Skip to main content
Log in

Patent rights and innovative activity: evidence from national and firm-level data

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Global standards of patent protection have been strengthened and harmonized in recent years. Despite the heated policy debates and theoretical controversies, empirical studies of the consequences for innovative activity are scant. This paper contributes to the debate by providing an empirical analysis of the effects of patent strength on different aspects of innovative activity, namely firm-level research and development (R&D), domestic patenting, and foreign patenting. The analysis employs an updated index of patent rights. The results show the complexity of evaluating the effects of patent reform on innovative activity, since the effects vary nonlinearly (depending on the initial level of patent strength) and vary by a country's level of economic development. Overall, for developing economies, patent strength negatively affects domestic patent filings and insignificantly affects R&D and foreign patent filings. For developed economies, patent strength positively affects R&D and domestic patent filings, and negatively affects foreign patent filings, after some critical level of patent protection is reached.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the text of the TRIPS agreement, see http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/27-trips_01_e.htm

  2. The exception is that Yang and Maskus (2001), Kanwar and Evenson (2003), and Park and Lippoldt (2005) use an earlier version of the Patent Rights Index in their studies.

  3. For example, Bosworth (1980) uses dummy variables to indicate whether certain patent law features exist, such as duration, novelty, or compulsory licensing. Ferrantino (1993) uses dummy variables to indicate whether a country was a member of an international patent treaty. Rapp and Rozek (1990) consider additional features of patent systems, but do not incorporate enforcement mechanisms. A disadvantage with these previous measures, for the purposes of our research, is that they are limited to one year of record. Branstetter et al. (2004) follow the dummy variable method (giving a value of 1 if a reform has occurred, 0 otherwise). Some pitfalls with this approach are that reforms are not one-shot but ongoing over time, and that there are various magnitudes of reform (from major ones to minor ones). Lerner (2002) also looks at several features of the patent system, but does not aggregate them into an overall measure of the strength of patent rights. Mansfield (1994) and Sherwood (1997) rely on surveys of expert opinion or perceptions of the strength of patent rights. These surveys provide ratings for a few countries and a single time period. Moreover, issues can be raised about the comparability of different interviewees' perceptions, since there is no information on how to scale the responses. How does one expert's rating compare with another's?

  4. The 10 industries are: Beverages (3.6%), Construction Machinery (5.6%), Electrical Components (7.7%), Food (13.8%), Household Appliances (2.2%), Industrial Chemicals (11.4%), Nonferrous Metals (5.8%), Rubber (3.6%), Scientific Instruments (35.7%), and Semiconductors (10.6%).

  5. The Patent Rights Index data are available upon request from Walter Park.

  6. Data on the patent rights index are available from the corresponding author upon request.

  7. See the documentation in United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Handbook of Statistics, 2003 (http://www.unctad.org/en/docs//tdstat28_enfr.pdf). Only one country switched from the developing to developed group during the sample period – namely Israel in 1978.

  8. For example, membership of the Paris Convention grew from 70 members in 1970 to 97 in 1990 and 160 in 2000. Membership of the PCT grew from 20 members in 1970 to 123 in 1990 and 175 in 2000. Membership of UPOV grew from 4 in 1970 to 19 in 1990 and 46 in 2000. Membership of TRIPS grew from 113 in 1995 to 140 in 2000.

  9. In preliminary analyses, we also controlled for measures of industry munificence (i.e., resource abundance), dynamism (volatility of industry sales), and concentration (Herfindahl-type index for top 20 firms in an industry). However, these variables were insignificant determinants once the industry dummies were included.

  10. The LR test statistic, −2(ln L R −lnL U ), where L R (L U ) is the log-likelihood value of the restricted (unrestricted) model, is distributed as a chi-square distribution (with one degree of freedom).

  11. Bearing in mind that, since Eq. (1) is exponential, the critical value occurs at PRI*=−β̂1/2β̂2. Thus a U-shaped effect arises if β̂2>0 (and an inverse-U if β̂2<0), evaluated at PRI*.

