Skip to main content
Log in

Balancing private and state ownership in emerging markets' telecommunications infrastructure: country, industry, and firm influences

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 01 September 2004

Abstract

Bargaining between host states and investors over the terms of investment in sensitive sectors of the economy generates political and economic tensions. In this study, we investigate the factors that contribute to the outcomes of those negotiations as measured by the private (vs state-owned) share of newly consummated telecommunications infrastructure projects. We find that private ownership is positively associated with overall economic development and investment liberalization in the host country and with greenfield (vs divestiture) and joint venture (vs wholly owned) projects. Private ownership is negatively associated with existing telecommunications infrastructure, higher levels of state ownership of foreign investing firms, and the technological sophistication of the projects. Our analysis also shows a curvilinear (inverted U-shaped) relationship between investment policy hazards and private ownership. This finding supports the insight from transaction cost economics that potential gains from internalization are greatest at intermediate levels of uncertainty.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anderson, E. and Gatignon, H. (1986) ‘Modes of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and propositions’, Journal of International Business Studies 17(3): 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C. (1993) ‘Investment and adoption in advanced telecommunications’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 20: 227–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard, S.L. (1997) ‘An empirical assessment of the proximity–concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade’, American Economic Review 87: 520–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M. (1976) The Future of the Multinational Enterprise, Holmes and Meier: London.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1996) Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A.D. (1990) Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, S. (1986) ‘Types of synergy and economic value: the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms’, Strategic Management Journal 7: 119–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Contractor, F.J. (1990) ‘Ownership patterns of US joint ventures abroad and the liberalization of foreign government regulations in the 1980s: evidence from the benchmark surveys’, Journal of International Business Studies 21(1): 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Contractor, F.J. and Lorange, P. (1988) ‘Why Should Firms Cooperate? The Strategy and Economics Basis for Cooperative Ventures’, in F. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies in International Business, Lexington Books: Lexington, MA, pp: 3–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J.D. and Moskowitz, T.J. (1999) ‘Home bias at home: local equity preference in domestic portfolios’, Journal of Finance 54: 2045–2073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J.D. and Moskowitz, T.J. (2001) ‘The geography of investment: informed trading and asset prices’, Journal of Political Economy 109(4): 811–841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeCastro, J. and Uhlenbruck, N. (1997) ‘Characteristics of privatization: evidence from developed, less-developed, and former communist countries’, Journal of International Business Studies 28: 123–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delios, A. and Beamish, P. (1999) ‘Survival and profitability: the roles of experience and intangible assets in foreign subsidiary performance’, Academy of Management Journal 44(4): 480–491.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewenter, K.L. and Malatesta, P.H. (1997) ‘Public offerings of state-owned and privately-owned enterprises: an international comparison’, Journal of Finance 52: 1659–1679.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doh, J.P. (2000) ‘Entrepreneurial privatization strategies: order of entry and local partner collaboration as sources of competitive advantage’, Academy of Management Review 25: 551–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doh, J.P. and Teegen, H. (2000) ‘Government mandates and local partner participation in emerging markets: policy and performance implications for government and business strategies’, Paper Presented at the Academy of International Business Annual Meeting, Phoenix, Arizona, 20 November.

  • Doh, J.P. and Teegen, H. (2002) ‘Government privatization strategies in emerging economies: whether to go some or all of the way’, Journal of International Business and Economy 3 (1): 69–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doh, J.P. and Teegen, H. (2003) ‘Private infrastructure investment in emerging economies: comparing the Latin American and Asian experience’, Management Research 1(1): 9–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doz, Y. and Prahalad, C.K. (1980) ‘How MNCs cope with host government intervention’, Harvard Business Review, 58 (3): 149–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eden, L. and Molot, M.A. (2002) ‘Insiders, outsiders and host country bargains’, Journal of International Management 8: 359–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt, K.M. (1989) ‘Agency theory: an assessment and review’, Academy of Management Review 14: 7–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engardio, P. (1994) ‘Third world leapfrog’, Business Week, (18 May) 47–49.

