs should be deducted from the project's revenues in arriving at the potential profits to the source firm. Our specification recognizes that C* represents a deduction from revenues that, regardless of entry mode, will affect the net income available to the source firm. We thank two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments on these issues.

  3. The cost minimization approach is also consistent with the broader international business literature, including internalization arguments, and with many models that describe cost minimization as a means of studying profit-maximizing strategies (see Buckley and Casson, 1976; Williamson, 1991; Varian, 1992; Hennart, 1993; Caves, 1996). Two simple assumptions facilitate such a comparison among entry modes. First, the source firm is the only firm that possesses the knowledge-based assets at first (Hirsch, 1976; Dunning, 1993; Caves, 1996). Second, there exist several potential partners in the host location (Rugman, 1981). Such conditions allow the monopolist to extract the profits from any partnership (see also Buckley and Casson, 1998). Then, assuming that demand is independent of the mode of entry used by firms, cost minimization is strictly equivalent to profit maximization (Hirsch, 1976; Rugman, 1981; Williamson, 1991; Hennart, 1993).

  4. The basic model assumes that the net present value of gross revenues is equal across entry modes. However, should any systematic difference in revenues exist across modes, these could be accommodated in the model as shifts of equivalent magnitude in the various cost components. For example, if we were to assume that a technology must be exploited extremely rapidly, and that licensing (partnering) inherently allows faster entry (notwithstanding knowledge transfer issues), then increases in A*, and possibly M*, could accommodate the opportunity cost of not licensing (partnering). Alternatively, D* could be shifted downwards.

  5. In the section ‘Extending the model’, we discuss alternative potential means of shielding knowledge, including secrecy and intellectual property rights.

  6. The presumption that the knowledge can be transferred deserves further attention, because tacit knowledge may be inherently difficult to transfer. We return to this issue below.

  7. Although α+β<1 is a necessary condition for an alliance to be preferable to licensing and WOS, it is not a sufficient condition. If D* sufficiently exceeds A*, or vice versa, then the condition will not by itself allow an alliance to outperform both a WOS and a license. Conversely, the condition is sufficient to ensure that an alliance is the preferred mode in a range where A* and D* are approximately equal.