  12. The F-statistic, F=(R U 2R R 2)/[(1−R U 2)/(NK)], where R U 2 (R R 2) is the unrestricted (restricted) R-squared, is distributed as an F-distribution with (1, NK) degrees of freedom, where NK is the number of observations less the number of RHS variables.

  13. As Murmann's (2003) study of the synthetic dye industry in Germany during the 19th century shows, the appropriateness of patent strength depends on the circumstances, including timing. The patent law of 1877 was successful because it ‘came after the industry had already developed strong firms and science was providing the tools to do systematic R&D on new dyes … Had the German patent law arrived in 1858, it is doubtful that as many German firms would have developed into strong competitors. Fewer firms would have entered the industry, and inefficient firms would have been more likely to survive’ (p: 33).

References

  • Allred, B.B. and Park, W.G. (2007) ‘The influence of patent protection on firm innovation investment in manufacturing industries’, Journal of International Management 13 (2): 91–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962) ‘Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention’, in R. Nelson (ed.) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, pp: 610–614.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004) Economic Growth, 2nd edn, McGraw-Hill: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J. and Maskin, E. (2000) ‘Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation’, Working Paper 00-01, MIT Department of Economics: Cambridge, MA.

  • Bosworth, D.L. (1980) ‘The transfer of US technology abroad’, Research Policy 9 (4): 378–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter, L.G., Fisman, R. and Foley, C.F. (2004) ‘Do stronger intellectual property rights increase international technology transfer? Empirical evidence from US firm-level panel data’, Department of Economics Working Paper, Columbia University, New York.

  • Cadot, O. and Lippman, S.A. (1995) ‘Barriers to imitation and the incentive to innovate’, Working Paper No. 434, Los Angeles: Western Management Science Institute, University of California.

  • Cameron, A.C. and Trivedi, P.K. (1998) Regression Analysis of Count Data, Cambridge University Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J., Glac, K. and Harding, R. (2004) ‘The internationalization of R&D: the Swiss case’, Management International Review 44 (Special Issue 3): 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chin, J. and Grossman, G. (1990) ‘Intellectual Property Rights and North–South Trade’, in R.W. Jones and A.O. Krueger (eds.) The Political Economy of International Trade: Essays in Honor of Robert E. Baldwin, Basil Blackwell: Cambridge, MA, pp: 90–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W.M., Nelson, R.R. and Walsh, J.P. (2000) ‘Protecting their intellectual assets: appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not)’, NBER Working Paper No. 7552, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Commission on Intellectual Property Rights (2002) ‘Integrating intellectual property rights and development policy’, London, UK. (Report available online at: www.iprcommission.org/graphic/documents/final_report.htm).

  • Deardorff, A.V. (1992) ‘Welfare effects of global patent protection’, Economica 59: 35–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diwan, I. and Rodrik, D. (1991) ‘Patents, appropriate technology, and North–South trade’, Journal of International Economics 30 (1–2): 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J.H. (1977) ‘Trade, Location of Economic Activity and the MNE: A Search for an Eclectic Approach’, in B. Ohlin, P. Hesselborn and P.M. Wijkman (eds.) The International Allocation of Economic Activity: Proceedings of a Nobel Symposium Held at Stockholm, Holmes & Meier: New York, pp: 395–418.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Evenson, R. and Westphal, L. (1997) ‘Technological Change and Technology Strategy’, in H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.) Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 3, North-Holland: Amsterdam, pp: 2209–2299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrantino, M.J. (1993) ‘The effect of intellectual property rights on international trade and investment’, Weltwirtschafliches Archiv 129: 300–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frost, T.S. (2001) ‘The geographic sources of foreign subsidiaries’ innovations’, Strategic Management Journal 22 (2): 101–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gadbaw, R.M. and Richards, T. (eds.) (1988) Intellectual Property Rights: Global Consensus, Global Conflict, Westview Press: Westport, CT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais, D. (1998) The TRIPS Agreement: Drafting History and Analysis, Sweet & Maxwell: London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginarte, J.C. and Park, W.G. (1997) ‘Determinants of patent rights: a cross-national study’, Research Policy 26 (3): 283–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass, A.J. (2004) ‘Imitation as a stepping stone to innovation’, Department of Economics Working Paper, Texas A&M University.

