Skip to main content
Log in

The effectiveness of laws against bribery abroad

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the effectiveness of laws against bribery abroad in inducing foreign investors to reduce their investments in corrupt countries. The laws are designed to reduce the supply of bribes by foreign investors by increasing the costs of bribing abroad. Such increase in costs will make foreign investors more sensitive to corruption, and induce them to reduce their investments in corrupt countries. However, the paper argues that these laws need to be implemented and coordinated in multiple countries to become effective. Otherwise, investors in a country will have incentives to bypass them when competitors from other countries are not bound by similar legal constrains. The empirical analysis shows that investors from countries that implemented the OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business Transactions of 1997 reduced their investments in corrupt countries. Investors from the US, which were bound by the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act of 1977, also reduced investments in corrupt countries, but only after the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention was in place.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In addition to increasing the costs and risks of corruption, there are other alternatives to reduce corruption, such as reducing government intervention and discretion, increasing competition, reducing incentives for bribes, improving transparency in government activities, and government decentralization (Ades & Di Tella, 1997, 1999; Fisman & Gatti, 2002; Rose-Ackerman, 1999; Shleifer & Vishny, 1993). I do not discuss these in the paper.

  2. The legislative history appears in US Congress (1977) and US Senate (1977), and is summarized in Hines (1995) and Seitzinger (1999).

  3. In the US, the FCPA was altered in 1998 by the International Anti-Bribery and Fair Competition Act of 1998 (US Congress, 1998) to bring it in line with the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention. Among the changes was the redefinition of “foreign official” to include officials of public international organizations, and the application of the Act to all issuers of securities in the US and not only US ones. For a history of this legislation see Larson (1997) and US Department of Justice (1998).

  4. Not all the economies listed are independent countries (e.g., Hong Kong). I nevertheless treat them as independent sources or destinations of FDI. Additionally, data for Belgium and Luxembourg appear together in the UNCTAD reports. I use them as one single source or destination. The host economies for which I have FDI data are: Algeria, Angola, Argentina, Armenia, Australia, Austria, Azerbaijan, Bahamas, Barbados, Belgium/Luxembourg, Belize, Benin, Bermuda, Bolivia, Brazil, Brunei, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cambodia, Cameroon, Canada, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Chile, Colombia, Comoros, Costa Rica, Cuba, Czech Republic, Denmark, Djibouti, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Eritrea, Estonia, Ethiopia, Finland, France, Gambia, Germany, Greece, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Jamaica, Japan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia, Lithuania, Macau, Macedonia, Malawi, Mali, Mauritius, Mexico, Moldova, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar, Netherlands, New Zealand, Nicaragua, Norway, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Poland, Portugal, Russia, Rwanda, Saint Kitts and Nevis, Saint Lucia, Sierra Leone, Slovakia, Slovenia, Somalia, South Korea, Spain, Suriname, Sweden, Switzerland, Tanzania, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, UK, Uruguay, USA, Uzbekistan, Venezuela, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.

  5. I have a cross-sectional panel of seven years of investment relationships between home country i and host country j. The problems of serial correlation will appear at the home-host country dyad, especially in the interaction between the indicator that the home country has laws against bribery abroad and the indicator of host country corruption. This interaction will start taking values above zero once the laws are in place, and will continue with similar values in years after the laws are passed because the level of corruption in the host country changes little from year to year. Therefore in the models I will control for problems in the error term in the home–host dyad.

  6. I thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this paper.

  7. I use a random effect panel model to be able to compute the effects of the controls, many of which are time invariant, and to correct for time-variant shocks that affect investors from a home country to a host country. This is the approach taken by Bertrand et al. (2004).

  8. I cannot run the model where I ignore the time series information because the FCPA was in place throughout the period of analysis. Therefore there is no before and after period where I can compare the effect of the FCPA on the residuals from the regression of the controls on FDI inflows. However, I do run this analysis when analyzing the behavior of US investors once the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention was in place.

  9. In this analysis I cannot compare US investments before and after 1998 in the same equation because they are mutually exclusive categories that become collinear in the analysis. As I explained before, the residual analysis takes data only from the country with the treatment. Hence we can run only one indicator at a time. If instead of running the model with US investments after 1998 on the residuals we run the model with US investments before 1998 on the residuals, the coefficient is positive and statistically significant. US investors were not further deterred by host country corruption before the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention.