  • Fagre, N. and Wells, L. (1982) ‘Bargaining power of multinationals and host governments’, Journal of International Business Studies 13: 9–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gatignon, H. and Anderson, E. (1988) ‘The multinational corporation's degree of control over subsidiaries: an empirical test of a transaction cost explanation’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4(2): 305–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gomes-Casseres, B. (1989) ‘Ownership structures of foreign subsidiaries’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11: 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosse, R. and Trevino, L. (1996) ‘Foreign direct investment in the United States: an analysis by country of origin’, Journal of International Business Studies 27(1): 139–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S.J. and Hart, O.D. (1986) ‘The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration’, Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guilford, J.P. (1954) Psychometric Methods, McGraw-Hill: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hair, J.F., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L. and Black, W.C. (1995) Multivariate Data Analysis, Prentice-Hall: Upper Saddle River, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrigan, K. (1988) ‘Strategic Alliances and Partner Asymmetries’, in F. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.) Cooperative Strategies in International Business, Lexington Books: Lexington, MA, pp: 53–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harzing, A.-W. (2002) ‘Acquisitions versus greenfield investments: international strategy and management of entry modes’, Strategic Management Journal 23: 211–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W.J. and Williamson, O.E. (1999) ‘Comparative economic organization – within and between countries’, Business and Politics 1: 261–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W.J. and Zelner, B.A. (2000) ‘The institutional environment for telecommunications investment’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 10(1): 123–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J.-F. (1991) ‘The transaction costs theory of joint ventures: an empirical study of Japanese subsidiaries in the United States’, Management Science 37: 483–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J.-F. and Park, Y.-R. (1993) ‘Greenfield vs acquisition’, Management Science 39: 1054–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heritage Foundation (1990–1998) Index of Economic Freedom, Heritage Foundation: Washington, DC.

  • Hill, C.W.L., Hwang, P. and Kim, W.C. (1990) ‘An eclectic theory of the choice of international entry mode’, Strategic Management Journal 11: 117–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitt, M.A., Dacin, T.M., Levitas, E., Arregle, J.L. and Borza, A. (2000) ‘Partner selection in emerging and developed market contexts: resource-based and organizational learning perspectives’, Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 449–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofman, A. (2000) The Economic Development of Latin America in the Twentieth Century, Edward Elgar: Northampton, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoskisson, R.E., Eden, L., Lau, C.M. and Wright, M. (2000) ‘Strategy in emerging economies’, Academy of Management Journal 43(3): 249–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jemison, D.B. and Sitkin, S.B. (1986) ‘Corporate acquisitions: a process perspective’, Academy of Management Review 11: 145–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976) ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C. and Murphy, K.J. (1990) ‘Performance pay and top management incentives’, Journal of Political Economy 98: 225–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kambhato, P. (1998) ‘The Flagship Role of Telecommunications’, in I. Lieberman and C. Kirkness (eds.) Privatization and Emerging Equity Markets, The World Bank: Washington, DC, pp: 88–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, K.J., Tosi, H. and Cannella, A.A. (1999) ‘Multilevel theory building: benefits, barriers, and new developments’, Academy of Management Review 24: 243–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S. (1979) ‘Political risk: a review and reconsideration’, Journal of International Business Studies 10: 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S. (1987) ‘Testing the bargaining hypothesis in the manufacturing sector in developing countries’, International Organization 41: 609–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. and Singh, H. (1988) ‘The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode’, Journal of International Business Studies 19(3): 411–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kostova, T. (1999) ‘Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: a contextual perspective’, Academy of Management Review 24: 308–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kostova, T. and Roth, K. (2002) ‘Adoption of an organizational practice by the subsidiaries of the MNC: institutional and relational effects’, Academy of Management Journal 45: 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, H.W. and Beamish, P.W. (1990) ‘Cross-cultural cooperative behavior in joint ventures in LDCs’, Management International Review 30: 87–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lecraw, D.J. (1984) ‘Bargaining power, ownership, and profitability of transnational corporations in developing countries’, Journal of International Business Studies 5(1): 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenway, S.A. and Murtha, T.P. (1994) ‘The state as strategist in international business research’, Journal of International Business Studies 25(3): 513–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, C. (1938) America's Stake in International Investments, The Brookings Institution: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, C. (1948) The United States and Foreign Investment Problems, The Brookings Institution: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lubatkin, M. (1983) ‘Mergers and the performance of the acquiring firm’, Academy of Management Review 8: 218–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKnight, L.W., Vaaler, P.M., Schrage, N.N. and Katz, R.L. (2003) ‘Creative Destruction in Emerging Markets: Privatizing Telecoms and the State’, in L.F. Cranor and S.S. Wildman (eds.) Rethinking Rights and Regulations: Institutional Responses to New Communications Technologies, MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, pp: 367–396.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mesch, G. (1992) ‘Salinas’ rush for ‘bypass technologies’’, Satellite Communications 16: 20–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikesell, R. (1979) The World Copper Industry: Structure and Economic Analysis, Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, MD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D. and Lessard, D.R. (eds.) (2001) The Strategic Management of Large Engineering Projects: Shaping Institutions, Risks and Governance, MIT Press: Cambridge MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mudambi, R. (2003) Privatization and Globalization: The Changing Role of the State in Business, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtha, T.P. and Lenway, S.A. (1994) ‘Country capabilities and the strategic state: how national political institutions affect multinational corporations’ strategies’, Strategic Management Journal 15: 113–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C. (1986) ‘The new institutional economics’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 142: 230–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C. (1993) ‘Institutions and credible commitment’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149: 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C. (1994) ‘Economic performance through time’, American Economic Review 84: 359–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2000) OECD Information Technology Outlook 2000, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris.