References

  • Agmon, T. and Hirsch, S. (1979) ‘Multinational corporations and the developing economics: potential gains in a world of imperfect markets and uncertainty’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 41: 333–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida, P. (1996) ‘Knowledge sourcing by foreign multinationals: patent citation analysis in the US semiconductor industry’, Strategic Management Journal 17: 155–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida, P., Song, J. and Grant, R.M. (2002) ‘Are firms superior to alliances and markets? An empirical test of cross-border knowledge building’, Organization Science 13(2): 147–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E. and Gatignon, H. (1986) ‘Modes of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and propositions’, Journal of International Business Studies 17(3): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argote, L. (1999) Organizational learning: creating, retaining and transfering knowledge, Kluwer: Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A. and Fosfuri, A. (2000) ‘Wholly owned subsidiary versus technology licensing in the worldwide chemical industry’, Journal of International Business Studies 31(4): 555–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1969) ‘Classificatory notes on the production and transmission of technical knowledge’, American Economic Review 59: 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, C. and Ghoshal, S. (1989) Managing Across Borders: The Transnational Solution, Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birkinshaw, J. and Hood, N. (1998) ‘Multinational subsidiary evolution: capability and charter change in foreign-owned subsidiary companies’, Academy of Management Review 23(4): 773–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. and Casson, M.C. (1976) The Future of the Multinational Enterprise, Holmes & Meier: London.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. and Casson, M.C. (1996) ‘An economic model of international joint venture strategy’, Journal of International Business Studies 27(5): 849–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. and Casson, M.C. (1998) ‘Analyzing foreign market entry strategies: extending the internalization approach’, Journal of International Business Studies 29(3): 539–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capron, L., Dussauge, P. and Mitchell, W. (1998) ‘Resource redeployment following horizontal acquisitions in Europe and North America, 1988–1992’, Strategic Management Journal 19(7): 631–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1971) ‘International corporations: the industrial economics of foreign investment’, Economica 38: 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1996) Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1937) ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W.M., Goto, A., Nagata, A., Nelson, R.R. and Walsh, J.P. (2002) ‘R&D spillovers, patents and the incentives to innovate in Japan and the United States’, Research Policy 31(8–9): 1349–1367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990) ‘Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation’, Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 128–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Contractor, F.J. (1985) ‘A generalized theorem for joint-venture and licensing negotiations’, Journal of International Business Studies 16(2): 23–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Contractor, F.J. (1990) ‘Contractual and cooperative forms of international business: towards a unified theory of modal choice’, Management International Review 30(1): 31–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, R. and Foray, D. (1997) ‘The economics of codification and the diffusion of knowledge’, Industrial and Corporate Change 6(3): 595–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. (1989) ‘Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage’, Management Science 35(12): 1504–1511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J.H. (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy, Addison-Wesley: Reading, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, C.S. (1990) ‘Transferring core manufacturing technologies in high-technology firms’, California Management Review 32(4): 56–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godkin, L. (1988) ‘Problems and practicalities of technology transfer: a survey of the literature’, International Journal of Technology Management 3: 587–603.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S. and Bartlett, C.A. (1990) ‘The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network’, Academy of Management Review 15(4): 603–625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grant, R.M. (1996) ‘Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm’, Strategic Management Journal 17(special issue): 109–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, A.K. and Govindarajan, V. (2000) ‘Knowledge flows within multinational corporations’, Strategic Management Journal 21(4): 473–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J.-F. (1993) ‘Explaining the ‘swollen middle’: why most transactions are a mix of market and hierarchy’, Organization Science 4(4): 529–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, S. (1976) ‘An international trade and investment theory of the firm’, Oxford Economic Papers 28: 258–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hymer, S.H. (1960) ‘The international operations of national firms: a study of direct foreign investment’, Doctoral dissertation, MIT (published by MIT Press in 1976).

  • Kenney, M. and Florida, R. (1993) Beyond Mass Production: The Japanese System and Its Transfer to the US, Oxford University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, W.C. and Hwang, P. (1992) ‘Global strategy and multinationals’ entry mode choice’, Journal of International Business Studies 23(1): 29–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. and Chang, S.J. (1991) ‘Technological capabilities and Japanese foreign direct investment in the United States’, Review of Economics and Statistics 73: 401–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992) ‘Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology’, Organization Science 3(3): 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1993) ‘Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation’, Journal of International Business Studies 24(4): 625–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1995) ‘Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: a reply’, Journal of International Business Studies 26(2): 417–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotabe, M., Martin, X. and Domoto, H. (2003) ‘Gaining from vertical partnerships: knowledge transfer, relationship duration and supplier performance improvement in the US and Japanese automotive industries’, Strategic Management Journal 24(4): 293–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard-Barton, D. (1988) ‘Implementation as mutual adaptation of technology and organization’, Research Policy 17: 251–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard-Barton, D. and Sinha, D. (1993) ‘Developer–user interaction and user satisfaction in internal technology transfer’, Academy of Management Journal 36(5): 1125–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A., Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1987) ‘Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3: 783–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Love, J.H. (1995) ‘Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: a theoretical note’, Journal of International Business Studies 26(2): 399–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E., Romeo, A., Schwartz, M., Teece, D.J., Wagner, S. and Brach, P. (1982) Technology Transfer, Productivity, and Economic Policy, Norton: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, X., Mitchell, W. and Swaminathan, A. (1995) ‘Recreating and extending Japanese automobile buyer-supplier links in North America’, Strategic Management Journal 16(8): 589–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, X. and Salomon, R. (2003) ‘Tacitness, learning and international expansion: a study of foreign direct investment in a knowledge-intensive industry’, Organization Science, 14(3).