References

  • Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. 1997. National champions and corruption: Some unpleasant interventionist arithmetic. Economic Journal, 107(443): 1023–1043.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. 1999. Rents, competition, and corruption. American Economic Review, 89(4): 982–993.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. 1997. Corruption and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 1320–1346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., & Mullainathan, S. 2004. How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1): 249–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevan, A. A., & Estrin, S. 2004. The determinants of foreign direct investment into European transition economies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(4): 775–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevan, A. A., Estrin, S., & Meyer, K. 2004. Foreign investment location and institutional development in transition economies. International Business Review, 13(1): 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boddewyn, J. J. 1988. Political aspects of MNE theory. Journal of International Business Studies, 19(3): 119–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard, L. 1997. An empirical assessment of the proximity-concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade. American Economic Review, 87(4): 520–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Intelligence Agency 2005. World Factbook. https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/index.html. Accessed 10 January 2005.

  • Cuervo-Cazurra, A. 2006. Who cares about corruption? Journal of International Business Studies, 37(6): 803–822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delios, A., & Henisz, W. J. 2003a. Political hazards, experience and sequential entry strategies: The international expansion of Japanese firms, 1980–1998. Strategic Management Journal, 24(11): 1153–1164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delios, A., & Henisz, W. J. 2003b. Policy uncertainty and the sequence of entry by Japanese firms, 1980–1998. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(3): 227–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. 2002. The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, K. 1997. Corruption as an international policy problem: Overview and recommendations. In K. Elliott (Ed.), Corruption and the global economy: 175–233. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Encyclopedia Britannica 2005. http://www.britannica.com/. Accessed 8 January 2005.

  • Fisman, R., & Gatti, R. 2002. Decentralization and corruption: Evidence across countries. Journal of Public Economics, 83(3): 324–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J., & Rose, A. 2002. An estimate of the effect of common currencies on trade and income. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2): 437–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. 2001. Distance still matters: The hard reality of global expansion. Harvard Business Review, 79(8): 137–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. 2005. Econometric analysis (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Habib, M., & Zurawicki, L. 2002. Corruption and foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(2): 291–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamra, W. 2000. Bribery in international business transactions and the OECD convention: Benefits and limitations. Business Economics, 35(4): 33–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinmann, F. 2004. Will the OECD convention stop foreign bribery? In Hodess, R., Inowlocki, T., Rodriguez, D & Wolfe T. (Eds) Global Corruption Report 2004: 128–135. London: Pluto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J. 2000. The institutional environment for multinational investment. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 16(2): 334–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R. 1995. Forbidden payment: Foreign bribery and American business after 1977. NBER Working Paper no. 5266, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

  • Horstmann, I. J., & Markusen, J. R. 1992. Endogenous market structures in international trade (natura facit saltum). Journal of International Economics, 32(1–2): 109–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. -E. 1977. The internationalization process of the firm: A model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of International Business Studies, 8(1): 23–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaikati, J., & Label, W. A. 1980. The foreign antibribery law: Friend or foe? Columbia Journal of World Business, 15(1): 46–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D. 1997. Corruption: The facts. Foreign Policy, 107(Summer): 114–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. 2003. Governance matters III: Governance indicators 1996–2002. World Bank Working Paper no. 3106, World Bank, Washington, DC.

  • Lambsdorff, J. G. 2003. How corruption affects persistent capital flows. Economics of Governance, 4(3): 229–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6): 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larson, A. 1997. US policy on corruption. In K. Elliott (Ed.), Corruption and the global economy: 237–240. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linneman, H. 1966. An econometric study of international trade flows. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. 1995. Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3): 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro, P. 1998. Corruption and the composition of government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics, 69(2): 263–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD 1996. Recommendation of the council on the tax deductibility of bribes to foreign public officials. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/1997doc.nsf/LinkTo/daffe-ime-br(97)20. Accessed 10 January 2005.

  • OECD 1997. Convention on combating bribery of foreign public officials in international business transactions. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/1997doc.nsf/LinkTo/daffe-ime-br(97)20. Accessed 10 January 2005.