  • Grossman, G. and Lai, E. (2004) ‘International protection of intellectual property’, American Economic Review 94 (5): 1635–1653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B.H. and Ziedonis, R.H. (2001) ‘The patent paradox revisited: an empirical study of patenting in the US semiconductor industry, 1979–1995’, RAND Journal of Economics 32 (1): 101–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J., Hall, B.H. and Griliches, Z. (1984) ‘Econometric models for count data with an application to the patents–R&D relationship’, Econometria 52 (4): 909–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, M.A. and Eisenberg, R.S. (1998) ‘Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research’, Science 280 (5364): 698–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1993) ‘Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights’, Econometrica 61 (6): 1247–1280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hingley, P. and Park, W.G. (2003) ‘Patent family data and statistics at the European Patent Office’, [www document] www.wipo.int/patent/meetings/2003/statistics_workshop/en/presentation/statistics_workshop_hingley.pdf (accessed 10 July 2007).

  • Horowitz, A.W. and Lai, E.L.C. (1996) ‘Patent length and the rate of innovation’, International Economic Review 37(4): 785–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. and Lerner, J. (2004) Innovation and its Discontents: How our Broken Patent System is Endangering Innovation and Progress, and What to do about it, Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanwar, S. and Evenson, R. (2003) ‘Does intellectual property protection spur technological change?’ Oxford Economic Papers 55 (2): 235–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitch, E.W. (1977) ‘The nature and function of the patent system’, Journal of Law and Economics 20 (2): 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korenko, G. (1999) ‘Intellectual property protection and industrial growth’, Journal of World Intellectual Property 2 (1): 47–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kortum, S. and Lerner, J. (1999) ‘What is behind the recent surge in patenting?’ Research Policy 28 (1): 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W.M. and Posner, R.A. (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J. (2002) ‘Patent protection and innovation over 150 Years’, NBER Working Paper No. 8977, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Levin, R.C., Klevorick, A., Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1987) ‘Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development’, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity 3: 784–829.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1994) ‘Intellectual property protection, foreign direct investment, and technology transfer’, International Finance Corporation Discussion Paper No. 19, Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Maskus, K.E. (2000) Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy, Institute for International Economics: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, K.E. and Penubarti, M. (1995) ‘How trade-related are intellectual property rights?’ Journal of International Economics 39 (3): 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazzoleni, P. and Nelson, R. (1998) ‘The benefits and costs of strong patent protection: a contribution to the current debate’, Research Policy 27 (3): 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murmann, J.P. (2003) Knowledge and Competitive Advantage: The Coevolution of Firms, Technology, and National Institutions, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W.D. (1969) Invention Growth, and Welfare: A Theoretical Treatment of Technological Change, MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, W.G. and Lippoldt, D. (2005) ‘International licensing and the strengthening of intellectual property rights in developing countries during the 1990s’, OECD Economic Studies 40 (1): 7–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, W.G. and Wagh, S. (2002) ‘Index of patent rights, 2000 update’, in J. Gwartney and R. Lawson (eds.) Economic Freedom of the World Annual Report 2002, Fraser Institute: Vancouver, pp: 33–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M.E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press: New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rapp, R.T. and Rozek, R.P. (1990) ‘Benefits and costs of intellectual property protection in developing countries’, Journal of World Trade 24 (5): 75–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakakibara, M. and Branstetter, L. (2001) ‘Do stronger patents induce more innovation? Evidence for the 1988 Japanese patent law reforms’, RAND Journal of Economics 32 (1): 77–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F.M. (1972) ‘Nordhaus’ theory of optimal patent life: a geometric reinterpretation’, American Economic Review 62 (3): 422–427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F.M. and Weisburst, S. (1995) ‘Economic effects of strengthening pharmaceutical patent protection in Italy’, International Review of Industrial Property and Copyright Law 26 (6): 1009–1024.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scotchmer, S. (2004) Innovation and Incentives, MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C. (2000) ‘Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting’, Innovation Policy and the Economy 1: 119–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherwood, R. (1990) Intellectual Property and Economic Development, Westview Press: Boulder, CO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherwood, R.M. (1997) ‘Intellectual property systems and investment stimulation: the ratings of systems in eighteen developing countries’, IDEA: Journal of Law and Technology 37 (2): 261–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siebeck, W. (ed.) (1990) ‘Strengthening protection of intellectual property: a survey of the literature’, World Bank Discussion Paper No. 112, Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Smith, P. (2001) ‘How do foreign patent rights affect US exports, affiliate sales, and licenses?’ Journal of International Economics 55 (2): 411–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (2004) ‘Towards a pro-development and balance intellectual property regime’, Columbia University Draft.