  • Martin, X., Swaminathan, A. and Mitchell, W. (1998) ‘Organizational evolution in an interorganizational environment: incentives and constraints on international expansion strategy’, Administrative Science Quarterly 43(3): 566–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFetridge, D.G. (1995) ‘Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: a comment’, Journal of International Business Studies 26(2): 409–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (1991) ‘Why investors value multi-nationality’, Journal of Business 64(2): 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (1992) ‘Internalization: an event study’, Journal of International Economics 33: 41–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, T., Petersen, B. and Sharma, D. (2003) ‘Knowledge transfer performance of multinational companies’, Management International Review, 43(4).

  • Polanyi, M. (1958) The Tacit Dimension, University of Chicago Press: Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pugel, T.A. (1978) International Market Linkages and US Manufacturing: Prices, Profits and Patterns, Ballinger Publishing: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, R. and DeFillippi, R.J. (1990) ‘Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage’, Academy of Management Review 15(1): 88–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivkin, J. (2001) ‘Reproducing knowledge: replication without imitation at moderate complexity’, Organization Science 12(3): 274–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A.M. (1981) Inside the Multinationals: The Economics of Internal Markets, Columbia University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P. (1998) ‘On the dynamics of appropriability, of tacit and of codified knowledge’, Research Policy 26(7–8): 843–856.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shan, W. and Song, J. (1997) ‘Foreign direct investment and the sourcing of technological advantage: evidence from the biotechnology industry’, Journal of International Business Studies 28(2): 267–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaver, J.M. (1998) ‘Accounting for endogeneity when assessing strategy performance: does entry mode affect FDI survival? Management Science 44(4): 571–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonin, B. (1999a) ‘Ambiguity and the process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances’, Strategic Management Journal 20(7): 595–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonin, B. (1999b) ‘Transfer of marketing know-how in international strategic alliances: an empirical investigation of the role and antecedents of knowledge ambiguity’, Journal of International Business Studies 30(3): 463–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramaniam, M. and Venkatraman, N. (2001) ‘Determinants of transnational new product development capability: testing the influence of transferring and deploying tacit over-seas knowledge’, Strategic Management Journal 22: 359–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szulanski, G. (1996) ‘Exploring internal stickiness: impediments to the transfer of best practice within the firm’, Strategic Management Journal 17(special issue): 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D.J. (1977) ‘Technology transfer by multinational corporations: the resource cost of transferring technological know-how’, Economic Journal 87: 242–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D.J. (1981) ‘The market for know-how and the efficient international transfer of technology’, Annals of American Academy of Political and Social Science 458: 81–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D.J. (2000) Managing Intellectual Capital, Oxford University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H.R. (1992) Microeconomic Theory, Norton: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel, E. (1994) ‘Sticky information’ and the locus of problem solving: implications for innovation’, Management Science 40(4): 429–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Krogh, G., Ichijo, K. and Nonaka, I. (2000) Enabling Knowledge Creation, Oxford University Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1991) ‘Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives’, Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S.G. (1995) ‘Four R's of Profitability: Rents, Resources, Routines, and Replication’, in C.A. Montgomery (ed.) Resource-Based and Evolutionary Theories of the Firm: Towards a Synthesis, Kluwer Academic Press: Boston, pp: 147–178.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, R. (1997) The Competitive Advantage of Knowledge-Based Resources in the Semiconductor Industry, Garland Publishing: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zander, U. and Kogut, B. (1995) ‘Knowledge and the speed of transfer and imitation of organizational capabilities: an empirical test’, Organization Science 6(1): 76–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are thankful for comments from Sanjeev Agarwal, Jean-Luc Arregle, Peter Buckley, Witold Henisz, Michael Lenox, Joanne Oxley, Alan Rugman, Anju Seth, Myles Shaver, Bernard Wolf and Bernard Yeung. We are also grateful for comments from the editor and anonymous reviewers. All remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to X Martin.

Additional information

Accepted by Tom Brewer, Outgoing Editor, 28 February 2003.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Martin, X., Salomon, R. Knowledge transfer capacity and its implications for the theory of the multinational corporation. J Int Bus Stud 34, 356–373 (2003). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400037

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400037

Keywords

Navigation