  • Olson, M. (1993) ‘Dictatorship, democracy, and development’, American Political Science Review 87: 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oxley, J.E. (1997) ‘Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: a transaction cost approach’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 13: 387–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan, Y. and Tse, D.K. (2000) ‘The hierarchical model of market entry modes’, Journal of International Business Studies 31(4): 535–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, E.C. and Guney, S.E. (1993) ‘The structure of privatization plans’, Financial Management 22: 84–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M.E. (1985) Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, The Free Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M.E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations, The Free Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • PPI (1999, 2000, 2001) Private Participation in Infrastructure Database, The World Bank: Washington, DC.

  • Ramamurti, R. (2000) ‘A multilevel model of privatization in emerging economies’, Academy of Management Review 25: 525–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramamurti, R. (2001) ‘The obsolescing ‘bargaining model’? MNC–host developing country relations revisited’, Journal of International Business Studies 32(1): 23–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramamurti, R. (2003) ‘Can governments make credible promises?’, Journal of International Management 9(3): 253–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Root, F.R. and Ahmed, A. (1978) ‘The influence of policy instruments on manufacturing direct foreign investment in developing countries’, Journal of International Business Studies 9: 81–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. (1981) Inside The Multinationals: The Economics of Internal Markets, Columbia University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. (2003) International Business, FT/Prentice-Hall: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarkar, M.B., Cavusgil, S.T. and Aulakh, P. (1999) ‘International expansion of telecommunication carriers: the influence of market structure, network characteristics, and entry imperfections’, Journal of International Business Studies 30(2): 361–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaan, J.L. (1988) ‘How to control a joint venture even as a minority partner’, Journal of General Management 14(1): 4–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1956) ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth’, Quarterly Journal Of Economics 70: 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (1996) ‘Recombinant property in East European capitalism’, American Journal of Sociology 101: 993–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stopford, J.M. and Strange, S. (1991) Rival States, Rival Firms: Competition for World Market Shares, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Swan, T.W. (1956) ‘Economic growth and capital accumulation’, Economic Record 36: 51–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C. (2000) ‘The impact of host country government policy on US multinational investment decisions’, The World Economy 23(5): 28–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Telegeography (2000) New International Operators, Telegeography: Washington, DC.

  • Uhlenbruck, K. and DeCastro, J. (1998) ‘Privatization from the acquirer's perspective: a mergers and acquisitions based framework’, Journal of Management Studies 25(5): 619–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uhlenbruck, K. and DeCastro, J. (2000) ‘Foreign acquisitions in Central and Eastern Europe: outcomes of privatization in transitional economies’, Academy of Management Journal 43: 381–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uhlenbruck, K., Meyer, K. and Hitt, M. (2003) ‘Organizational transformation in transition economies: resource-based and organizational learning perspectives’, Journal of Management Studies 40(2): 257–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vachani, S. (1995) ‘Enhancing the obsolescing bargain theory: a longitudinal study of foreign ownership of US and European multinationals’, Journal of International Business Studies 26(1): 159–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, R. (1971) Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of US Enterprise, Basic Books: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wells, L.T. and Gleason, E.S. (1995) ‘Is foreign infrastructure investment still risky?’, Harvard Business Review, (September/October) 44–53.

  • Westney, E. (1993) ‘Institutionalization Theory and the Multinational Corporation’, in S. Ghoshal and E. Westney (eds.) Organization Theory and the Multinational Corporation, St Martin's Press: New York, pp: 53–75.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkins, M. (ed.) (1977) British Overseas Investments: 1907–1948, Arno Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilkins, M. (1988) ‘The free-standing company, 1870–1914: an important type of British foreign direct investment’, Economic History Review 41(2): 259–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1975) Markets and Hierarchies, The Free Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1984) ‘Corporate governance’, Yale Law Journal 93: 1197–1230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1998, 1999) World Development Indicators, The World Bank: Washington, DC.

  • WTO (1999) Telecommunications Services, Background Note by the Secretariat, 8 December World Trade Organization: Geneva, pp: 99–4942.