  • Taylor, M.S. (1993) ‘TRIPs, trade, and technology transfer’, Canadian Journal of Economics 26 (3): 625–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (1975) The Role of the Patent System in the Transfer of Technology to Developing Countries, Report No. TD/B/AC.11/19/Add.1, UNCTAD: Paris.

  • van Elkan, R. (1996) ‘Catching up and slowing down: learning and growth patterns in an open economy’, Journal of International Economics 41 (1): 95–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varsakelis, N.C. (2001) ‘The impact of patent protection, economy openness and national culture on R&D investment: a cross-country empirical investigation’, Research Policy 30 (7): 1059–1068.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watal, J. (2000) Intellectual Property Rights in the WTO and Developing Countries, Kluwer Law International: The Hague.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G. and Maskus, K. (2001) ‘Intellectual property rights, licensing, and innovation in an endogenous product-cycle model’, Journal of International Economics 53 (1): 169–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziedonis, R.H. (2004) ‘Don’t fence me in: fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms’, Management Science 50 (6): 804–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Brian Silverman, Mike (Masaaki) Kotabe, Stephen Tallman, Scott Swan, Sully Taylor, Fritz Foley, and Smita Wagh for helpful discussions, and three anonymous referees for their thorough comments and review.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Walter G Park.

Additional information

Accepted by Arie Y Lewin, Editor-in-Chief and Brian Silverman, Departmental Editor, 7 November 2006. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

Appendices

Appendix A: Index scoring methods

Patent Rights Index (PRI)

Table A1

Table 10 Table a1

Explanatory notes on the Patent Rights Index

Membership in international agreements

Countries that participate in these international agreements indicate their willingness to provide national, nondiscriminatory treatment to foreigners. In addition, TRIPS obliges member states to make laws, regulations, judicial decisions, and administrative rulings transparent (Article 63). The fact that TRIPS has cross-cutting multilateral statutory and procedural obligations is why we include it under the membership component even though some of its individual provisions are captured in other parts of the index. Participation in each of these agreements receives a score of 1/4, for a total of 1 if the country participates in all four.

Coverage

Rather than list the universe of technologies that could be patentable, we focus on a few technological fields that provide maximum variability across countries. The score assigned to this component is the fraction of those fields that are patentable under national law.

Enforcement mechanisms

Preliminary injunctions require individuals to cease alleged infringements prior to a case hearing. Contributory infringement clauses aid in preventing third parties from contributing to infringement. Burden-of-proof reversals shift the burden to alleged infringers to prove non-infringement. Countries receive a score of 1/3 for providing each of these.

Loss of rights

This category measures whether loss of rights will not occur owing to: (a) ‘working’ requirements, (b) compulsory licensing, and (c) revocation of patents. Each area is scored 1/3, for a total of 1 if none of the three occurs. ‘Working’ requirements require the patent holder to exploit the invention by a certain period of time or forfeit rights. Compulsory licensing requires patentees to share the use of the innovation with third parties. If a country does not impose compulsory licensing within 3 or 4 years from the date of patent grant, it receives credit for this area. Countries that do not revoke patent rights owing to non-working or other reasons also receive credit for this area.

Duration of protection

A score ranging from 0 to 1 is awarded based on the percentage of the appropriate standard duration provided. For example, a country that allows 15 years of protection from the date of application date receives a score of 0.75 for this component.

Appendix B: List of countries in the patent sample

Table A2

Table 11 Table a2

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Allred, B., Park, W. Patent rights and innovative activity: evidence from national and firm-level data. J Int Bus Stud 38, 878–900 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400306

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400306

Keywords

Navigation