  • OECD 2005. International direct investment statistics. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://caliban.sourceoecd.org/vl=24733987/cl=18/nw=1/rpsv/statistic/s14_about.htm?jnlissn=16081080. Accessed 20 January 2005.

  • OECD 2006. Steps taken by state parties to implement and enforce the convention on combating bribery of foreign public officials in international business transactions. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/50/33/1827022.pdf. Accessed 1 May 2007.

  • OECD 2007. Compilation of recommendations made in the phase 2 reports. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/51/45/37171905.pdf. Accessed 1 May 2007.

  • Rodriguez, P., Uhlenbruck, K., & Eden, L. 2005. Government corruption and the entry strategies of multinationals. Academy of Management Review, 30(2): 383–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. 1999. Corruption and government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Seitzinger, M. V. 1999. CRS report to congress. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service. http://www.fas.org/irp/crs/Crsfcpa.htm. Accessed 25 January 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1993. Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3): 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smarzynska, B. K., & Wei, S. J. 2000. Corruption and composition of foreign direct investment: Firm-level evidence. NBER Working Paper no. 7969, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

  • Svaleryd, H., Hakkala, K., & Norback, P. J. 2005. Asymmetric effects of corruption on FDI: Evidence from Swedish multinational firms. IUI Working Paper no. 641, Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm. http://www.ifn.se/Wfiles/wp/wp641.pdf.

  • Svensson, J. 2005. Eight questions about corruption. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(5): 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V. 1998. Corruption around the world: Causes, consequences, scope, and cures. IMF staff papers, 45(4): 559–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Transparency International 2001. TI keeps up the pressure. In Hodess, R., Banfield, J. & Wolfe T. Global Corruption Report 2001: 201–202. Berlin: Transparency International.

  • Transparency International 2005. Corruption perceptions index. http://www.transparency.org. Accessed 15 January 2005.

  • Uhlenbruck, K., Rodriguez, P., Doh, J., & Eden, L. 2006. The impact of corruption on entry strategy: Evidence from telecommunication projects in emerging economies. Organization Science, 17(3): 402–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD 2005. World investment directory on-line. FDI country profiles. http://www.unctad.org/Templates/Page.asp?intItemID=3198&lang=1. Accessed 18 January 2005.

  • US Congress 1977. The Foreign Corrupt Practices Act of 1977. 95th US Congress, Washington, DC. http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/fraud/fcpa/fcpastat.htm. Accessed 1 February 2005.

  • US Congress 1998. The International Anti-Bribery and Fair Competition Act of 1998. Washington, DC: 105th US Congress. http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/fraud/fcpa/history/1998/amends/antibribe.html. Accessed 1 February 2005.

  • US Department of Justice 1998. International Anti-Bribery Act of 1998. Legislative History. http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/fraud/fcpa/history/1998/amends/leghistory.html. Accessed 1 February 2005.

  • US Senate 1977. Foreign Corrupt Practices and Domestic and Foreign Investment Improved Disclosure Acts of 1977. Senate Report No. 95–114. 95th US Congress, Washington, DC. http://www.usdoj.gov/criminal/fraud/fcpa/history/1977/senaterpt.html. Accessed 1 February 2005.

  • Voyer, P. A., & Beamish, P. W. 2004. The effect of corruption on Japanese foreign direct investment. Journal of Business Ethics, 50(3): 211–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, S. J. 2000a. Local corruption and global capital flows. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2000(2): 303–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, S. J. 2000b. How taxing is corruption on international investors? The Review of Economic and Statistics, 82(1): 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank 2005. World development indicators. http://www.worldbank.org/data/. Accessed 4 January 2005.

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank anonymous referees, the Special Issue Editor Witold Henisz, Kendall Roth, and participants at the Academy of International Business annual meeting for useful suggestions, and the Center for International Business Research and Education at the University of South Carolina for financial support. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alvaro Cuervo-Cazurra.

Additional information

Accepted by Anand Swaminathan, Special Issue Editor and Witold Henisz, Special Issue Editor and Departmental Editor, 31 August 2007. This paper has been with the author for two revisions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cuervo-Cazurra, A. The effectiveness of laws against bribery abroad. J Int Bus Stud 39, 634–651 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400372

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400372

Keywords

Navigation