  • Wright, M., Hoskisson, R.E., Busenitz, L.W. and Dial, J. (2000) ‘Entrepreneurial growth through privatization: the upside of management buyouts’, Academy of Management Review 25: 591–601.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wymbs, C. (2002) ‘US firms’ entry into the European telecommunications market: a question of modalities choice’, Journal of High Technology Management Research 13: 87–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yan, A. and Gray, B. (1994) ‘Bargaining power, management control, and performance in United States–China joint ventures: a comparative case study’, Academy of Management Journal 37: 1478–1517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zahra, S.A., Ireland, R.D., Gutierrez, I. and Hitt, M.A. (2000) ‘Privatization and entrepreneurial transformation: emerging issues and a future research agenda’, Academy of Management Review 25: 509–524.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We acknowledge the financial support of George Washington, Temple, and Villanova Universities. We thank JIBS Departmental Editors Stefanie Lenway and Tom Murtha for their guidance and suggestions, and two anonymous reviewers for comments on earlier drafts of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jonathan P Doh.

Additional information

Accepted by Tom Murtha and Stefanie Lenway, Departmental Editors, 20 February 2004. This paper has been with the author for three revisions.

An erratum to this article is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400105.

Appendix: Description of PPI database

Appendix: Description of PPI database

Database coverage

Projects that have reached financial closure and directly or indirectly serve the public. Projects in water, transport, electricity, telecommunications, and natural gas. The telecommunications sector includes local, national, and international phone services and mobile phone services. Other services (Internet, paging, trunking, and value-added services) and private networks are excluded. Low- and middle-income developing countries, as defined and classified by the World Bank.

Definition of private participation

The private company must assume operating risk during the operating period or development and operating risk during the contract period. A foreign state-owned firm is considered a private entity.

Definition of a project unit

A corporate entity created to operate infrastructure facilities is considered a project. When two or more physical facilities are operated by the corporate entity, all are considered as one project.

Project types

  1. 1)

    Operations and management contract: A private entity takes over the management of a SOE for a given period. This category includes management contracts and leases.

  2. 2)

    Greenfield project: A private entity or a public–private JV builds and operates a new facility. This category includes build–own–transfer and build–own–operate contracts.

  3. 3)

    Divestiture: A private consortium buys an equity stake in a SOE. The private stake may or may not imply private management of the company.

Definition of financial closure

For greenfield projects, and for operations and management contracts with major capital expenditure, financial closure is defined as the existence of a legally binding commitment of equity holders or debt financiers to provide or mobilize funding for the project. The funding must account for a significant part of the project cost, securing the construction of the facility. For operations and management contracts, a lease agreement or a contract authorizing the commencement of management or lease service must exist. For divestitures, equity holders must have a legally binding commitment to acquire the facility assets.

Recording of investments

Investments and privatization revenues generally have been recorded on a commitment basis in the year of financial closure (for which data are typically readily available). Actual disbursements have not been tracked. Where privatizations and new investments are phased and data were available at financial closure, they are recorded in phases.

State ownership of principal project investor (added to PPI database by authors)

We identified the parent name of the principal project investor and used this to determine the level of (home) state ownership of the investor. As most projects include three or fewer investors, and the investors are listed according to their ownership share in the investment, we focused first on the initial investor in identifying the level of state ownership of the investor. We gathered data from a range of sources to determine the relative state ownership of the project investors. These data sources include the International Telecommunications Union, the Telegeography New International Operators report (2000), the WTO (1999), company annual reports, web sites, SEC 10-K and 10-Q filings, and the Lexis–Nexis and ABI/INFORM databases. We chose 1998 as the relevant year for measuring state ownership in order to match the other data sources. Although using more recent data may result in an underestimation of the impact of state ownership, owing to the continued privatization of large state-owned investors such as Deutsche Telecom, this conservative approach will limit the potential of a Type I error in which variation is attributed to investor state ownership when firms are actually moving toward private governance.

State ownership and percent private

The calculation of the percentage of the project that is state owned does not incorporate the state ownership of the investor, but only the residual (non-private) percentage still in the hands of the host state. Although the variable ‘investor state ownership’ may appear to overlap with the measure of non-private (government) ownership of the project, the percentage of the project that is ‘private’ can include investors that themselves are state owned. Hence there is no risk of ‘double counting’ or tautological model formulation. See ‘definition of private participation’ above (e.g., ‘A foreign state-owned company is considered a private entity’).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Doh, J., Teegen, H. & Mudambi, R. Balancing private and state ownership in emerging markets' telecommunications infrastructure: country, industry, and firm influences. J Int Bus Stud 35, 233–250 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400082

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400082

Keywords

Navigation